University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School
Penn Carey Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Penn Carey Law: Legal Scholarship Repository
All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Works
3-16-2023
Bibb Balancing: Regulatory Mismatches Under the Dormant Bibb Balancing: Regulatory Mismatches Under the Dormant
Commerce Clause Commerce Clause
Michael S. Knoll
University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School
Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship
Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Supreme Court of the United States
Commons
Repository Citation Repository Citation
Knoll, Michael S., "Bibb Balancing: Regulatory Mismatches Under the Dormant Commerce Clause" (2023).
All Faculty Scholarship
. 2932.
https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/2932
This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Works at Penn Carey Law: Legal Scholarship
Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Penn
Carey Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact biddlerepos@law.upenn.edu.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 1 24-FEB-23 14:13
Bibb Balancing: Regulatory Mismatches
Under the Dormant
Commerce Clause
Michael S. Knoll & Ruth Mason*
A
BSTRACT
Courts and commentators have long understood dormant Commerce
Clause doctrine to contain two types of cases: discrimination and undue bur-
dens. This Article argues for a further distinction that divides cases into single-
state burdens, which arise from the application of a single state’s law alone,
and mismatch burdens, which arise from legal diversity. Although the Su-
preme Court purports to apply Pike balancing in all undue-burden cases, we
show that the Court’s approach in mismatch cases differs substantially. Specif-
ically, unlike in single-state cases, balancing in mismatch cases involves an
implicit and potentially problematic comparison by the Court between the
challenged state’s regulation and those of other states. We label this analysis
Bibb balancing,” after the famous mudflaps case, and we show that mis-
match cases present the Court with a more challenging set of issues than do
other types of dormant Commerce Clause cases. Despite the criticisms that
attach to Bibb balancing, failing to restrain regulatory mismatches would
threaten the smooth functioning of the national marketplace and undercut im-
portant federalism values. Thus, in addition to clarifying the doctrine and ac-
knowledging the drawbacks of Bibb balancing, this Article provides advice
for achieving more consistent and defensible results in mismatch cases.
* Michael S. Knoll is the Theodore K. Warner Professor of Law, University of Penn-
sylvania Carey Law School; Professor of Real Estate, The Wharton School; and Co-Director,
Center for Tax Law and Policy, University of Pennsylvania. Ruth Mason is the Edwin S. Cohen
Distinguished Professor of Law and Taxation and Director of the Virginia Center for Tax Law at
University of Virginia School of Law. We are grateful to our wonderful research assistants, who
helped with this project over the years: Maxwell Ain, Lawrence Barker, Charlie Beller, Xixi
Chen, James Collins, Tristan Deering, Emily Horowitz, Harvey Lou, Nicholas Roberti, Jarett
Rovner, Hunter Shaw, Bolton Smith, Dillon Tan, Ian Tomesch, and Francisco Torres. We are
also grateful to librarians Kristin Glover and Paul Riermaier. We received valuable commentary
from Brannon Denning, David Elkins, Victor Fleischer, Jens Frankenreiter, Brian Galle, David
Gamage, Ari Glogower, Risa Goluboff, Thomas Haley, David Hasen, John Harrison, Andrew
Hayashi, Deborah Hellman, Daniel Hemel, Hayes Holderness, Bradley Joondeph, Kurt Lash,
Julia Mahoney, Orly Mazur, Susan Morse, Daniel Ortiz, Miranda Perry Fleischer, Saikrishna
Prakash, Mildred Robinson, Emily Satterthwaite, Lawrence Solum, Paul Stephan, Adam Thim-
mesch, Pierre-Hugues Verdier, Clint Wallace, and workshop participants at NYU, Richmond
University, the University of California at Irvine, the University of Florida, and the University of
Virginia.
February 2023 Vol. 91 No. 1
1
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 2 24-FEB-23 14:13
2 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
T
ABLE OF
C
ONTENTS
I
NTRODUCTION
................................................. 3
R
I. T
HE
D
ORMANT
C
OMMERCE
C
LAUSE AND
I
TS
C
RITICS
............................................. 10
R
A. The Dormant Commerce Clause .................... 10
R
B. Criticisms of Dormant Commerce
Clause Doctrine ..................................... 14
R
II. R
EFRAMING
T
HE
D
ORMANT
C
OMMERCE
C
LAUSE
...... 15
R
A. Defining Types of Burdens.......................... 17
R
1. Symmetrical Versus Asymmetrical Burdens ..... 17
R
2. Single-State Versus Mismatch Burdens ......... 17
R
B. Single-State Burdens and Pike Balancing ............ 20
R
1. Facially Discriminatory Regulations ............ 20
R
2. Facially Neutral Regulations .................... 21
R
a. Pike v. Bruce Church (1970)................ 22
R
b. H. P. Hood & Sons, Inc. v.
Du Mond (1949) ............................ 23
R
c. Dean Milk Co. v. City of
Madison (1951) ............................. 24
R
d. Bendix Autolite Corp. v. Midwesco
Enterprises, Inc. (1988) ..................... 25
R
e. C & A Carbone, Inc. v. Town of
Clarkstown (1994) .......................... 26
R
f. Lloyd A. Fry Roofing Co. v.
Wood (1952) ................................ 27
R
3. Understanding Single-State Cases .............. 27
R
C. Mismatch Burdens and Bibb Balancing ............. 29
R
1. Cases ........................................... 29
R
a. Intentionally Protectionist Mismatches....... 29
R
i. Florida Lime & Avocado Growers, Inc.
v. Paul (1963)........................... 30
R
ii. Hunt v. Washington State Apple
Advertising Commission (1977) ......... 31
R
b. Nonprotectionist, or Arguably
Nonprotectionist, Mismatches ............... 33
R
i. Nonintervention ........................ 34
R
1. State Highway Department v.
Barnwell Bros., Inc. (1938)......... 34
R
2. Moorman Manufacturing Co. v.
Bair (1978) ......................... 35
R
ii. Intervention ............................ 37
R
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 3 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 3
1. Southern Pacific v.
Arizona (1945) ..................... 38
R
2. Bibb v. Navajo Freight
Lines (1959)........................ 39
R
3. Kassel v. Consolidated Freightways
Corp. of Delaware (1981) .......... 40
R
4. Minnesota v. Clover Leaf Creamery
Co. (1981).......................... 41
R
2. Understanding Mismatch Cases ................. 43
R
III. T
HE
S
PECIAL
P
ROBLEMS OF
B
IBB
B
ALANCING
.......... 44
R
A. Judicial Intervention or Nonintervention ............ 45
R
1. Relative Consensus in Single-State Cases ....... 45
R
2. Unsettled Approach to Mismatch Cases ........ 46
R
a. Noninterventionist View ..................... 46
R
b. Interventionist View ......................... 49
R
3. Comparing Intervention in Single-State and
Mismatch Cases................................. 51
R
B. Benchmarking ...................................... 54
R
1. Single-State Cases .............................. 55
R
2. Mismatch Cases................................. 55
R
3. Comparing Benchmarking in Single-State and
Mismatch Cases................................. 57
R
C. Judicial Legislation ................................. 59
R
D. Complexity of Balancing ............................ 62
R
IV. T
HE
F
UTURE OF
M
ISMATCH
C
ASES UNDER THE
D
ORMANT
C
OMMERCE
C
LAUSE
......................... 64
R
A. A Current Example: Cage-Free Eggs ................ 65
R
B. Reforming Bibb Balancing .......................... 67
R
C. Alternatives to Bibb Balancing ...................... 68
R
1. Mutual Recognition and Harmonization ........ 68
R
2. Requiring “National Treatment” for
“Like Products” ................................ 72
R
3. Focusing Exclusively on Legislative Intent ...... 74
R
C
ONCLUSION
................................................... 76
R
I
NTRODUCTION
Every law student learns that the dormant Commerce Clause has
two major doctrinal strands—discrimination and undue burden. The
doctrinal test for the latter involves balancing the burden a state im-
poses on interstate commerce against the state’s legitimate interest in
the challenged regulation. This balancing test has become synony-
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 4 24-FEB-23 14:13
4 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
mous with Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc.,
1
although it is actually much
older.
2
For decades, commentators and jurists have condemned Pike
balancing. Justice Scalia likened it to “judging whether a particular
line is longer than a particular rock is heavy.”
3
He also declared bal-
ancing a “quagmire”
4
that was “ill suited to the judicial function.”
5
Justice Rehnquist complained that balancing “gives no guidance what-
soever to . . . [s]tates as to whether their laws are valid or how to
defend them.”
6
Those criticisms find expression in today’s Supreme Court. For
example, Justice Thomas concluded that, because Pike balancing turns
“solely on policy considerations,” it involves legislative, not judicial,
decision-making.
7
Lower courts have likewise remarked that such bal-
ancing is subjective and challenging to apply.
8
Heaping scorn upon
Pike balancing, commentators have called it “fundamentally wrong,”
9
1
397 U.S. 137 (1970).
2
See Brannon P. Denning, Reconstructing the Dormant Commerce Clause Doctrine, 50
W
M
. & M
ARY
L. R
EV
. 417, 445–46 (2008) [hereinafter Denning, Reconstructing] (describing
Southern Pacific Co. v. Ariz. ex rel. Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761 (1945), as “the paradigmatic balancing
opinion”). Id. at 445 n.150 (tracing balancing back to Baldwin v. G. A. F. Seelig, Inc., 294 U.S.
511 (1935)).
3
Bendix Autolite Corp. v. Midwesco Enters., Inc., 486 U.S. 888, 897 (1988) (Scalia, J.,
concurring).
4
W. Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy, 512 U.S. 186, 210 (1994) (Scalia, J., concurring)
(“[O]nce one gets beyond facial discrimination our negative-Commerce-Clause jurisprudence
becomes (and long has been) a quagmire.”).
5
CTS Corp. v. Dynamics Corp. of Am., 481 U.S. 69, 95 (1987) (Scalia, J., concurring in
part).
6
Kassel v. Consol. Freightways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 706 (1981) (Rehnquist, J., dissent-
ing). Id. at 706 (calling the doctrine “hopelessly confused”).
7
United Haulers Ass’n, Inc. v. Oneida-Herkimer Solid Waste Mgmt. Auth., 550 U.S. 330,
349 (2007) (Thomas, J., concurring in the judgment); see also Camps Newfound/Owatonna, Inc.
v. Town of Harrison, 520 U.S. 564, 619 (1997) (Thomas, J., dissenting) (suggesting that such
balancing “surely invites us, if not compels us, to function more as legislators than as judges”);
id. at 610 (concluding that the doctrine “makes little sense, and has proved virtually unworkable
in application”). In Department of Revenue of Kentucky v. Davis, 553 U.S. 328, 354 (2008), a
majority of the Court questioned whether courts are capable of such balancing.
8
Colon Health Ctrs. of Am., LLC v. Hazel, 813 F.3d 145, 155 (4th Cir. 2016) (“highly
subjective”); Am. Beverage Ass’n v. Snyder, 735 F.3d 362, 379 (6th Cir. 2013) (Sutton, J., concur-
ring) (“ineffable test”); Nat’l Ass’n of Optometrists & Opticians v. Harris, 682 F.3d 1144, 1149
(9th Cir. 2012) (balancing has “not turned out to be easy to apply”); Wiesmueller v. Kosobucki,
571 F.3d 699, 704 (7th Cir. 2009) (“The judiciary lacks the time and the knowledge to be able to
strike a fine balance between the burden that a particular state regulation lays on interstate
commerce and the benefit of that regulation to the state’s legitimate interests.”); Pharm. Rsch. &
Mfrs. of Am. v. Concannon, 249 F.3d 66, 84 (1st Cir. 2001) (finding the “balancing test more
challenging to apply”).
9
Julian N. Eule, Laying the Dormant Commerce Clause to Rest, 91 Y
ALE
L.J. 425, 436
(1982). (“[T]he likelihood of judicial invalidation increases with the degree of burden imposed
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 5 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 5
a “historical vestige[],”
10
plagued by “severe conceptual problems,”
11
incoherent and inconsistent,
12
“seriously flawed,”
13
“illegitimate,”
14
“reviled,”
15
and “a disaster.”
16
Whereas a solid majority of the current Supreme Court supports
the discrimination strand of the dormant Commerce Clause,
17
it is not
clear where the Court stands on undue burdens.
18
Although the Su-
by state law . . . . There is something fundamentally wrong with a judicial framework that
prompts judicial intervention by the same trigger that induces political response.”).
10
Id. at 435.
11
Earl M. Maltz, How Much Regulation Is Too Much—An Examination of Commerce
Clause Jurisprudence, 50 G
EO
. W
ASH
. L. R
EV
. 47, 59 (1981).
12
Denning, Reconstructing, supra note 2, at 417. R
13
Jack L. Goldsmith & Alan O. Sykes, The Internet and the Dormant Commerce Clause,
110 Y
ALE
L.J. 785, 813 (2001).
14
Martin H. Redish & Shane V. Nugent, The Dormant Commerce Clause and the Consti-
tutional Balance of Federalism, 1987 D
UKE
L.J. 569, 599 (1987).
15
Brannon P. Denning, Justice Thomas, The Import-Export Clause, and Camps New-
found/Owatonna v. Harrison, 70 U. C
OLO
. L. R
EV
. 155, 156–57 (1999) [hereinafter Denning,
Justice Thomas] (“Almost universally reviled by academics and Justices on the Supreme Court as
without solid foundation in text or intent, and altogether lacking a coherent application, it never-
theless endures and continues to be employed by the Court, when its members are not busy
criticizing it.” (citations omitted)).
16
Richard B. Collins, Economic Union as a Constitutional Value, 63 N.Y.U. L. R
EV
. 43, 45
n.14 (1988) (quoting D
AVID
P. C
URRIE
, T
HE
C
ONSTITUTION IN THE
S
UPREME
C
OURT
: T
HE
F
IRST
H
UNDRED
Y
EARS
1789-1888, at 342 (1985)); id. at 44 n.14 (skeptically noting arguments against
the dormant Commerce Clause made by David Currie). For other leading critical accounts, see
generally, Mark Tushnet, Rethinking the Dormant Commerce Clause, 1979 W
IS
. L. R
EV
. 125
(1979); Saul Levmore, Interstate Exploitation and Judicial Intervention, 69 V
A
. L. R
EV
. 563
(1983); Donald H. Regan, The Supreme Court and State Protectionism: Making Sense of the
Dormant Commerce Clause, 84 M
ICH
. L. R
EV
. 1091 (1986); Michael E. Smith, State Discrimina-
tions Against Interstate Commerce, 74 C
AL
. L. R
EV
. 1203 (1986); Paul E. McGreal, The Flawed
Economics of the Dormant Commerce Clause, 39 W
M
. & M
ARY
L. R
EV
. 1191 (1998); Barry
Cushman, Formalism and Realism in Commerce Clause Jurisprudence, 67 U. C
HI
. L. R
EV
. 1089
(2000).
17
See infra note 51. R
18
The paucity of undue-burden decisions makes it difficult to discern the views of the
sitting Justices, which are discussed here in order of seniority, after describing the views of the
Chief Justice. Chief Justice Roberts did not join the part of United Haulers that applied Pike. See
United Haulers Ass’n v. Oneida-Herkimer Solid Waste Mgmt. Auth., 550 U.S. 330, 334 (2007).
At the same time, however, the part of the decision he authored and signed involved balancing
under the dormant Commerce Clause. See id. at 342 (weighing the state’s nonprotectionist inter-
est in the challenged ordinance that required waste to be disposed only at a public facility).
Justice Thomas’s opposition to all aspects of the dormant Commerce Clause is well-known and
unlikely to change. See, e.g., Comptroller of the Treasury of Md. v. Wynne, 575 U.S. 542, 578
(2015) (Thomas, J., dissenting). Justice Alito would adhere to dormant Commerce Clause prece-
dent. See Dep’t of Revenue of Ky. v. Davis, 553 U.S. 328, 376 (2008) (Alito, J., dissenting)
(“[T]he Court’s established dormant Commerce Clause precedents should be followed . . . .”).
Justice Alito joined Justice Kennedy’s dissent in Davis that argued that “[t]he undue burden
rule . . . remains an essential safeguard against restrictive laws that might otherwise be in force
for decades until Congress can act.” Id. at 365, 376 (Kennedy, J., dissenting). In 2018, the major-
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 6 24-FEB-23 14:13
6 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
preme Court referenced Pike favorably in 2018,
19
it has not invali-
dated a state statute under Pike for “a generation,”
20
and Justice
Thomas has even called for the termination of undue-burden
analysis.
21
At a time when important undue-burden cases are pending,
22
we
clarify the dormant Commerce Clause and Pike balancing. We also
provide principled methods to cabin judicial discretion in undue-bur-
den cases as an alternative to abandoning this vital constitutional doc-
trine. This Article thus constitutes a rare defense of a doctrinal area
that has been excoriated as both illegitimate and unclear, including by
members of the Court itself.
Courts and commentators divide dormant Commerce Clause doc-
trine into facial discrimination cases and undue-burden cases. Laws
ity in South Dakota v. Wayfair cited Pike as the applicable standard in dormant Commerce
Clause cases. See South Dakota v. Wayfair, Inc., 138 S. Ct. 2080, 2091 (2018). Although Justices
Sotomayor and Kagan joined Chief Justice Roberts’ dissent in Wayfair, that dissent was
grounded on the view that the Court should have hewed to precedent in Wayfair and not over-
turned a prior case. The dissenters therefore did not address Pike or the standard in undue-
burdens cases at all. See id. at 2101–05 (Roberts, C.J., dissenting); see also Edward A. Zelinsky,
Comparing Wayfair and Wynne: Lessons for the Future of the Dormant Commerce Clause, 22
C
HAP
. L. R
EV
. 55, 58 (2019) (arguing that despite dissenting in Wayfair, none of Roberts,
Breyer, Sotomayor, or Kagan “dispute[d] the fundamental legitimacy of the dormant Commerce
Clause”). That all three of Roberts, Sotomayor, and Kagan joined the 2019 majority decision in
Tennessee Wine to preclude a facially discriminatory state regulation for violating the dormant
Commerce Clause confirms Professor Zelinsky’s claim that those Justices continue to respect the
fundamental legitimacy of the dormant Commerce Clause, but it does not indicate those Justices’
views on the undue-burden doctrine specifically, as opposed to the nondiscrimination doctrine.
See Tenn. Wine & Spirits Retailers Ass’n v. Thomas, 139 S. Ct. 2449, 2456 (2019). Justice Gor-
such concurred in Wayfair, but he emphasized that his “agreement with the Court’s discussion of
the history of our dormant commerce clause jurisprudence . . . should not be mistaken for agree-
ment with all aspects of the doctrine.” Wayfair, 138 S. Ct. at 2100 (Gorsuch, J., concurring). At
the time this Article went to press, the views of Justices Kavanaugh, Barrett, and Jackson on
Pike were unknown.
19
The majority in Wayfair cited Pike as the applicable standard in undue-burden cases.
Wayfair, 138 S. Ct. at 2091. Justice Kennedy wrote the majority opinion, which Justices Thomas,
Ginsburg, Alito, and Gorsuch joined. Id. at 2087. Perhaps reflecting a perception of the obsoles-
cence of Pike, of the forty-seven amicus and party briefs filed in Wayfair, only five, including our
amicus, discussed Pike. See Brief of Brill, Knoll, Mason & Viard in Support of Petitioner at 3,
17–20, South Dakota v. Wayfair, Inc., 138 S. Ct. 2080 (2018) (No. 17-494).
20
B
ORIS
I. B
ITTKER
&B
RANNON
P. D
ENNING
, B
ITTKER ON THE
R
EGULATION OF
I
NTER-
STATE AND
F
OREIGN
C
OMMERCE
§ 6.05 (Aspen Publishers 2022) (2d ed. 2013) (citing Edgar v.
MITE Corp., 457 U.S. 624 (1982) as the last time such preclusion occurred). Lower courts, how-
ever, regularly engage in such balancing and at times do invalidate state laws on such grounds.
Id. (“Pike balancing is, however, alive and well in the lower courts.”).
21
See Wynne, 575 U.S. at 578.
22
See, e.g., Nat’l Pork Producers Council v. Ross, 6 F.4th 1021, 1025 (9th Cir. 2021), cert.
granted, 142 S. Ct. 1413 (2022) (challenging, under the dormant Commerce Clause, California’s
food product regulations that are stricter than those of other states).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 7 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 7
that overtly treat cross-border commerce worse than in-state com-
merce are facially discriminatory and presumptively unconstitu-
tional.
23
In contrast, courts examine facially neutral regulations for
whether they impose undue burdens on cross-border commerce; that
is, facially neutral regulations are ostensibly subject to Pike balancing.
Although commentators have provided coherent explanations for the
nondiscrimination strand of the dormant Commerce Clause, they have
struggled to understand undue burdens. Rather than focusing on the
discrimination cases, which are well understood and well justified, this
Article focuses on the harder undue-burden cases.
24
Augmenting the
traditional discrimination/undue-burden dichotomy, we offer a more
nuanced account. Our account considers not only whether the chal-
lenged regulation explicitly discriminates, but also the type of burden
the regulation imposes. We identify two types of burdens (or costs) on
interstate commerce: (1) those arising from a single state’s law, and
(2) those arising from interactions—more specifically, mismatches
among two or more states’ laws.
Single-state burdens arise when—irrespective of what other states
do—a regulation impedes interstate commerce relative to in-state
commerce. Thus, all facially discriminatory regulations impose single-
state burdens; the excess burden on interstate commerce arises from
the application of the challenged state’s law alone.
Facially neutral regulations, in turn, can impose single-state or
mismatch burdens. Consider the regulation challenged in Pike. In
Pike, Arizona required cantaloupes grown in Arizona also to be
packed there.
25
In our terms, this constituted a single-state burden be-
cause it did not depend on the packing regulations applicable in other
states; instead, the burden arose from Arizona law alone. In balancing
23
Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322, 337 (1979) (“[F]acial discrimination invokes the
strictest scrutiny.”).
24
For example, in his leading account of the dormant Commerce Clause, which garners
over 600 citations in Westlaw, Donald Regan argues that the Supreme Court decides dormant
Commerce Clause cases by reference to a simple question: Was the state motivated to pass the
challenged rule by intentional protectionism? If so, the Court strikes it down, and if not, the
Court upholds it. See Regan, supra note 16. Regan noted, however, that many cases did not seem R
to fit into this paradigm, and so he excluded those cases from his analysis. See id. at 1104 (cabin-
ing cases in which “genuine national interests other than the interest in avoiding state protec-
tionism” are at stake). This Article argues that certain undue-burden cases, namely, those
involving regulatory diversity, are not necessarily about protectionism, and so they cannot be
explained by a paradigm that relies exclusively on the presence or absence of intentional protec-
tionism. See discussion infra Section III.A.2.
25
Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 138, 142 (1970) (noting that rule challenged
was “even-handed[]”).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 8 24-FEB-23 14:13
8 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
in Pike, the Supreme Court thus examined only Arizona law, an ap-
proach we refer to as using an internal benchmark.
26
Mismatch burdens, in contrast, arise from the interaction of mul-
tiple states’ laws.
27
The defining feature of a mismatch burden is that
the presence or absence of similar regulation by other states does af-
fect the cost to comply with the first state’s regulation. The paradig-
matic mismatch case was Bibb v. Navajo Freight Lines, Inc.,
28
in which
the Supreme Court precluded an Illinois law that required trucks on
Illinois highways to have curved mudflaps at a time when other states
permitted or required trucks to have straight mudflaps. As a result of
the differences in the content of these regulations, trucks with straight
mudflaps traveling interstate had to divert around Illinois or, if they
wanted to enter Illinois, switch to curved mudflaps at the state bor-
der.
29
Although the Supreme Court purports to use Pike balancing in
both single-state and mismatch cases—indeed, the Court does not ex-
pressly distinguish the two types of cases—this Article shows that the
Supreme Court’s approach to each type of case differs substantially.
Specifically, in mismatch cases, the Court uses external benchmarks
consisting of other states’ laws to measure both the burden on inter-
state commerce and the challenged state’s regulatory interest. In Bibb,
for example, the Supreme Court understood the burden on interstate
commerce to arise from Illinois’s departure from the straight-mudflap
rule applicable in other states.
30
Likewise, in defending its deviating
rule, Illinois had to show that its curved-mudflap requirement pro-
duced a significant safety gain over and above that from the straight
mudflaps permitted on roads in other states.
31
As this Article explains,
such a posture can place a heavy burden on innovating states.
One purpose of this Article is simply to recognize that the Su-
preme Court uses different baselines for evaluating single-state and
mismatch cases; namely, it uses internal benchmarks in single-state
cases, whereas it uses external benchmarks consisting of other states’
laws in mismatch cases. Dividing cases into those imposing single-state
or mismatch burdens helps to explain dormant Commerce Clause doc-
trine—it represents an improvement over the traditional discrimina-
26
See id. at 142.
27
The Supreme Court sometimes refers to “inconsistent” regulations. See CTS Corp. v.
Dynamics Corp. of Am., 481 U.S. 69, 88 (1987). We refer to “mismatches” to convey neutrality
about the constitutional status of such regulations.
28
359 U.S. 520 (1959).
29
Id. at 527–28.
30
Id. at 529–30.
31
Id. at 523–24.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 9 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 9
tion/undue-burden dichotomy and allows us to better understand the
hard cases.
Armed with our doctrinal reframing, this Article also offers criti-
cisms of judicial review in mismatch cases. First, the Supreme Court
has not taken a consistent approach in mismatch cases. For example,
at times, the Supreme Court refuses to intervene at all in mismatch
cases on the grounds that courts lack institutional competence to pre-
clude regulatory diversity.
32
Other times, the Court intervenes in mis-
match cases on the theory that it is a duty of the Court to preclude
state laws that otherwise would segment, or “Balkanize,“ the national
marketplace.
33
Such doctrinal inconsistency generates justified claims
of arbitrariness, and it stands in stark contrast with the Supreme
Court’s approach to single-state cases. The justices generally agree
about whether and how to analyze single-state cases, although they
sometimes disagree about the proper outcome of that analysis.
Second, in any case in which the Supreme Court decides to inter-
vene to analyze a mismatch, it must then choose external benchmarks
against which to measure both the burden on interstate commerce and
the challenged state’s interest. But justices do not always agree on the
proper external benchmarks. Benchmark selection thus also generates
claims of arbitrariness.
34
Third, mismatch cases are more susceptible than are single-state
cases to charges of “judicial legislation.” The reason for this has to do
with how states cure constitutional violations. The remedy in any dor-
mant Commerce Clause case is preclusion, but preclusion takes on
special meaning in mismatch cases. Specifically, when the Supreme
Court precludes a mismatch burden, that preclusion may implicitly en-
dorse the regulation that the Court used as the external benchmark in
the case. Thus, this Article argues that mismatch cases may have the
practical effect of imposing harmonized substantive rules. Consider
Bibb. Although the formal remedy in Bibb was preclusion of Illinois’s
curved-mudflap rule, the implication of the Court’s decision was clear;
32
See, e.g., S.C. State Highway Dep’t v. Barnwell Bros., Inc., 303 U.S. 177, 195–96 (1938).
33
See, e.g., Bibb, 359 U.S. at 527 (emphasizing a need for national uniformity); see also
Tenn. Wine & Spirits Retailers Ass’n v. Thomas, 139 S. Ct. 2449, 2461 (2019) (noting a “central
concern of the Framers that was an immediate reason for calling the Constitutional Convention:
the conviction that in order to succeed, the new Union would have to avoid the tendencies
toward economic Balkanization that had plagued relations among the Colonies and later among
the States under the Articles of Confederation.” (quoting Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322,
325–26 (1979))).
34
See infra Section III.A.2.a (discussing Justice Rehnquist’s criticism of the selection of
the benchmark in Kassel).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 10 24-FEB-23 14:13
10 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
Illinois had to conform to the mudflap rules of neighboring states, a
phenomenon we refer to as harmonization by preclusion.
35
In con-
trast, in single-state cases, the typical remedy involves desisting appli-
cation of the offending regulation—as in Pikeor equalizing the
treatment of in-state and interstate economic actors—as in facial dis-
crimination cases—but it need not lead to harmonization. This Article
also gives reasons why judicial intervention in mismatch cases is more
likely than judicial intervention in single-state cases to lead to
deregulation.
36
Fourth, this Article demonstrates that because more constitu-
tional values are at stake in mismatch cases than in single-state cases,
mismatch cases are generally harder to resolve.
This Article proceeds as follows: Part I provides background on
and criticisms of the dormant Commerce Clause. Part II reframes the
dormant Commerce Clause by supplementing the discrimination-ver-
sus-undue-burden distinction with a distinction that looks to the type
of burden—single-state or mismatchimposed by the challenged reg-
ulation. Our framework augments, but does not supplant, the discrim-
ination-versus-undue-burden dichotomy. Part III compares mismatch
and single-state cases, explaining why certain well-known criticisms of
the dormant Commerce Clause apply with more force to mismatch
cases than to single-state cases. Part IV applies our new doctrinal
framework to a pending case to illustrate that mismatch cases raise
questions—such as which state’s rule prevails in cases of conflict? and
who decides?that go to the core of federalism. Part IV also offers
suggestions for how the Supreme Court could minimize the adverse
impacts of mismatch cases, without completely refusing to consider
them.
I. T
HE
D
ORMANT
C
OMMERCE
C
LAUSE AND
I
TS
C
RITICS
A. The Dormant Commerce Clause
The Commerce Clause of the Constitution grants Congress the
power “[t]o regulate Commerce with foreign Nations, and among the
several States, and with the Indian Tribes.”
37
The Supreme Court has
interpreted the Commerce Clause to express not only an affirmative
35
Bibb, 359 U.S. at 530 (observing that “a new safety device—out of line with the require-
ments of the other States—may be so compelling that [Illinois] need not be the one to give
way. . . . [T]he present showing—balanced against the clear burden on commerce—is far too
inconclusive to make [Illinois’s] mudguard meet that test.”).
36
See infra Section III.C.
37
U.S. C
ONST
. art. I, § 8, cl. 3.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 11 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 11
grant of power to Congress, but also an implicit restraint on the
states.
38
For two centuries, the Supreme Court has employed this
“dormant” aspect of the Commerce Clause to strike a balance be-
tween state and federal interests.
39
The relevant state interest is regulatory autonomy. Autonomy en-
ables states to govern flexibly, satisfy preferences, and act as laborato-
ries of democracy.
40
The Court has identified various national and
federal interests that limit state regulatory autonomy; for example, the
Court often refers to free-trade values, such as “preserv[ing] ‘the free
flow of interstate commerce.’
41
In the Court’s view, forbidding pro-
tectionism by states is union-preserving because it prevents “rivalries
and dislocations and reprisals”
42
that would “threaten at once the
peace and safety of the Union.”
43
Moreover, the Supreme Court has
interpreted the dormant Commerce Clause to protect out-of-state po-
litical interests that are not directly represented in the regulating
state’s political process, a concept sometimes called representation re-
inforcement.
44
Importantly for this Article, the Court also has cited
risks that state regulations might segment—or “Balkanize”
45
—the na-
38
Gibbons v. Ogden, 22 U.S. (9 Wheat.) 1, 13–14 (1824).
39
For a history of the dormant Commerce Clause, see Denning, Reconstructing, supra
note 2, at 421, 427–48. R
40
Gregory v. Ashcroft, 501 U.S. 452, 458 (1991) (reciting federalism values); Dep’t of
Revenue of Ky. v. Davis, 553 U.S. 328, 338 (2008) (“[T]he Framers’ distrust of economic Balkan-
ization was limited by their federalism favoring a degree of local autonomy.”).
41
South Dakota v. Wayfair, Inc., 138 S. Ct. 2080, 2090 (2018) (quoting S. Pac. Co. v. Ariz.
ex rel. Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761, 770 (1945)).
42
H. P. Hood & Sons, Inc. v. Du Mond, 336 U.S. 525, 539 (1949).
43
Id. at 533. See generally Collins, supra note 16 (focusing on the dormant Commerce R
Clause’s role in forging economic union).
44
See, e.g., Southern Pacific, 325 U.S. at 767–68, n.2 (“[T]he Court has often recognized
that to the extent that the burden of state regulation falls on interests outside the state, it is
unlikely to be alleviated by the operation of those political restraints normally exerted when
interests within the state are affected.”); Hood, 336 U.S. at 539 (“[E]very consumer may look to
the free competition from every producing area in the Nation to protect him from exploitation
by any.”). For commentary, see, e.g., Eule, supra note 9, at 428, 435 (discussing representation R
reinforcement); see also J
OHN
H
ART
E
LY
, D
EMOCRACY AND
D
ISTRUST
: A T
HEORY OF
J
UDICIAL
R
EVIEW
83 (1980) (describing the dormant Commerce Clause as needed “to protect the politi-
cally powerless”); Tushnet, supra note 16, at 133 (observing that, in addition to outsiders, “the R
general consumer interest is at a systematic disadvantage in legislative combat against organized
groups”).
45
The first reference to Balkanization by the Supreme Court was in a concurrence in
Duckworth v. Arkansas, 314 U.S. 390, 400 (1941) (Jackson, J., concurring) (“The practical result
is that in default of action by us [state regulations] will go on suffocating and retarding and
Balkanizing American commerce, trade and industry.”). The first mention of Balkanization in
the majority of a dormant Commerce Clause case was in 1979 in Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S.
322, 325–26 (1979) (noting the Framers’ “conviction that in order to succeed, the new Union
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 12 24-FEB-23 14:13
12 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
tional market. Emphasizing the need for “national uniformity” in reg-
ulation, the Court at times has interpreted the dormant Commerce
Clause to preclude market-segmenting regulations.
46
At other times,
the Court declared it inappropriate to intervene to prevent states from
enacting market-segmenting laws.
Given the vital, but often opposing, interests at stake in dormant
Commerce Clause cases, it is perhaps no surprise that judicial stan-
dards in them have evolved over time.
47
Modern doctrine sees two
principal types of challenges: facial discrimination and undue bur-
dens.
48
Facial discrimination involves explicit distinctions between in-
state and out-of-state economic actors or between in-state and inter-
state commerce. When states expressly discriminate, their regulations
receive strict scrutiny.
49
Although some commentators criticize facial
discrimination doctrine,
50
nearly all accept it as either consistent with
our overall federal structure and the vision of the Constitution’s foun-
ders, or applicable as a matter of precedent, or both.
51
would have to avoid the tendencies toward economic Balkanization that had plagued relations
among the Colonies and later among the States under the Articles of Confederation”). Id. at 326
(citing similar analysis, in Hood, 336 U.S. at 533–34, that did not employ the term “balkaniza-
tion”). The Court’s most recent use of the term was in 2019 in Tennessee Wine & Spirits Retailers
Ass’n v. Thomas, 139 S. Ct. 2449, 2461 (2019) (quoting Hughes, 441 U.S. at 325–26). The Court
has employed the term in a number of other instances. See Camps Newfound/Owatonna, Inc. v.
Town of Harrison, 520 U.S. 564, 577 (1997) (“Avoiding this sort of ‘economic balkanization,’ and
the retaliatory acts of other States that may follow, is one of the central purposes of our negative
Commerce Clause jurisprudence.” (citation omitted)); Fulton Corp. v. Faulkner, 516 U.S. 325,
333 n.3 (1996) (referring to “‘economic Balkanization’ that our dormant Commerce Clause juris-
prudence has long sought to prevent”); Bacchus Imports, Ltd. v. Dias, 468 U.S. 263, 276 (1984)
(“It is also beyond doubt that the Commerce Clause itself furthers strong federal interests in
preventing economic Balkanization.”).
46
See, e.g., Bibb v. Navajo Freight Lines, Inc., 359 U.S. 520, 527 (1959) (quoting Morgan v.
Virginia, 328 U.S. 373, 386 (1946)).
47
See Denning, Reconstructing, supra note 2, at 427–48 (giving history of dormant Com- R
merce Clause jurisprudence).
48
South Dakota v. Wayfair, Inc., 138 S. Ct. 2080, 2090–91 (2018) (“Modern precedents
rest upon two primary principles that mark the boundaries of a State’s authority to regulate
interstate commerce. First, state regulations may not discriminate against interstate commerce;
and second, States may not impose undue burdens on interstate commerce. State laws that dis-
criminate against interstate commerce face ‘a virtually per se rule of invalidity.’ State laws that
‘regulate[] even-handedly to effectuate a legitimate local public interest . . . will be upheld unless
the burden imposed on such commerce is clearly excessive in relation to the putative local bene-
fits.’” (citation omitted) (first quoting Granholm v. Heald, 544 U.S. 460, 476 (2005); then quoting
Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 142 (1970))). Other dormant Commerce Clause chal-
lenges involve nexus and extraterritoriality, doctrines this Article does not consider.
49
See, e.g., id.
50
See generally McGreal, supra note 16 (arguing that courts should not strike even facially R
discriminatory state laws in areas where in-state and out-of-state commerce do not compete).
51
Direct Mktg. Ass’n v. Brohl, 814 F.3d 1129, 1150 (10th Cir. 2016) (Gorsuch, J., concur-
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 13 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 13
A state law that does not facially discriminate may nevertheless
violate the dormant Commerce Clause by imposing an “undue bur-
den” on interstate commerce. For the better part of a century, undue-
burdens analysis has involved judicial balancing.
52
The modern
description of this balancing derives from Pike v. Bruce Church:
Where the statute regulates even-handedly to effectuate a le-
gitimate local public interest, and its effects on interstate
commerce are only incidental, it will be upheld unless the
burden imposed on such commerce is clearly excessive in re-
lation to the putative local benefits. If a legitimate local pur-
pose is found, then the question becomes one of degree. And
the extent of the burden that will be tolerated will of course
depend on the nature of the local interest involved, and on
whether it could be promoted as well with a lesser impact on
interstate activities.
53
Ultimately, judges have the same goals when they apply undue-
burden analysis as when they apply nondiscrimination analysis,
namely, to weigh national and federal interests against state interests.
But whereas facially discriminatory regulations rarely survive dormant
Commerce Clause analysis, courts regularly uphold statutes against
claims that they unduly burden interstate commerce. The Supreme
Court has not always been clear about why it permitted or precluded
ring) (“And to the extent that there’s anything that’s uncontroversial about dormant commerce
clause jurisprudence it may be this anti-discrimination principle, for even critics of dormant com-
merce clause doctrine often endorse it even as they suggest it might find a more textually com-
fortable home in other constitutional provisions.”). In Tennessee Wine, Justices Alito, Breyer,
Ginsburg, Kagan, Kavanaugh, Sotomayor, and Chief Justice Roberts joined in precluding a
facially discriminatory state regulation for violating the dormant Commerce Clause. 139 S. Ct.
2449, 2456, 2476 (2019). Justices Gorsuch and Thomas dissented. Justice Gorsuch dissented be-
cause he concluded that the Twenty-first Amendment immunized the challenged regulation from
dormant Commerce Clause review. Id. at 2484 (Gorsuch, J., dissenting). Even as he has con-
curred in judgments applying the dormant Commerce Clause, Justice Gorsuch has expressed
skepticism about it. See Wayfair, 138 S. Ct. at 2100–01 (2018) (Gorsuch, J., concurring)
(“Whether and how much of this can be squared with the text of the Commerce Clause, justified
by stare decisis, or defended as misbranded products of federalism or antidiscrimination impera-
tives flowing from Article IV’s Privileges and Immunities Clause are questions for another
day.”). Justice Thomas opposes all aspects of the dormant Commerce Clause on grounds of its
atextuality. See, e.g., Comptroller of the Treasury of Md. v. Wynne, 575 U.S. 542, 578 (2015)
(Thomas, J., dissenting) (“I continue to adhere to my view that the negative Commerce
Clause . . . cannot serve as a basis for striking down a state statute.” (quoting McBurney v.
Young, 569 U.S. 221, 237 (2013) (Thomas, J., concurring))). Since Tennessee Wine, Justice Bar-
rett filled the seat of the late Justice Ginsburg, and Justice Jackson filled the seat of retired
Justice Breyer. As discussed supra note 18, their views as justices on dormant Commerce Clause R
doctrine are not yet known.
52
See Denning, Reconstructing, supra note 2, at 443–45 (tracing balancing back to 1938). R
53
Pike, 397 U.S. at 142 (citation omitted).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 14 24-FEB-23 14:13
14 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
particular “even-handed” regulations under its undue-burdens stan-
dard.
54
As the next Section explains, this lack of clarity has generated
significant criticism.
B. Criticisms of Dormant Commerce Clause Doctrine
This Section reviews criticisms of the dormant Commerce Clause.
Although some—including Justice Thomas—have argued that the
dormant Commerce Clause is illegitimate because it lacks a sufficient
textual basis,
55
this Article focuses on criticisms lodged by those who,
although they accept dormant Commerce Clause doctrine in principle,
argue that the Court’s approach to deciding cases is deficient. The
main criticisms are that the doctrine is arbitrary and invites courts to
act as legislatures.
Discrimination against interstate commerce has a clear intuitive
meaning, but the idea of “undue burdens” does not. Critics—on and
off the bench—complain that Pike balancing usurps the legislative
role by encouraging judges to indulge their own preferences when de-
ciding whether to uphold or to preclude a state regulation.
56
Justice
Scalia, for instance, disparaged the analysis as “ad hocery.”
57
And a
persistent frustration with undue-burdens doctrine is that seemingly
similar cases garner sharply different outcomes. For example, in one
case, the Supreme Court held that a state that imposed more stringent
truck length limits than did neighboring states unduly burdened inter-
state commerce, but in another, it held that a state that imposed more
stringent truck weight limits than did neighboring states did not vio-
late the dormant Commerce Clause.
58
Despite criticisms of arbitrariness, there are some settled doc-
trines. As Donald Regan observed in his seminal 1986 article criticiz-
ing the dormant Commerce Clause, many cases boil down to the
question of whether the state enacted a regulation with protectionist
54
For examples, see infra Part II; see also B
ITTKER
& D
ENNING
, supra note 20. R
55
See Denning, Justice Thomas, supra note 15, at 157–59 (discussing views of Justice R
Thomas).
56
See supra notes 4–16 (describing criticisms). R
57
Comptroller of the Treasury of Md. v. Wynne, 575 U.S. 542, 574 (2015) (Scalia, J., dis-
senting); see also Denning, Reconstructing, supra note 2, at 422 (describing “cases with similar R
facts being decided differently, and the different outcomes justified on the basis of tendentious
distinctions.”).
58
Compare Kassel v. Consol. Freightways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 677–79 (1981) (precluding
a state from deviating from the truck-length rule implemented in contiguous states), with S.C.
State Highway Dep’t v. Barnwell Bros., Inc., 303 U.S. 177, 195–96 (1938) (upholding ability of
state to maintain truck width and weight limits that differed from those of neighboring states).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 15 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 15
intent.
59
Although an express consideration of protectionist intent
does not always form part of the Supreme Court’s analysis, Regan
argued that the outcome of most cases could be predicted based on
the absence or presence of protectionist intent.
60
Specifically, where
protectionist intent was present, the Court generally precluded the
regulation; where such intent was absent, the Court generally sus-
tained the regulation. A major problem with this account, as Regan
readily acknowledged, was that it could not explain the decisions in a
number of dormant Commerce Clause cases—involving, among other
topics, cross-border transportation and tax—where the burden on in-
terstate commerce did not arise from intentional protectionism.
61
Re-
gan therefore cabined these cases as exceptions to the general rule
that the dormant Commerce Clause targets only intentional protec-
tionism.
62
This Article reveals what the cases excluded by Regan have
in common—they are mismatch cases, which warrant, and receive, dif-
ferent doctrinal analysis.
II. R
EFRAMING
T
HE
D
ORMANT
C
OMMERCE
C
LAUSE
This Part reframes undue-burdens doctrine.
63
The Supreme
Court’s dormant Commerce Clause doctrine has long been under-
stood to involve two principal types of cases: facial discrimination and
59
Regan, supra note 16, at 1093. R
60
Id. Regan summarized the dormant Commerce Clause by the simple statement that
“[l]aws with protectionist purpose are invalid . . . laws without protectionist purpose . . . are
valid.” Id. at 1104. We think Regan overstates his claim, but it is important to note that he
limited it to only what he called “movement-of-goods” cases. Id. at 1182. Regan readily acknowl-
edged that interstate transportation, tax, and some other cases were not decided exclusively
upon the absence or presence of intentional protectionism, but rather were based on other val-
ues, including “national interest.” Id. (describing cases in which “the Court appears to do more
under the dormant commerce clause than merely suppress state protectionism”). What the cases
Regan excluded from his category of movement-of-goods have in common is that they are mis-
match cases. Although Regan referred to cases by topical area, there is nothing special about
transportation, tax, or even goods. Mismatches can occur in any area, including regulation of
goods. Indeed, Regan was forced to define his category of movement-of-goods cases as including
only “those cases in which no national interest other than the anti-protectionism interest is impli-
cated,” a definition he noted was “an interesting tautology.” Id. at 1191.
61
Id. at 1182. Another problem with Regan’s claim—which is that courts do and should
decide dormant Commerce Clause cases based only on the absence or presence of protectionist
intent—is that, except in cases of facial discrimination, it not only may be difficult to ascertain
legislative intent, but disputes have arisen regarding what types of evidence legitimately can be
used to ascertain legislative intent. See generally Caleb Nelson, Judicial Review of Legislative
Purpose, 83 N.Y.U. L. R
EV
. 1784, 1795–1858 (2008) (giving history of judicial practices in deter-
mining legislative intent).
62
See Regan, supra note 16, at 1184–86. These exceptions are important for our analysis, R
and for understanding the dormant Commerce Clause more generally. See infra Section II.B.
63
Because it seeks to address the core of the dormant Commerce Clause, this Article does
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 16 24-FEB-23 14:13
16 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
undue burdens.
64
Jurists and commentators paired each type of case
with a method of judicial review: strict scrutiny for facial discrimina-
tion, and Pike balancing for undue burdens.
65
But that framework
does not accurately reflect the doctrine, which is more nuanced. The
disconnect between the actual doctrine and its description by courts
and commentators has bolstered claims that the doctrine is confusing
and incoherent and therefore should be limited or even eliminated.
This Part advocates for a conception of undue-burden doctrine
that is more faithful to the cases; one that takes into account the type
of burden the challenged rule imposes: single-state or mismatch. Sec-
tion II.A defines single-state and mismatch burdens. Section II.B
shows how the Supreme Court analyzes single-state burdens. Section
II.C shows how the Supreme Court analyzes mismatch burdens.
Thinking of cases in terms of single-state burdens and mismatch bur-
dens allows us to see consistent, but unstated, differences in the Su-
preme Court’s approaches to deciding these cases. Although the
Supreme Court has not formally acknowledged a distinction between
single-state and mismatch burdens, and even though the Court claims
to apply the same doctrinal test—Pike balancingto all cases involv-
ing facially neutral rules, this Part shows that the Court as a practical
matter treats the two types of cases differently. For example, unlike
with single-state cases, justices often express reluctance to intervene in
mismatch cases, reasoning that because resolving mismatch cases in-
volves picking one state’s rule to prevail over another, it is essentially
legislative, not judicial. Likewise, this Part shows that, in those mis-
match cases in which the Court decides to intervene, it uses what we
call external benchmarks. Specifically, it compares the challenged
state’s regulation to other states’ regulation. No such cross-state com-
parisons are needed in single-state cases because, by definition, the
burden in a single-state case arises from the regulation of a single state
acting alone. Thinking about the cases in the way we suggest here clar-
ifies and simplifies the doctrine and lays the groundwork for our nor-
mative arguments in the rest of the Article.
not address several of its subdoctrines, including the market-participation exception, the govern-
ment-function exception, the extraterritoriality doctrine, or dormant-Commerce-Clause nexus.
64
See supra text accompanying note 48. R
65
See South Dakota v. Wayfair, Inc., 138 S. Ct. 2080, 2090–91 (2018); Brown-Forman Dis-
tillers Corp. v. N.Y. State Liquor Auth., 476 U.S 573, 579 (1986).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 17 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 17
A. Defining Types of Burdens
Before diving into our doctrinal analysis, this Section reviews the
types of burdens that matter under the dormant Commerce Clause,
and it defines single-state and mismatch burdens.
1. Symmetrical Versus Asymmetrical Burdens
Not all regulations impose burdens relevant to dormant Com-
merce Clause analysis. Consider regulations that impose what we call
symmetrical burdens. Symmetrical burdens fall evenly on in-state and
interstate commerce. For example, although they undoubtedly impact
cross-border commerce, some local regulations—such as minimum
wage laws and building codes—are symmetrical; compliance is no
more burdensome for out-of-staters than for in-staters, and hence the
rules do not discourage interstate commerce relative to in-state com-
merce. Accordingly, any legitimate state interest should be enough to
sustain them against dormant Commerce Clause challenges.
66
Contrast asymmetrical burdens, which this Article defines as
those that impose disproportionately greater costs on interstate com-
merce than on in-state commerce, hence discouraging interstate com-
merce relative to in-state commerce and potentially inspiring tit-for-tat
retaliation among states. The dormant Commerce Clause restrains
some, but not all, asymmetrical burdens. Specifically, it restrains only
unjustified asymmetrical burdens. State autonomy interests—includ-
ing states’ need to protect residents, cater to local conditions, and
achieve other legitimate ends—can justify asymmetrical burdens. Me-
diating between or balancing those interests is the heart of dormant
Commerce Clause analysis.
2. Single-State Versus Mismatch Burdens
A principal insight of this Article is that to fully understand dor-
mant Commerce Clause doctrine, we must first understand that regu-
lations impose different types of asymmetrical burdens on interstate
commerce. We can subdivide those burdens into two types: single-
state burdens and mismatch burdens. Single-state burdens arise from
the application of the challenged state’s law alone. Mismatch burdens
arise from the application of two or more states’ laws.
A regulation imposes a single-state burden when it burdens inter-
state commerce more than in-state commerce irrespective of what
66
See, e.g., Huron Portland Cement Co. v. Detroit, 362 U.S. 440, 448 (1960) (applying
rational-basis review).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 18 24-FEB-23 14:13
18 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
other states do. Specifically, regulation imposes a single-state burden
when: (1) it would discourage cross-border commerce relative to in-
state commerce if no other states regulated in the area, and (2) it
would also do so if all other states were to adopt regulation identical to
that of the challenged state. Thus, one can think of single-state bur-
dens as being functionally equivalent, in compliance-cost terms, to an
entry toll. If a state has a flat annual entry toll, that toll imposes an
asymmetrical cost that is higher for cross-border commercial actors
than for commercial actors operating wholly within the state. And the
cost associated with that toll is independent of other states’ tolls; it
does not rise or fall depending on any other state’s toll.
Facially discriminatory rules impose single-state burdens—the
asymmetrical burden on interstate commerce arises from the law of
the discriminating state alone. But facially neutral rules can impose
single-state or mismatch burdens.
67
For example, Pike v. Bruce Church
involved a facially neutral rule that imposed a single-state burden. In
Pike, Arizona required farmers who grew cantaloupes in the state also
to pack them there.
68
Because the burden arising from Arizona’s rule
did not depend on the actions or regulations of other states, it was a
single-state burden. Specifically, adoption by other states of rules simi-
lar to (or different from) the Arizona rule would not affect the cost to
comply with the Arizona rule.
But facially neutral rules also may impose mismatch burdens. A
regulation imposes a mismatch burden if: (1) it would discourage
cross-border commerce relative to in-state commerce if no other state
regulated in the area, but (2) it would not discourage cross-border
commerce relative to in-state commerce if all other states adopted the
same regulation as the challenged state. Mismatch burdens are contin-
gent on other states’ regulations; they disappear when other states
have the same rule.
Mismatches can consist of substantive differences in the content
of regulations, as when one state allows sixty-five-foot trucks while
another prohibits them. Mismatches also occur when one state has a
regulation, and another state has no corresponding regulation, such
that an interstate economic actor becomes subject to new rules when
it expands across the border. Mismatches thus either increase costs for
cross-border, but not in-state, economic actors or strip out-of-state ec-
onomic actors of comparative advantages they otherwise would pos-
sess. When state regulations interact, the cost to comply with one
67
A state law can also impose both single-state and mismatch burdens. See infra note 70. R
68
Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 143 (1970).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 19 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 19
state’s regulation can vary from zero (if the state’s regulation is in no
dimension stricter than or incompatible with other states’ regula-
tions)
69
to infinite (if the state’s rule is mutually exclusive with other
states’ rules). In some cases, compliance will be cheap; in others it
could be so high that it stops cross-border commerce in its tracks.
70
Consider the facially neutral mismatch in Bibb, in which cross-
border truckers challenged an Illinois regulation that imposed a
curved-mudflap requirement at a time when neighboring states per-
mitted or required straight mudflaps.
71
If all other states adopted Illi-
nois’s curved-mudflap rule, then interstate truckers would experience
no greater costs to comply with Illinois’s rule than would in-state
truckers because truckers everywhere would use only curved mud-
flaps. But because Illinois’s rule was different from those of other
states, out-of-state truckers had to stop at the border to change mud-
flaps. Therefore, the burden in Bibb, which arose from regulatory di-
versity, is a mismatch burden. The most important feature of
mismatches is that they are conditionalthe burden one state’s rule
imposes depends on the existence and content of other states’ rules.
Even when protectionist intent does not motivate the adoption of a
regulatory mismatch, a mismatch may severely curtail interstate com-
merce. Worse, states may create regulatory mismatches with protec-
69
Consider the existence of different opening-hours requirements for retailers. While
technically the regulations are mismatched, opening-hours diversity would have a negligible
asymmetrical burden on interstate commerce. Other examples might include local safety regula-
tions that impose costs on both in-state and out-of-state economic interests. See, e.g., Ray v. Atl.
Ritchfield Co., 435 U.S. 151, 173 (1978) (upholding a facially neutral requirement that tankers
exceeding certain size limits be accompanied by a tug escort in Puget Sound).
70
Regulations that impose mismatch burdens also can impose single-state burdens. The
classic example of a regulation that imposes both single-state and mismatch burdens is the Illi-
nois anti-takeover regulation struck down in CTS Corp. v. Dynamics Corp. of America, 481 U.S.
69 (1987). That regulation, which permitted Illinois to prevent a merger or acquisition if as little
as ten percent of the target corporation’s shares were held by Illinois residents, would potentially
create a mismatch with anti-takeover laws of other states. Id. at 72–75. The Illinois law also
imposed a single-state burden in that the law allowed the Illinois Secretary of State almost unfet-
tered ability to block such an acquisition. Id. at 81. Underscoring these two different types of
burdens, the Court several years later in Edgar v. MITE Corp., 457 U.S. 624 (1982) upheld an
Indiana anti-takeover law that only applied to target corporations chartered in Indiana, thus
reducing the possibility of overlapping jurisdictional claims (and hence reducing potential mis-
match burdens). Id. at 626–27, 646. In contrast, the dissent would have struck the law because it
gave Indiana broad authority to prevent takeovers, and takeovers overwhelmingly involved out-
of-state acquirers and in-state targets. In our terms, the dissent determined that the challenged
regulation imposed a severe single-state burden on interstate commerce. Id. at 656. This Article
does not consider the corporate law cases here because they implicate extraterritoriality more
than undue burdens.
71
Bibb v. Navajo Freight Lines, Inc., 359 U.S. 520, 520 (1959).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 20 24-FEB-23 14:13
20 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
tionist intent, as when North Carolina forbade apple growers from
displaying quality-grading information from their state of origin in
Hunt v. Washington State Apple Advertising Commission.
72
Section
II.C will discuss both Bibb and Hunt.
B. Single-State Burdens and Pike Balancing
This Section illustrates how the Supreme Court analyzes single-
state cases that allege discrimination against or undue burdens on in-
terstate commerce.
73
Whereas facial discrimination receives strict
scrutiny, facially neutral single-state burdens are subject to Pike
balancing.
1. Facially Discriminatory Regulations
The easiest type of single-state burden to identify and understand
involves facial discrimination, that is, regulation that expressly distin-
guishes between state residents and nonresidents or between in-state
and interstate commerce. Facial discrimination imposes single-state
burdens because the burden does not depend on the content of any
other state’s rule. Facial discrimination cases have never been contro-
versial or difficult for courts to resolve under the dormant Commerce
Clause. Subjected to strict scrutiny, facially discriminatory regulations
almost never survive.
74
For example, in Hughes v. Oklahoma,
75
the Su-
preme Court held that Oklahoma could not forbid the out-of-state
sale of minnows caught within Oklahoma, while at the same time per-
mitting the in-state sale of such minnows; in Lewis v. BT Investment
Managers, Inc.,
76
the Court held that Florida could not prohibit out-
of-state business entities from conducting certain financial activities in
Florida that the state permitted equivalent Florida entities to conduct;
72
432 U.S. 333, 335–36 (1977).
73
The goal of this Article is to explain the most puzzling cases, namely facially neutral, but
burdensome, regulations. Other types of single-state burdens, including facially discriminatory
laws and taxes that fail the Court’s internal-consistency test, are subject to strict scrutiny and are
almost always precluded. The reason for strict scrutiny in cases of facial discrimination are obvi-
ous; reasons for strict scrutiny of internally inconsistent taxes less so. For explanation as to why
internally inconsistent taxes properly receive strict scrutiny, see Michael S. Knoll & Ruth Mason,
The Economic Foundation of the Dormant Commerce Clause, 103 V
A
. L. R
EV
. 309, 329–33
(2017). Notwithstanding the technical nature of the explanation that underlies use of the internal
consistency test, the actual application of that test is straightforward, and so it is easy to identify
tax rules that are internally inconsistent and therefore discriminatory. See generally id.
74
Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322, 337 (1979) (“[F]acial discrimination invokes the
strictest scrutiny . . . .”).
75
441 U.S. 332, 337–38 (1979).
76
447 U.S. 27, 27, 44 (1980).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 21 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 21
and in Boston Stock Exchange v. State Tax Commission,
77
the Court
held that New York could not tax stock sales at a lower rate when they
took place in New York than when they took place elsewhere. The
Supreme Court likewise has struck down facially discriminatory regu-
lations that banned in-state operations by nonresidents,
78
banned di-
rect shipment of alcohol to state residents by out-of-state producers,
79
and more.
80
Rarely has the Supreme Court found a facially discrimina-
tory regulation to be justified.
81
Few commentators dispute that courts
act properly when they preclude facially discriminatory rules.
82
2. Facially Neutral Regulations
The dormant Commerce Clause also precludes facially neutral
rules that discriminate in effect. The Supreme Court has stated that
“[t]he commerce clause forbids discrimination, whether forthright or
ingenious.”
83
When evaluating a facially neutral rule, what matters to
the Court is the rule’s impact on interstate commerce.
84
Each case dis-
cussed in this Section involves a facially neutral regulation that im-
posed a single-state burden on interstate commerce; these cases
involve Pike balancing.
77
429 U.S. 318, 318–19, 336 (1977).
78
Tenn. Wine and Spirits Retailers Ass’n v. Thomas, 139 S. Ct. 2449, 2476 (2019).
79
Granholm v. Heald, 544 U.S. 460, 465–66 (2005) (precluding a Michigan law allowing
in-state, but not out-of-state, wineries to ship directly to Michigan customers).
80
Great Atl. & Pac. Tea Co. v. Cottrell, 424 U.S. 366, 367–68 (1976) (striking down a
Mississippi statute prohibiting the sale of out-of-state milk in Mississippi unless its source state
accepted the sale of Mississippi milk in its territory); Sporhase v. Nebraska ex rel. Douglas, 458
U.S. 941, 943, 960 (1982) (precluding a Nebraska statute prohibiting the withdrawal of Nebraska
groundwater for transport across state lines unless the destination state granted reciprocal rights
of withdrawal and transport into Nebraska); see, e.g., New England Power Co. v. New Hamp-
shire, 455 U.S. 331, 333–34, 344 (1982) (precluding a New Hampshire law prohibiting the export
of hydroelectric power).
81
See Maine v. Taylor, 477 U.S. 131, 132–33, 151–52 (1986) (finding complete ban on
imported baitfish justified to prevent introduction of parasites and invasive species when no less
restrictive preventative measures would be effective).
82
But see Eule, supra note 9, at 428 (arguing for a “radically diminished role” for the R
dormant Commerce Clause, even in discrimination cases).
83
W. Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy, 512 U.S. 186, 201 (1994); see also Dean Milk Co. v.
City of Madison, 340 U.S. 349, 354 (1951) (reasoning that limiting dormant Commerce Clause
scrutiny to facially discriminatory regulation “would mean that the Commerce Clause of itself
imposes no limitations on state action . . . save for the rare instance where a state artlessly
discloses an avowed purpose to discriminate against interstate goods”).
84
See W. Lynn Creamery, 512 U.S. at 201 (referring to a rule’s “practical operation”).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 22 24-FEB-23 14:13
22 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
a. Pike v. Bruce Church (1970)
In Pike v. Bruce Church, the challenged regulation involved ty-
ing, a requirement that forces a commercial actor that conducts some
commercial activity in a state to also conduct additional commercial
activity there.
85
A cantaloupe grower challenged Arizona’s require-
ment that cantaloupes grown in Arizona also had to be packed there.
86
The asymmetrical burden in Pike arose because, by tying packing to
growing, Arizona precluded multistate growers from obtaining econo-
mies of scale from using packing facilities that they may have already
owned outside Arizona. For example, the challenger in Pike would
have preferred to use a packing facility it already owned nearby, just
across the border in California.
87
This asymmetrical burden was also a
single-state burden. Specifically, the cost to comply with Arizona’s
regulation would not decrease if all other states adopted an identical
rule. The Arizona rule, in effect, functioned as an entry toll.
To decide Pike, the Supreme Court invoked a preexisting doctri-
nal tool that has come to be known as Pike balancing. Under Pike
balancing, the Court first compares the asymmetrical burden a state
imposes on interstate commerce to the state’s interest in the chal-
lenged regulation.
88
The Court then may engage in narrow tailoring by
asking whether the state could have achieved its interest via a method
that would burden interstate commerce less than does the challenged
regulation.
89
In Pike, the Supreme Court compared the burden Ari-
zona imposed on in-state growers to the burden Arizona imposed on
interstate growers, and it concluded that only interstate growers had
to relinquish economies of scale that derived from consolidating pack-
85
Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 138, 145 (1970) (defining tying as “requiring
business operations to be performed in the home State that could more efficiently be performed
elsewhere”); cf. S.-Cent. Timber Dev., Inc. v. Wunnicke, 467 U.S. 82, 102, (1984) (Rehnquist, J.,
dissenting) (arguing that the majority should not have invalidated under the dormant Commerce
Clause a state’s “tying arrangement” that required timber harvested in a state also to be
processed there).
86
Pike, 397 U.S. at 138. The Court considered the Arizona packing rule to be facially
neutral because it did not draw a de jure distinction between in-state and out-of-state growers in
order to treat them differently. On the contrary, by its terms, the Arizona statute applied to all
growers the same way—if they grew cantaloupes in Arizona, they had to pack them there. Id. at
140–42.
87
Id. at 138. The parties in Pike stipulated that its practical effect was to “compel the
company to build packing facilities in [Arizona].” Id. at 140.
88
Id. at 142–43.
89
The Supreme Court does not always engage in explicit narrow tailoring as part of Pike
balancing, and in its most recent description of Pike balancing, it did not even mention it. See
South Dakota v. Wayfair, Inc., 138 S. Ct. 2080, 2091 (2018).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 23 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 23
ing into a single plant.
90
The Supreme Court weighed this burden
against Arizona’s justification for the regulation, which was to inform
the market that the relevant cantaloupes had been grown in Ari-
zona,
91
and the Court concluded that the burden outweighed Ari-
zona’s interest.
92
The Court also noted the relevance of alternative,
less burdensome, regulations—such as labelingby which Arizona
could achieve its local interest.
93
It is not uncommon for courts strik-
ing a law that imposes a single-state burden under Pike to find both
that the law’s burden exceeds its benefit and that less burdensome
means were available to achieve the state’s legitimate ends.
Not every reader will be convinced by the Court’s analysis in Pike
that the asymmetric burden on interstate commerce outweighed the
states’ regulatory interest. Balancing involves a judgment call. The
Court’s decision in Pike rested in part on its long-held
94
attitude to-
ward the practice of tying, which it saw as imposing a “straitjacket on
the appellee company with respect to the allocation of its interstate
resources.”
95
The Court declared tying worthy of “particular suspi-
cion”
96
and declared it “virtually per se illegal.”
97
b. H. P. Hood & Sons, Inc. v. Du Mond (1949)
Dormant Commerce Clause challenges also arise when states use
facially neutral rules to limit market access. In H. P. Hood & Sons,
90
Pike, 397 U.S. at 145–46.
91
Id. at 142.
92
Id. at 143, 145 (distinguishing Arizona’s “tenuous” interest in the reputation of its pro-
duce from other types of interests that would have carried more weight, such as safety).
93
Id. at 142.
94
See Toomer v. Witsell, 334 U.S. 385, 403 (1948) (striking down a North Carolina statute
that tied shrimp packing to shrimp fishing, concluding that “an inevitable concomitant of [this]
statute . . . is to divert to South Carolina employment and business which might otherwise go to
Georgia”).
95
Pike, 397 U.S at 146; id. at 145 (“The nature of that burden is, constitutionally, more
significant than its extent” (emphasis added)); see also Toomer, 334 U.S. at 403–04 (disapproving
South Carolina’s attempt to “impose an artificial rigidity on the economic pattern of the indus-
try”); id. at 410 (Rutledge, J., concurring) (referring to the tying regulation as “aimed in terms
directly at interstate commerce alone, and thus would seem to be discriminatory in intent and
effect”). For other cases invalidating tying, see, e.g., Minnesota v. Barber, 136 U.S. 313, 329–30
(1890) (meat sold in-state had to be inspected there); Foster-Fountain Packing Co. v. Haydel, 278
U.S. 1, 13–14 (1928) (requiring shrimp caught in-state to be processed there); Johnson v. Haydel,
278 U.S. 16, 16–17 (1928) (requiring oysters caught in-state to be processed there); S.-Cent.
Timber Dev., Inc. v. Wunnicke, 467 U.S. 82, 84–85 (1984) (requiring timber harvested in-state to
be processed there).
96
Pike, 397 U.S. at 145.
97
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 24 24-FEB-23 14:13
24 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
Inc. v. Du Mond,
98
for example, the Supreme Court considered
whether New York could deny an out-of-state milk buyer a license to
operate an in-state milk depot because the state wanted to protect its
in-state milk market from greater competition from any source,
whether in-state or out-of-state. A majority of the Court held that
New York violated the dormant Commerce Clause because, despite
the absence of facial discrimination, the “avowed purpose” of the de-
nial of the license was to “aid local economic interests”
99
and for the
Court to permit such “prohibition of competition”
100
might spur “fan-
tastic rivalries and dislocations and reprisals.”
101
But the dissenters in
the case would have struck a different balance.
102
They regarded as
legitimate New York’s interest in stabilizing the milk market by regu-
lating all new entrants.
103
They viewed “the prevention of destructive
competition [as] a permissible exercise of the police power,”
104
pro-
vided the state did not target out-of-state competition for special
treatment.
105
Put differently, regulating to reduce competition was
permissible, whereas regulating to reduce competition specifically
from out-of-staters was impermissible. Thus, the dissenters would have
remanded for more fact-finding on the state’s intentions and its
interests.
c. Dean Milk Co. v. City of Madison (1951)
In 1951, the Supreme Court decided another milk case, Dean
Milk Co. v. City of Madison.
106
In Dean Milk, the City of Madison
banned the sale of milk in the city unless the milk was bottled within
98
336 U.S. 525, 526–27 (1949).
99
Id. at 530–31, 538 (“[T]he state may not use its admitted powers to protect the health
and safety of its people as a basis for suppressing competition.”).
100
Id. at 538 (quoting Buck v. Kuykendall, 267 U.S. 307, 315 (1925)).
101
Id. at 539.
102
Id. at 564 (Frankfurter, J., dissenting) (refusing to join the majority because he could not
“agree in treating what is essentially a problem of striking a balance between competing interests
as an exercise in absolutes”). Joined by Justice Murphy, Justice Black separately dissented, con-
cluding that there was no discrimination, and that, on balance, the state’s interest should have
prevailed. Id. at 549 (Black, J., dissenting).
103
Because a state’s interest in ensuring its residents a steady supply of wholesome milk is
so strong, the Supreme Court has accepted stringent regulation of the milk industry, including
price controls. Id. at 529.
104
Id. at 566 (Frankfurter, J., dissenting) (distinguishing state regulation of “competition
from whatever source,” which is permitted under the dormant Commerce Clause, from regula-
tion of “out-of-state competition,” which is not).
105
Id. at 570 (Frankfurter, J., dissenting).
106
340 U.S. 349 (1951).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 25 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 25
five miles of Madison’s central square.
107
Although the ordinance did
not explicitly target interstate commerce—and many Wisconsin dairy
farmers were also disadvantaged—an Illinois milk distributor argued
that the ordinance nevertheless violated the dormant Commerce
Clause. Madison responded that the ordinance promoted a legitimate
state interest, namely “convenient, economical and efficient plant in-
spection.”
108
But the Supreme Court held that the ordinance had the
“practical effect” of “exclud[ing] from distribution in Madison whole-
some milk produced and pasteurized in Illinois.”
109
In this case, physi-
cal distance to the Madison town square operated as a proxy to
discriminate against interstate commerce.
110
The Court concluded that
by limiting milk sold in the city to only milk bottled at a short distance
from the city center, Madison—and by extension Wisconsin—discrim-
inated against milk from other states.
111
Dean Milk featured narrow
tailoring: because the city had available to it “reasonable [and] nondis-
criminatory alternatives” to satisfy “its unquestioned power to protect
the health and safety of its people,” the Supreme Court held that the
ordinance was not justified.
112
Such more narrowly tailored alterna-
tives would have included a requirement that milk from points farther
away be inspected to the same quality standards as those applicable in
Madison.
113
d. Bendix Autolite Corp. v. Midwesco Enterprises, Inc. (1988)
Bendix Autolite Corp. v. Midwesco Enterprises, Inc.
114
involved a
challenge to an Ohio statute that tolled the statute of limitations for
claims against out-of-state corporations that had not designated an
agent for service.
115
The Supreme Court noted that the challenged
statute imposed a heavy burden on interstate commerce.
116
The Ohio
107
Id. at 350–51, 355.
108
Id. at 352.
109
Id. at 354.
110
Although the Court did not describe the challenged regulation in terms of tying, the
regulation conditioned one economic activity in the city (selling milk) upon the economic actor’s
performance of additional economic activity in the city (inspection). See id. at 354–55.
111
Id. at 354.
112
Id.
113
Id. at 355 (noting that the city health inspector had suggested this option to the city
based on a federal “Model Milk Ordinance”).
114
486 U.S. 888 (1988).
115
Id. at 889–90.
116
Id. at 891 (the nature of the burden was that an out-of-state company had to either
indefinitely toll the statute of limitations or indefinitely subject itself to suit in Ohio on any cause
of action).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 26 24-FEB-23 14:13
26 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
statute imposed a single-state burden—the adoption by other states of
a tolling statute identical to Ohio’s would do nothing to reduce the
burden Ohio imposed on interstate commerce.
Although it did not cite Pike, in deciding Bendix, a majority of
the Supreme Court engaged in balancing.
117
It compared the burden
Ohio imposed on interstate commerce to Ohio’s interest in enabling
its residents to serve process on foreign corporations. The Court held
that the challenged statute added little to Ohio’s long-arm statute, and
therefore the burden it imposed on interstate commerce could not be
justified under the dormant Commerce Clause.
118
One may agree or
disagree with the outcome in Bendix; we review it here to emphasize
that, even though it did not expressly cite Pike, the Bendix Court used
balancing to decide the case.
e. C & A Carbone, Inc. v. Town of Clarkstown (1994)
Like milk, waste disposal has generated many dormant Com-
merce Clause challenges. In the 1994 case C & A Carbone, Inc. v.
Town of Clarkstown,
119
a majority of the Supreme Court held that a
New York town violated the dormant Commerce Clause by requiring
local companies to process solid waste at a particular commercial fa-
cility. The town had granted the commercial facility a monopoly to
process local waste at above-market prices as part of a deal under
which the monopolist would build the processing plant and later trans-
fer it to the town for one dollar.
120
A majority of the Court held the
arrangement violated the dormant Commerce Clause because it “de-
prive[d] out-of-state businesses of access to a local market”
121
and
“squelche[d] competition.”
122
Although the town had a legitimate,
nonprotectionist, reason for granting the monopoly, namely, it was a
way to fund the construction of a processing plant that would be trans-
ferred to the town, the Court held that the town could have achieved
its goal through less protectionist measures, such as taxation.
123
Three
117
See id. at 897 (Scalia, J., concurring) (citing Pike and describing the majority opinion as
“[h]aving evaluated the interests on both sides as roughly as this, the Court then proceeds to
judge which is more important. This process is ordinarily called ‘balancing.’”).
118
Id. at 893–94 (majority opinion).
119
511 U.S. 383 (1994).
120
Id. at 386–87.
121
Id. at 389.
122
Id. at 392.
123
Id. at 393–94. The majority held the challenged ordinance to be discriminatory, but
Justice O’Connor pointed out that it was not facially so, since all of the town’s waste had to be
processed by the monopolist. See id. 405–06 (O’Connor, J., concurring) (concluding that the
ordinance was invalid under Pike).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 27 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 27
dissenting justices concluded that the ordinance should have been up-
held because the processing facility was so closely related to the
town’s governing function.
124
f. Lloyd A. Fry Roofing Co. v. Wood (1952)
In contrast with the facially neutral cases just discussed, which
involved obvious protectionist impacts, rules that impose only inciden-
tal single-state burdens and do not involve protectionist intent typi-
cally survive dormant Commerce Clause review. For example, in 1952
in Lloyd A. Fry Roofing Co. v. Wood,
125
the Supreme Court upheld a
facially neutral state truck-licensing regime that required “driver-own-
ers to do nothing except apply for a permit.”
126
Although the permit-
ting regime involved what we would call an asymmetrical single-state
burden on interstate commerce,
127
the Supreme Court held that the
burden was justified because it enabled the state to “properly apply
[its] valid police, welfare, and safety regulations to motor carriers us-
ing its highways.”
128
In other cases, the Supreme Court upheld regula-
tions, despite the asymmetric burdens they imposed on interstate
commerce, either because the asymmetric impact on interstate com-
merce was only incidental or because the burden was justified by the
regulatory interest.
3. Understanding Single-State Cases
Balancing in some single-state cases is easy because one side of
the scale—either adverse impact on interstate commerce or legitimate
state interest—is essentially empty. For example, facially discrimina-
tory rules almost never survive dormant Commerce Clause review for
lack of a legitimate state interest in the discriminatory rule. Similarly,
in Hood, a majority of the Court ultimately rejected the legitimacy of
New York’s proffered state interest, which was to reduce competi-
tion.
129
Such reasoning is equivalent to concluding that the state had
no legitimate interest to weigh against the burden it imposed on inter-
124
Id. at 419 (Souter, J., dissenting).
125
344 U.S. 157 (1952).
126
Id. at 161; id. at 163 (upholding the regulation).
127
That is, the cost to comply did not depend on the rules of any other state, and in particu-
lar, the cost to comply would not decrease if other states adopted the same rule.
128
Fry Roofing, 344 U.S. at 161; see also California v. Thompson, 313 U.S. 109, 111, 116
(1941) (upholding a $1 licensing fee and $1000 bond requirement).
129
H. P. Hood & Sons, Inc. v. Du Mond, 336 U.S. 525, 542 (1949) (“[H]ere the challenge is
only to a denial of facilities for interstate commerce upon the sole and specific grounds that it
will subject others to competition and take supplies needed locally, an end, as we have shown,
always held to be precluded by the Commerce Clause.”).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 28 24-FEB-23 14:13
28 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
state commerce. Other Pike balancing cases are likewise easy to re-
solve because the burden side of the balancing scale is essentially
empty, such that any legitimate state interest can outweigh it. This is
true of de minimis asymmetrical burdens on interstate commerce,
such as the registration requirement in Fry Roofing.
130
The remainder of cases involve more careful review. For example,
regulations that impose significant asymmetrical burdens—such as the
tying regulation in Pike or the statute of limitations in Bendixcan
only be justified by legitimate state interests that cannot be satisfied
via less burdensome regulation. Thus, it should come as no surprise
when the Supreme Court strikes down regulations—such as those in
Dean Milk and Carbonethat completely close the state’s market to
out-of-state competition. The Court upholds such stringent rules only
in rare cases, as when needed to prevent contagion that cannot be
stopped by other means.
131
Other cases involve close judgment calls.
Although a majority of the Court in Hood thought that New York’s
refusal to grant a milk-depot permit to an out-of-state milk buyer was
motivated by an illegitimate state interest—namely protectionism that
would inspire retaliation—three dissenters regarded the state as moti-
vated by an intent to stabilize competition in a way that did not imper-
missibly target out-of-state interests. Cases like Hood frustrate
observers because it is difficult to predict their outcomes.
132
Likewise,
in his concurrence in Bendix, Justice Scalia observed that the interests
on each side of the Pike balancing scale were “incommensurate,” and
“an opinion could as persuasively have been written coming out the
opposite way.”
133
This Article will have more to say about Pike bal-
ancing in Part III, after we introduce the notion of mismatches.
130
See Fry Roofing, 344 U.S. at 162 (citing precedent for the conclusion that “a state can
regulate so long as no undue burden is imposed on interstate commerce, and that a mere re-
quirement for a permit is not such a burden”).
131
Compare Maine v. Taylor, 477 U.S. 131, 151–52 (1986) (finding complete ban on im-
ported baitfish was justified to prevent introduction of parasites and invasive species because no
less restrictive means would be effective), with R.R. Co. v. Husen, 95 U.S. 465, 473–74 (1877)
(precluding exclusion of out-of-state cattle to prevent contagion because less restrictive means,
including quarantines and inspections, were available).
132
See, e.g., Regan, supra note 16, at 1262 (“I am not certain Hood was correctly decided R
or, if it was, what is the best analysis.”).
133
Bendix Autolite Corp. v. Midwesco Enters., Inc., 486 U.S. 888, 897 (Scalia, J.,
concurring).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 29 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 29
C. Mismatch Burdens and Bibb Balancing
We now consider mismatches.
134
The defining feature of a mis-
match is that the presence or absence of similar regulation by other
states affects the cost to comply with the first state’s rule. Put simply,
mismatch burdens arise from differences among states’ regulations,
and they either increase costs for cross-border, but not in-state, eco-
nomic actors or strip out-of-state economic actors of comparative ad-
vantages they otherwise would possess.
Some dormant Commerce Clause concerns are common to both
single-state and mismatch cases, whereas others are unique to mis-
match cases. As with single-state cases, mismatches may raise ques-
tions about intentional protectionism. That is, mismatches may be
designed deliberately to exclude out-of-state products or services or to
otherwise increase costs for out-of-staters, and concerns about inten-
tional protectionism may be present even when states also seem to
have good reasons (e.g., safety or consumer protection) for regulating.
When mismatches display intentional protectionism, the Court re-
solves them on that basis alone. But the Court may also closely scruti-
nize mismatch cases even when it finds no protectionist intent. In such
cases, the Court employs what we call Bibb balancing. Unlike Pike
balancing, Bibb balancing employs external benchmarks consisting of
other states’ laws as a baseline for evaluating the challenged state’s
rule. This approach is inevitable; mismatch burdens must be measured
against other states’ laws because the nature of a mismatch burden is
that it arises from regulatory diversity.
1. Cases
a. Intentionally Protectionist Mismatches
When states enact regulatory mismatches with protectionist in-
tent, courts have precluded them for that reason.
135
In this respect,
mismatch and single-state cases are similar. Such cases pose the prob-
lem of establishing intent, but this problem is common to both single-
state and mismatch cases.
134
In general, our selection of cases is meant to be representative, rather than comprehen-
sive, of the problem of mismatches.
135
See, e.g., J. R. Brooks & Son, Inc. v. Reagan, No. C-71-1311 SC, 1973 U.S. Dist. LEXIS
15732, at *8, *20 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 18, 1973) (precluding an intentionally protectionist mismatch).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 30 24-FEB-23 14:13
30 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
i. Florida Lime & Avocado Growers, Inc. v. Paul (1963)
For example, in Florida Lime & Avocado Growers, Inc. v. Paul,
136
California prohibited the shipment within California of avocados that
did not meet a minimum fat threshold.
137
Florida’s use of federal ripe-
ness standards, which relied on picking date and fruit size, created a
mismatch with California’s use of fat content.
138
California defended
the fat-content rule as needed to ensure ripeness, but Florida avocado
growers complained that Florida avocado varietals were unlikely to
reach California’s prescribed minimum fat content, even when fully
ripe according to federal standards.
139
Although California did not
facially discriminate against Florida avocados, there was a question of
whether California used fat content as a discriminatory proxy.
140
The
trial record in Florida Lime did not enable the Supreme Court to con-
clude that California had protectionist intent to exclude Florida avo-
cados. This was not only because the trial record contained conflicts
and questions regarding the admissibility of certain evidence,
141
but
also because the trial court assumed, apparently contrary to fact, that
at the time California enacted the challenged regulation “California
growers faced no meaningful competition from Florida growers.”
142
To get clarity on this question, the Supreme Court remanded the
case for further fact finding.
143
The Court also confirmed that even if
the regulation was not adopted for protectionist motives, given its dis-
proportionate effect on Florida avocados, “the continued application”
of the regulation might discriminate against or unduly burden or inter-
state commerce,
144
in a manner that outweighed what the Court re-
garded as California’s legitimate interest in ensuring the ripeness of
136
373 U.S. 132 (1963).
137
Id. at 133–34.
138
Id. at 139.
139
Id. at 134–35 (federal standards were based on days of maturity).
140
Florida Lime is a mismatch case because, if all states implemented California’s fat-con-
tent rule, then farmers would adjust to that regulation, and farmers in Florida would grow either
no avocados or only avocados that could meet California’s standard, which would also be Flor-
ida’s standard. Thus, under conditions of uniform rules, the asymmetrical burden on interstate
commerce would disappear. See id. at 133–134.
141
Id. at 155.
142
Id. at 153 n.19 (noting that this assumption was questionable because there not only
“appear[ed] to have been vigorous competition” between the two states, but also because Flor-
ida growers “immediately and vigorously protested” the passage of the fat-content rule, and a
U.S. senator representing Florida filed a complaint with the Department of Agriculture).
143
Id. at 136–37. See id. at 154 (noting that the district court’s evidentiary rulings had cre-
ated confusion in the record).
144
Id. at 153–54.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 31 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 31
avocados for California consumers.
145
Interestingly, four dissenting
justices would have held that federal avocado ripeness standards pre-
empted conflicting California rules, in part on the grounds that a goal
of the Secretary of Agriculture in prescribing national standards was
to avoid “[l]ack of uniformity [that] tends to obstruct commerce [and]
to divide the nation into many markets.”
146
Although there is no pub-
lished case on remand, in a subsequent case challenging the same reg-
ulation, a three-judge California district court precluded the fat-
content rule on the grounds that it operated “as an embargo against
Florida-grown avocados” that could not be justified by California’s
consumer-protection interests.
147
In striking the law, the panel under-
scored extensive evidence of intentional protectionism on the part of
the California legislature, and it pointed to—as a less discriminatory
alternative—the federal picking-date and size rules that Florida
used.
148
ii. Hunt v. Washington State Apple Advertising
Commission (1977)
In 1977, the Supreme Court decided on the merits another case
involving what the out-of-state challenger charged was an intention-
ally protectionist mismatch. In Hunt v. Washington State Apple Adver-
tising Commission,
149
North Carolina had a rule that required apple
shipping containers to bear only either federal quality gradings or no
grades at all; such containers could not bear grades from other states’
regulatory regimes.
150
North Carolina’s requirement was “unique in
145
Id. at 154 (noting that “[o]ther state regulations raising similar problems have been
found to be discriminatory or burdensome notwithstanding a legitimate state interest in some
form of regulation—either because they exceeded the limits necessary to vindicate that interest
or because they unreasonably favored local producers at the expense of competitors from other
States”) (citation omitted). Note, however, that the dissenters emphasized that there was no
claim by California that the regulation advanced health or protected consumers against fraud or
deceptive practices. See id. at 161 n.3 (White, J. dissenting).
146
Id. at 169 (White, J., dissenting).
147
J. R. Brooks & Son, Inc. v. Reagan, No. C-71-1311 SC, 1973 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 15732, at
*8 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 18, 1973). The case involved a fourteen-day trial in which the court took
evidence of asymmetrical effect and protectionist intent. Among other facts, the panel concluded
that maintenance of the fat-content regulation was “the result of pressure from the California
avocado industry, for the purpose, inter alia, of excluding competition from Florida avocados in
California markets.” Id. at *14–15 (holding that California’s interest could be served by adopting
the federal standards of ripeness, which were based on size and harvest date).
148
Id. at *10–11.
149
432 U.S. 333 (1977).
150
Id. at 352.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 32 24-FEB-23 14:13
32 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
the 50 States,”
151
and specifically, it was different from grading stan-
dards applicable in Washington. Because Washington quality grading
standards were stricter, they conferred a marketplace advantage on
Washington apples.
152
Indeed, the Washington Apple Commission,
which brought the case, suggested that North Carolina adopted its
rule barring other states’ labels specifically to strip Washington apples
of their competitive advantage in the North Carolina market. The
Commission insisted that the impact on Washington apples was “not
an unintended byproduct” of the North Carolina regulation.
153
Al-
though the Supreme Court acknowledged “some indications in the re-
cord”
154
that North Carolina sought to exclude or disadvantage
Washington apples, the Court concluded that it “need not ascribe an
economic protection motive to the North Carolina Legislature to re-
solve this case.”
155
Instead, the Court noted that North Carolina’s rule would require
Washington growers to either repack their apples or to “obliterate the
printed labels on containers shipped to North Carolina.”
156
The Court
thus took Washington law as a given, and framed North Carolina law
as a deviation from it. Put differently, the Court used Washington’s
regime as a baseline for measuring the burden that the North Carolina
regime imposed on interstate commerce. The use of other states’ re-
gimes as a baseline in measuring the burden on interstate commerce
imposed by the challenged state’s regulation is what we mean when
we characterize the Supreme Court as using an “external benchmark”
in mismatch cases.
Citing Pike, the Court weighed against this burden North Caro-
lina’s proffered interest, which was to protect consumers from confu-
sion arising from a multiplicity of different apple grading standards.
157
151
Id. at 337.
152
Id. at 350–51 (noting that the market preferred Washington’s grading system to the
federal grading system because Washington’s displayed greater consistency, [due to] its empha-
sis on color, and its supporting mandatory inspections”).
153
Id. at 352.
154
Id.
155
Id.
156
North Carolina required labels on closed containers of apples to either have the applica-
ble USDA grade or no grade shown at all. This meant that Washington growers could not display
Washington’s own unique state grade on apple containers they shipped to North Carolina. Be-
cause Washington growers packed their apples into prelabeled containers before shipping to
various states, North Carolina’s “unique regulation would have required Washington growers to
obliterate the printed labels on containers shipped to North Carolina, thus giving their product a
damaged appearance,” or face the significant logistical and financial cost of repacking apples
specifically for sale in North Carolina. Id. at 337–38.
157
See id. at 350. North Carolina cited the fact that seven states used their own unique
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 33 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 33
The Court did not think the North Carolina statute would advance
North Carolina’s legitimate
158
consumer-protection goal.
159
And more-
over, the Court reasoned that North Carolina buyers would experi-
ence less confusion from Washington’s more precise labeling regime
than from North Carolina’s preferred alternative.
160
Such reasoning
weighs not only the burden, but also North Carolina’s regulatory in-
terest against a baseline generated by Washington’s labeling regime.
Finally, the Court pointed to less restrictive alternatives by which
North Carolina could achieve its consumer-protection goals, such as
allowing Washington growers to display both Washington and federal
grades.
161
Ultimately, the Hunt Court engendered doctrinal confusion by
mixing the discrimination and undue burden strands of dormant Com-
merce Clause when it concluded that “the challenged statute has the
practical effect of not only burdening interstate sales of Washington
apples, but also discriminating against them.”
162
We may be able to
attribute this mixed legal conclusion to evidence that North Carolina
intentionally created the mismatch to exclude Washington apples.
163
A
better way to understand Hunt under the balancing standard might be
to say that the burden on interstate commerce arising from the mis-
match easily outweighed North Carolina’s dubious
164
—or even imper-
missibly protectionist—interest in its labeling rule.
b. Nonprotectionist, or Arguably Nonprotectionist, Mismatches
When the Supreme Court cannot resolve a mismatch case based
on intentional protectionism, it follows one of two major doctrinal ap-
proaches. Under the first, it summarily upholds the regulation. We call
this approach noninterventionist because the Court justifies it by refer-
apple grading system and argued that lack of uniformity could confuse the consumer as to the
apple’s actual quality. Id. at 349.
158
Id. at 350 (referring to “health and consumer protection” as legitimate goals).
159
Id. at 353 (North Carolina’s rule can “hardly be thought to eliminate the problems of
deception and confusion”).
160
Id.
161
Id. at 354.
162
Id. at 350, 352 (noting the challenger’s argument that the regulation’s “discriminatory
impact on interstate commerce was not an unintended byproduct”).
163
Id. at 352 (acknowledging “some indications in the record” to the effect that North
Carolina intentionally discriminated against Washington apples).
164
North Carolina’s consumer protection interest was dubious both because the state
sought to protect sophisticated bulk apple buyers who could be expected to know their business,
and because there was no evidence of actual market confusion for the sixty years of operation of
the Washington grading regime. Id. at 338.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 34 24-FEB-23 14:13
34 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
ence to limits on its own institutional powers. The second approach,
which is interventionist, involves Bibb balancing. Under Bibb balanc-
ing, the Court either precludes or sustains the challenged law after
analysis. Both the interventionist and noninterventionist approaches
appear to be alive and well, and which will prevail in a given case is
unpredictable.
i. Nonintervention
1. State Highway Department v. Barnwell Bros., Inc. (1938)
In 1938, in South Carolina State Highway Department v. Barnwell
Bros., Inc.,
165
South Carolina adopted truck weight and width limits
that were stricter than those of neighboring states.
166
Challengers ar-
gued that South Carolina’s rule unconstitutionally burdened interstate
commerce. The South Carolina regulation imposed a mismatch bur-
den; specifically, if all states had the same limits as South Carolina,
truckers everywhere would comply with those limits, and so South
Carolina’s rule would not disproportionately burden (or exclude) out-
of-state trucks.
South Carolina argued that it needed strict weight and width lim-
its to protect its roads from wear.
167
Even though the district court
found the limits were an unreasonable means to preserve highways
and conferred no safety advantage,
168
and even though the Supreme
Court acknowledged that the vast majority of interstate trucking ex-
ceeded the South Carolina limits and therefore would be shut out of
South Carolina,
169
the Supreme Court nevertheless unanimously
170
up-
held the regulation on the grounds that state highways were a particu-
larly local concern.
171
Expressly rejecting judicial balancing
172
to
resolve “non-discriminatory”
173
burdens, the Supreme Court applied
rational-basis review.
174
Unlike in some other cases this Article dis-
cusses, a perceived need for national uniformity in highway regula-
165
303 U.S. 177 (1938).
166
Id. at 179.
167
Id. at 192–93.
168
Id. at 183.
169
See id. at 182.
170
The decision was 7–0. Justices Cardozo and Reed did not take part. Id. at 196.
171
Id. at 190.
172
Id. at 191–92 (noting that the constitutionality of such highway regulation “is not to be
determined by weighing in the judicial scales the merits of the legislative choice and rejecting it if
the weight of evidence presented in court appears to favor a different standard”).
173
Id. at 190.
174
Id. at 189 (“[S]o long as the state action does not discriminate, the burden is one which
the Constitution permits because it is an inseparable incident of the exercise of a legislative
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 35 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 35
tions played no role in Barnwell; indeed, the Court observed that
precluding South Carolina’s rule would be tantamount to “forc[ing]
the states to conform to standards which Congress might, but has not
adopted.”
175
Thus, if uniform regulation of highways were needed,
Congress, not the Supreme Court, should impose them.
176
2. Moorman Manufacturing Co. v. Bair (1978)
Moorman Manufacturing Co. v. Bair
177
was a 1978 case involving
a state income tax. Before examining Moorman, however, we offer a
word of qualification. In 2015, in Comptroller of the Treasury of Mary-
land v. Wynne,
178
the Supreme Court confirmed that mismatches in
tax bases (as opposed to mismatches in tax compliance rules), do not
violate the dormant Commerce Clause as long as they are what the
Court calls “internally consistent” because internally consistent taxes
do not asymmetrically burden interstate commerce.
179
Forty years ago,
however, when the Supreme Court decided Moorman, the Wynne
view of tax mismatches had not yet been developed. Thus, when
judges, litigants, and commentators thought about mismatched tax ba-
ses, particularly when such mismatches produced double taxation,
they generally assumed that mismatches produced asymmetric ef-
fects—that is, that they imposed greater costs on interstate than in-
authority.”). Id. at 192 (applying rational-basis review in the absence of any finding of
discrimination).
175
Id. at 187.
176
Id. at 190 (deciding that burdens arising from conflicts may require “legislation designed
to secure uniformity or in other respects to protect the national interest in the commerce, [and]
curtail to some extent the state’s regulatory power. But that is a legislative, not a judicial func-
tion, to be performed in the light of the Congressional judgment of what is appropriate regula-
tion of interstate commerce . . . .”).
177
437 U.S. 267, 283 (1978).
178
575 U.S. 542 (2014).
179
An internally consistent rule is one that, if adopted by all the states, would not result in
higher taxation for interstate than for in-state commerce. Id. at 560 (2015). The Court is correct,
as an economic matter, that—even when they lead to double taxation—tax base mismatches do
not asymmetrically burden interstate commerce as long they are internally consistent. The rea-
sons are technical and explained in our earlier work. See Knoll & Mason, supra note 73. R
The Court recently gave an example of a tax-base mismatch that would not violate the
dormant Commerce Clause. The Court stated that if one state taxed solely on the basis of resi-
dence—that is, it taxed its residents on their income regardless of where they earned that in-
come—and another state taxed solely on the basis of source—that is, it taxed all income earned
in the state regardless of where the owner of the income resided—then the simultaneous applica-
tion of those two regimes to a single person engaged in interstate commerce would not violate
the dormant Commerce Clause, notwithstanding resulting double taxation (or nontaxation). See
Wynne, 575 U.S. at 565–66. For more on why this result makes sense as an economic matter—
namely, because it would impose no asymmetric burden on interstate commerce—see Knoll &
Mason, supra note 73. R
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 36 24-FEB-23 14:13
36 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
state commerce.
180
Although the Supreme Court ultimately adopted a
more sophisticated view of tax mismatches in Wynneone that is sup-
ported by economic analysis—this Article nevertheless discusses
Moorman because it provides insights into how justices think about
mismatches that they perceive as imposing asymmetrical burdens on
interstate commerce.
181
Understanding Moorman also requires a little background on
state taxation. The definition of income for state tax purposes gener-
ally does not generate mismatches because the states use harmonized
rules; specifically, they borrow the federal definition of income.
182
But
conflicts arise when states divide that income among themselves. For
example, states use formulas to calculate the portion of a company’s
income that is taxable in each state; those formulas account for the
relative presence in the state of the company’s factors of production,
such as payroll, property, and sales. In Moorman, a corporate tax-
payer complained that it suffered unconstitutional double taxation
when Iowa used a single-factor-sales formula at a time when all other
states used a particular three-factor formula dubbed the Massachu-
setts formula.
183
In a 6–3 decision, the Moorman Court acknowledged that diver-
sity in tax-apportionment formulas could lead to double taxation, but
it concluded that responsibility for any resulting burden was not at-
tributable solely to any one state.
184
Different states adopted different
tax apportionment rules. Iowa used sales; all other states used the
Massachusetts formula. As a result, the Court regarded multiple states
to be responsible for the mismatch.
185
Because the overlap could have
been cured by Iowa adopting the Massachusetts formula, or by other
states “us[ing] the Iowa formula,”
186
the Court could not conclude that
“the Iowa formula was at fault for whatever overlap may have ex-
180
They did not yet understand that although internally inconsistent mismatches were pro-
tectionist, internally consistent mismatches are not. See Knoll & Mason, supra note 73, at 312 R
(explaining which types of tax mismatches are protectionist).
181
Incidentally, although it played no role in the decision in Moorman, the challenged re-
gime in Moorman was internally consistent, and therefore also would be upheld under the
Court’s post-Wynne jurisprudence.
182
See Ruth Mason, Delegating Up: State Conformity with the Federal Tax Base, 62 D
UKE
L.J. 1267, 1269 (2013).
183
Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. 267, 271–72 (1978); id. at 283 (Powell J., dissenting)
(noting that forty-four out of forty-five states with income taxes used the three-factor formula).
184
Id. at 270, 276 (majority opinion).
185
Id. at 277 (“[W]e could not accept appellant’s argument that Iowa, rather than Illinois,
was necessarily at fault in a constitutional sense.”).
186
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 37 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 37
isted.”
187
The Court specifically refused to use the dominant Massa-
chusetts formula as a benchmark for evaluating Iowa’s rule, reasoning
that doing so would require “the prevalent practice [to] be endorsed
as the constitutional rule.”
188
The Court resisted such endorsement,
even though it would have prevented double taxation, because the
Constitution is “neutral with respect to the content of any uniform
rule.”
189
Endorsing the Massachusetts formula as a nationwide rule
would have involved “extensive judicial lawmaking.”
190
Although con-
ceding that there may be “an overriding national interest in uniform-
ity” in taxation, the majority disagreed that any uniform rule could be
selected by the Supreme Court.
191
Instead, it was to Congress, “and
not this Court, that the Constitution has committed such policy
decisions.”
192
Like the Court’s holding in Barnwell, the majority’s reasoning in
Moorman was that any burden on interstate commerce arising from
legal diversity was not cognizable under the dormant Commerce
Clause. Although forty years separated Moorman and Barnwell, and
although the Moorman Court did not rely on Barnwell, the reasoning
in the two cases is similar in the sense that the Supreme Court would
not attribute the burden arising from a regulatory mismatch to the
challenged state alone—even when the challenged state had an outlier
rule. The Court refused to use other states’ laws as a benchmark, and
it refused to endorse a nationally uniform rule. In contrast, two dis-
senters in Moorman cited Pike and Bibb to argue that the Supreme
Court should have eliminated the mismatch by precluding Iowa’s out-
lier tax rule.
193
ii. Intervention
When mismatch cases do not involve clear protectionism, the
Court takes one of two approaches. Either it summarily upholds the
mismatch on the grounds that doing otherwise would exceed its com-
petence, as in Barnwell and Moorman, or it engages in more meaning-
ful dormant Commerce Clause review—using Bibb balancing as
distinct from Pike balancing—as in the cases discussed in this Section.
187
Id.
188
Id. at 279.
189
Id.
190
Id. at 278.
191
Id. at 280.
192
Id.
193
Id. at 295–96 (Powell, J., dissenting) (citing Bibb); id. at 289 (Powell, J., dissenting)
(citing Pike).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 38 24-FEB-23 14:13
38 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
1. Southern Pacific v. Arizona (1945)
Our first interventionist case, Southern Pacific Co. v. Arizona ex
rel. Sullivan,
194
sharply contrasts with Barnwell. In Southern Pacific,
the Supreme Court considered Arizona’s facially neutral regulation
that, for safety reasons, placed upper bounds on the lengths of passen-
ger and freight trains.
195
Neighboring states had no (or less restrictive)
train-length standards, so challengers complained that the Arizona
rule inhibited interstate commerce by requiring interstate train opera-
tors to remove cars at the border.
196
This is a mismatch burden be-
cause if all states adopted Arizona’s train-length rules, then all train
operators in all states would comply with the Arizona rule every-
where, and cross-border train operators would face no special costs
that in-state operators did not.
197
For example, there would be no bor-
der stops to remove train cars.
The Southern Pacific Court specifically identified the relevant
burden as one associated with state regulatory diversity, and the Court
noted that such diversity “impair[ed]” the “uniformity of efficient rail-
road operation.”
198
Moreover, the Court singled out Arizona’s prac-
tice as restrictive compared to the rules of other states, because, at the
time, many other states had no length limits at all, so it was “standard
practice” to use more train cars than the Arizona law permitted.
199
Southern Pacific marks a sharp contrast with the view expressed by
the Barnwell Court that the content of other states’ rules did not
matter.
200
Although the Southern Pacific Court employed balancing, the
way it measured the burden and benefits of the Arizona regulation
was different than in the single-state cases, such as Pike.
201
Acknowl-
194
325 U.S. 761 (1945).
195
Id. at 763.
196
Id. at 774.
197
The mismatch burdens arose from differences between Arizona’s rule and other states’
rules (or, in this case, the absence of rules in other states). If all other states had the same rule as
Arizona, then trains everywhere would comply with it, and so trains crossing Arizona’s border
would face no burden that trains traveling exclusively within Arizona did not also face. Because
the burden would disappear upon harmonization, it is a mismatch burden.
198
Southern Pacific, 325 U.S. at 773.
199
Id. at 771.
200
S.C. State Highway Dep’t v. Barnwell Bros., Inc., 303 U.S. 177, 195 (1938) (“The fact
that many states have adopted a different standard is not persuasive.”).
201
Southern Pacific, 325 U.S. at 768–69 (“[R]egulation of local matters may also operate as
a regulation of commerce, in which reconciliation of the conflicting claims of state and national
power is to be attained only by some appraisal and accommodation of the competing demands of
the state and national interests involved.”). Id. at 783–84 (concluding the “state interest is out-
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 39 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 39
edging public safety as a compelling government interest, the Su-
preme Court concluded that Arizona attained only a “slight and
dubious advantage”
202
in safety by implementing length limitations.
And it concluded that the safety interest could not outweigh “the na-
tional interest in keeping interstate commerce free from interferences
which seriously impede it and subject it to local regulation which does
not have a uniform effect.”
203
Thus, it was not the absolute effect of
the Arizona rule on interstate commerce that mattered, but rather its
effect relative to the rules—or lack thereof—of other states. In this
way, the Southern Pacific Court weighed contingent interests on both
sides of the balancing scale: it calculated the burden Arizona imposed
on interstate commerce by reference to other states’ regulation (or
lack thereof), and it evaluated Arizona’s improvement in safety rela-
tive to other states’ rules.
204
Under this calculus, the Court concluded
that the burden outweighed the state interest. The Court furthermore
concluded that if safety concerns warranted train-length limits, only
Congress could impose them.
205
Justice Black dissented from the deci-
sion, arguing that it was improper for the Supreme Court to act as a
“super-legislature”
206
that second-guessed the safety judgments of the
Arizona legislature.
207
2. Bibb v. Navajo Freight Lines (1959)
Decided in 1959, Bibb v. Navajo Freight Lines, Inc.
208
involved a
challenge to an Illinois regulation requiring trucks to have curved
weighed by the interest of the nation in an adequate, economical and efficient railway transpor-
tation service, which must prevail”).
202
Id. at 779.
203
Id. at 776.
204
See, e.g., id. at 778 (comparing Arizona’s accident record after it regulated train lengths
to that of other states without regulation). Id. at 779 (contrasting other measures, such as head-
light, caboose, and full-crew requirements, where the safety gains justified the burden on inter-
state commerce).
205
Id. at 781 (“[W]hen a state goes beyond safety measures which are permissible because
only local in their effect upon interstate commerce, . . . the State will encounter the principle that
such requirements, if imposed at all, must be [imposed] through the action of Congress which
can establish a uniform rule.”). By contrast, in other cases in which the Supreme Court deemed
train safety measures to be less burdensome, the Court permitted them. See id. at 782 (referenc-
ing prior cases in which the Court upheld train regulations requiring full crews, headlights, and
more).
206
Id. at 788 (Black, J., dissenting).
207
Id. at 786 (noting also that Congress had considered imposing the same length limits
that the Court now declared to confer inadequate safety benefits). Justice Douglas likewise dis-
sented, on the grounds that “courts should intervene only where the state legislation discrimi-
nated against interstate commerce.” Id. at 795 (Douglas, J., dissenting).
208
359 U.S. 520 (1959). The Court’s interventionist opinion in Bibb was drafted by Justice
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 40 24-FEB-23 14:13
40 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
mudflaps at a time when all other states either permitted or required
straight mudflaps.
209
The Supreme Court focused on the regulatory
mismatch, identifying “the question [as] whether one State could pre-
scribe standards for interstate carriers that would conflict with the
standards of another State.”
210
As in Southern Pacific, the Bibb Court
took those other states’ regulations as the benchmark in measuring
the burden imposed by Illinois’s different rule. As a result, it attrib-
uted exclusively to Illinois the costs truckers incurred to stop at the
border to weld on new mudflaps, even though those costs arose from
regulatory diversity traceable to at least two states.
211
The Supreme
Court weighed this burden against Illinois’s proffered safety interest,
but, citing findings by the district court, the Court held that the pur-
ported safety advantages of curved over straight mudflaps were insuf-
ficient to overcome the “need for national uniformity in the
regulations for interstate travel.”
212
The Bibb Court, like the Southern
Pacific Court, thus weighed contingent interests on both sides of the
balance scale; it calculated the burden imposed by the Illinois regula-
tion against a baseline of other states’ regulations, and it weighed Illi-
nois’s safety interest against a baseline of other states’ safety
measures.
213
3. Kassel v. Consolidated Freightways Corp. of
Delaware (1981)
In Kassel v. Consolidated Freightways Corp. of Delaware,
214
Iowa
limited trucks on its highways to fifty-five or sixty feet in length, de-
pending on the type of truck.
215
The rule faced a dormant Commerce
Clause challenge because it was “out of step”
216
with those of many
other states, which permitted sixty-five-foot trucks on their highways.
In evaluating the challenge to the mismatched rule, the Supreme
Court used external benchmarks. For example, in determining that the
Douglas, who fourteen years earlier dissented in Southern Pacific, arguing that the Court should
not have intervened because the Arizona law was not discriminatory. Id. at 521.
209
Id. at 521–23.
210
Id. at 526.
211
Id. at 524–25, 527.
212
Id. at 527 (quoting Morgan v. Virginia, 328 U.S. 373, 386 (1946)); id. at 530.
213
The state relied on Barnwell to argue that “a federal court is precluded from weighing
the relative merits of the contour mudguard against any other kind of mudguard.” Id. at 528. In
rejecting this argument, the Supreme Court referred to the “equal footing” of the states, whose
statutes “are of equal dignity when measured against the Commerce Clause.” Id. at 529.
214
450 U.S. 662 (1981).
215
Id. at 665–66. Each limit applied to a different kind of truck. Id.
216
Id. at 671.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 41 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 41
burden on interstate commerce included the need to detour around
Iowa or switch to smaller trucks, the Supreme Court implicitly used
other states’ preexisting regulations as a baseline.
217
The Court thus
regarded Iowa alone as causing interstate truckers to incur switching
and detour costs.
218
Iowa defended its rule on safety grounds, but in
weighing the state’s safety concerns, the Court again conducted a rela-
tive, not absolute, inquiry. Specifically, the Court used other states’
regulations as a benchmark by comparing the safety of Iowa’s rule to
the safety of other states’ rules.
219
Citing the trial court’s findings, the
Court concluded that the comparative safety benefit from Iowa’s
shorter length limits was “illusory.”
220
Moreover, the Court found that
because the regulation would “bear[] disproportionately on out-of-
state residents and businesses,” it was not due the typical deference
shown by courts to safety regulations.
221
In striking down the regula-
tion, the Court also noted that exceptions to Iowa’s truck length limits
were “helpful to local interests,” while burdening out-of-state inter-
ests, which raised suspicion that Iowa’s regulation “may not have been
designed to ban dangerous trucks, but rather to discourage interstate
truck traffic.”
222
Indeed, two concurring justices found the regulation
protectionist. By contrast, citing Barnwell, three dissenters invoked
the noninterventionist approach. They concluded that a court’s role in
dormant Commerce Clause cases was limited to determining whether
the challenged regulation, “although rational, is merely a pretext for
discrimination against interstate commerce.”
223
4. Minnesota v. Clover Leaf Creamery Co. (1981)
In 1981 in Minnesota v. Clover Leaf Creamery Co.,
224
Minnesota
banned the sale of milk in plastic containers because use of such con-
tainers “presents a solid waste management problem for the state,
promotes energy waste, and depletes natural resources.”
225
On an evi-
dentiary record it described as mixed, the trial court held that Minne-
sota adopted the regulation to advantage the Minnesota pulp wood
217
See id. at 671, 674.
218
See id. at 667, 671.
219
Id. at 671; id. at 673 (citing studies and testimony comparing safety of fifty-five-foot to
sixty-five-foot trucks).
220
Id. at 671.
221
Id. at 676–77.
222
Id. Iowa exempted from the regulation individuals and businesses in important border
cities, which covered Iowa’s ten largest cities. Id. at 676.
223
Id. at 692 (Rehnquist, J., dissenting).
224
449 U.S. 456 (1981).
225
Id. at 457 (quoting M
INN
. S
TAT
. § 116F.21 (1978) (repealed 1981)).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 42 24-FEB-23 14:13
42 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
industry, which made materials used in paper milk cartons.
226
The
Minnesota Supreme Court, by contrast, found that although Minne-
sota passed the regulation for the legitimate purpose of “encouraging
[] reuse and recycling of materials and reducing the amount and type
of material entering the solid waste stream,” the regulation was not
rationally related to achieving that purpose, and therefore the court
struck the regulation under the Equal Protection Clause without
reaching the dormant Commerce Clause.
227
The Supreme Court reversed. On the equal protection claim, the
Supreme Court concluded that the plastic container ban was rationally
related to Minnesota’s environmental goals.
228
The Supreme Court
then turned to the dormant Commerce Clause and concluded, citing
Pike, that “[e]ven granting that the out-of-state plastics industry is
burdened relatively more heavily than the Minnesota pulpwood in-
dustry, we find that this burden is not ‘clearly excessive’ in light of the
substantial state interest in promoting conservation of energy and
other natural resources and easing solid waste disposal problems.”
229
Interestingly, although the Supreme Court used external benchmark-
ing to determine the burden of Minnesota’s rule—it compared Minne-
sota’s plastic-container ban to other states’ laws permitting plastic—it
did not benchmark Minnesota’s environmental goals against the regu-
lations of any other states. This choice may have been motivated by
the difference in purposes animating Minnesota’s plastic ban as com-
pared to other states’ packaging rules, which did not serve environ-
mental goals. Ultimately, the Supreme Court held that the regulation
was “nondiscriminatory” and that its burden on interstate commerce
was small relative to Minnesota’s interest in protecting the environ-
ment by banning plastic jugs.
230
Although he agreed that the statute survived equal protection
challenge, Justice Powell dissented from the dormant Commerce
Clause decision in Clover Leaf. He would have remanded the case to
226
Id. at 460.
227
Clover Leaf Creamery Co. v. State, 289 N.W.2d 79, 82 (Minn. 1979), rev’d, 449 U.S. 456
(1981); see also Clover Leaf, 449 U.S. at 463–64 (noting that the challengers had “produced
impressive supporting evidence at trial to prove that the probable consequences of the ban on
plastic nonreturnable milk containers will be to deplete natural resources, exacerbate solid waste
disposal problems, and waste energy, because consumers unable to purchase milk in plastic con-
tainers will turn to paperboard milk cartons, allegedly a more environmentally harmful
product”).
228
Clover Leaf, 449 U.S. at 459, 466.
229
Id. at 473; see also Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 142 (1970) (articulating
“clearly excessive” standard for burdens on interstate commerce).
230
Clover Leaf, 449 U.S. at 472–74.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 43 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 43
determine whether, as the trial court had found, the regulation was
enacted with protectionist intent.
231
Also dissenting, Justice Stevens
would have deferred to the factual findings of the lower courts, and
therefore he concluded that the “the essential predicate for the major-
ity’s conclusion that the ‘local benefits [are] ample to support Minne-
sota’s decision under the Commerce Clause,’ is absent.”
232
2. Understanding Mismatch Cases
Recognizing the differences between single-state and mismatch
cases does not enable us to explain the different outcomes across the
mismatch cases in a satisfying way. In three out of four of the inter-
state transportation cases this Article discussed—all but Barnwell
the Court balanced, which led it to preclude outlier interstate trans-
portation rules regarding train lengths, mudflaps, and truck lengths. In
Barnwell, however, the Court upheld state regulations involving truck
weight and widths without balancing their adverse effects on interstate
commerce against the challenged states’ interests in enacting the regu-
lations. Outcomes in the product-standards cases were also mixed. In
Hunt, the Court held that the asymmetric burden on interstate com-
merce outweighed the state’s proffered consumer-protection interest;
the Hunt Court did not take seriously the consumer-protection justifi-
cation for North Carolina’s apple labeling rule, in part due to evidence
that protectionism motivated the rule. Unsure of how to balance in
Florida Lime, the Court remanded for a clearer determination of the
state’s interest in the avocado fat-content rule, and specifically,
whether the state adopted the rule for protectionist purposes. In con-
trast, where the Court, as with the plastic-container ban in Clover
Leaf, was convinced of the state’s legitimate interests, it upheld devi-
ating regulations notwithstanding their asymmetric burdens. In Moor-
man, the Court once again returned to the strong noninterventionist
view it had expressed forty years earlier in Barnwell that it had no
power to force a state to conform to the rules—here, the tax-appor-
tionment rules—of other states.
Although separating out the mismatch cases from single-state
cases does not enable us to explain the different outcomes across the
mismatch cases in a satisfying way, it does enable us to draw several
231
Id. at 476–77 (Powell, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part) (“[T]his Court has no
basis for inferring a rejection of the quite specific factfindings by the trial court,” which included
the trial court’s specific finding that the actual purpose of the regulation was to advantage the in-
state pulpwood industry at the expense of nonresident commercial interests).
232
Id. at 488 (Stevens, J., dissenting) (citation omitted) (quoting majority opinion).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 44 24-FEB-23 14:13
44 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
clarifying conclusions. First, as with single-state cases, if protectionist
legislative intent is evident in a mismatch case, then that intent, cou-
pled with protectionist effect, is usually dispositive, notwithstanding
the facial neutrality of the rule.
233
This explains the ultimate preclu-
sion by a California district court of the statute considered in Florida
Lime. Arguably, the presence of protectionist intent also explains the
result in Hunt. And even in cases like Kassel and Clover Leaf, where
the Court went on to balance, some justices, having concluded that
there was intentional protectionism, would have precluded the chal-
lenged regulation on that basis alone.
234
Second, sometimes the Court
intervenes to prevent mismatches, but other times, it does not. De-
pending upon your perspective, nonintervention in mismatch cases re-
flects judicial modesty or judicial abdication. This Article will have
more to say on this topic later.
235
Third, when it does balance in mis-
match cases, to measure the extent of a mismatch burden, the Court
has no choice but to look to the actual substantive laws applicable in
other states. Mismatch burdens are by definition measured against
other states’ actual laws (or lack thereof) because the nature of a mis-
match burden is that it arises from regulatory diversity.
III. T
HE
S
PECIAL
P
ROBLEMS OF
B
IBB
B
ALANCING
To highlight the differences between dormant Commerce Clause
balancing in single-state cases and mismatch cases, we have used
Pike balancing” to refer only to balancing in single-state cases and
Bibb balancing” to refer to balancing in mismatch cases. Several crit-
ical insights emerge from our distinction between Pike and Bibb bal-
ancing. Specifically, single-state and mismatch cases are different and
therefore should be—and aretreated differently by the Supreme
Court. This Part explains how our new doctrinal gloss bears on old
criticisms of dormant Commerce Clause analysis, namely that it is ar-
bitrary and invites “judicial legislation.” To that end, this Part criti-
cally compares single-state and mismatch cases from four
perspectives: (1) the initial decision whether or not the Court should
intervene, (2) the selection of benchmarks against which to evaluate
the burden on interstate commerce, (3) the tendency of preclusion in
233
This is the same reason that we did not find any mismatch cases that involved facial
discrimination. If a case involved facial discrimination, it usually would be summarily precluded,
and so the Court would not engage in fulsome balancing.
234
See Kassel v. Consol. Freightways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 685 (1981) (Brennan, J., concur-
ring); Clover Leaf, 449 U.S. at 475–76 (Powell, J., concurring).
235
See infra Section III.A.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 45 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 45
each type of case to result in judicial legislation, and (4) the number
and complexity of interests that the Court must balance in each type
of case. The goal of this Part is to acknowledge that, although both
single-state and mismatch cases are open to criticism, the criticisms
differ in each type of case. Most importantly, in several respects, mis-
match cases are subject to additional and more significant criticisms
than are single-state cases.
A. Judicial Intervention or Nonintervention
There appears to be broad—albeit not universal
236
—agreement
that courts are entitled to intervene in single-state cases. This Section
explains, however, that no such consensus exists regarding judicial in-
tervention in mismatch cases. As a result, the approach to mismatches
is unsettled, providing little guidance to lower courts as to how to re-
solve cases and little guidance to states regarding how to formulate
their laws to survive dormant Commerce Clause review.
1. Relative Consensus in Single-State Cases
Compared to mismatch cases, there seems to be much less con-
troversy surrounding judicial intervention in single-state cases. First,
intervention in facial discrimination cases has deep support.
237
Indeed,
as a judge on the Tenth Circuit, now-Justice Gorsuch wrote “to the
extent that there’s anything that’s uncontroversial about dormant
commerce clause jurisprudence it may be this anti-discrimination prin-
ciple, for even critics of dormant commerce clause doctrine often en-
dorse it even as they suggest it might find a more textually
comfortable home in other constitutional provisions.”
238
Similarly,
with respect to facially neutral single-state regulations, justices gener-
236
For example, Justice Thomas rejects the dormant Commerce Clause altogether, includ-
ing in cases of facial discrimination. See supra note 18. Because he rejects the dormant Com- R
merce Clause in its entirety, we cannot know whether Justice Thomas regards single-state cases
differently from mismatch cases. In Justice Thomas’s view, the Court acts improperly when con-
sidering either type of case under the dormant Commerce Clause.
237
For discussion of the current Supreme Court justices’ views on discrimination doctrine,
see supra note 51. R
238
See, e.g., Direct Mktg. Ass’n v. Brohl, 814 F.3d 1129, 1150 (10th Cir. 2016) (Gorsuch, J.,
concurring). Supreme Court justices use the terms “discrimination” and “protectionism” inter-
changeably. For discussion of this, see supra Section II.A. Justice Thomas is the most consistent
dissenter from the view described by Justice Gorsuch. United Haulers Ass’n, Inc. v. Oneida-
Herkimer Solid Waste Mgmt. Auth., 550 U.S. 330, 352 (2007) (Thomas, J., concurring in the
judgment) (referring to “the erroneous assumption that the Court must choose between eco-
nomic protectionism and the free market. But the Constitution vests that fundamentally legisla-
tive choice in Congress.”).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 46 24-FEB-23 14:13
46 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
ally seem to regard intervention as appropriate, and justices decide
those cases from a steady normative perspective, one that promotes
free trade.
239
Consistent with the notion that the dormant Commerce
Clause promotes free trade, analysis in cases involving facially neutral
single-state regulation often reads as an attempt to “smoke out”
protectionism.
240
2. Unsettled Approach to Mismatch Cases
Although justices generally agree that “discriminatory” mis-
matches—mismatches that a state enacted to deliberately exclude or
disadvantage interstate commerce compared to in-state commerce—
should be struck down, no similar general agreement exists about
other mismatch cases.
241
Specifically, justices disagree about whether
the dormant Commerce Clause limits regulatory diversity when that
diversity seems to be motivated by a legitimate state interest, rather
than protectionism.
a. Noninterventionist View
Under the noninterventionist view, mismatches that do not in-
volve intentional protectionism are subject to merely rational-basis re-
view.
242
For noninterventionists, regulatory diversity is either
normatively desirable—because, for instance, it promotes government
efficiency, responsiveness, experimentation, and ultimately lib-
erty
243
—or it is an inevitable concomitant of state autonomy that
courts have no authority to curtail.
244
As such, regulatory mismatches
239
See Regan, supra note 16, at 1097, 1269 (arguing that the Court is singularly focused on R
suppressing protectionist legislation, and highlighting that, although the suppression of protec-
tionist legislation aids free trade, such suppression is not the same as supporting laissez-faire or
free markets).
240
Id. (focusing on what Regan called free-movement-of-goods cases).
241
See, e.g., Hunt v. Wash. State Apple Advert. Comm’n, 432 U.S. 333, 352–53 (1977)
(writing, of a facially neutral statute, that it had the “effect of an embargo” and therefore consti-
tuted “discrimination against commerce”).
242
See supra note 174. R
243
Cf. Gregory v. Ashcroft, 501 U.S. 452, 458 (1991) (claiming that federalism “assures a
decentralized government that will be more sensitive to the diverse needs of a heterogenous
society; it increases opportunity for citizen involvement in democratic processes; it allows for
more innovation and experimentation in government; and it makes government more responsive
by putting the States in competition for a mobile citizenry”).
244
Eule, supra note 9, at 442, 445 (arguing that “judicial invalidation of evenhanded state R
commercial legislation through the current weighing process is inconsistent with our constitu-
tional system of representative democracy,” and the “rejection of unfettered trade as an appro-
priate goal of judicial scrutiny of local legislative efforts” would allow for salutary state
experimentation); Regan, supra note 16, at 1187 (“The existence of [regulatory] diversity can R
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 47 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 47
are a permanent feature of federalism. To illustrate the noninterven-
tionist view, this Section considers Barnwell and Moorman, cases in
which the noninterventionist view prevailed, as well as noninterven-
tionist dissents in Southern Pacific and Kassel.
In 1938, the Barnwell Court unanimously held that the burden
arising from mismatched truck width and weight rules “is one which
the Constitution permits because it is an inseparable incident of the
exercise of a legislative authority, which, under the Constitution, has
been left to the states.”
245
Even when they acknowledge that mis-
matches significantly burden interstate commerce,
246
justices holding
the noninterventionist view conclude that the Constitution provides
no authority for courts to eliminate mismatches. The Barnwell Court
expressed this view in typical fashion when it observed that “courts
are not any the more entitled, because interstate commerce is af-
fected, to substitute their own for the legislative judgment.”
247
Rather,
because the “[State] legislature, being free to exercise its own judg-
ment, is not bound by that of other legislatures,”
248
even the fact that
“all [other] states had adopted a single standard” cannot force an out-
lier state to conform to that standard.
249
If regulatory diversity be-
comes too burdensome, the noninterventionist view holds that the
states could take it upon themselves to harmonize their rules, or Con-
gress could enact nationwide rules.
250
In 1978 in Moorman, a six-justice majority held that the Supreme
Court could not force a state to use the same tax-allocation rule as
other states, even if leaving the deviating state’s rule in place would
lead to double taxation, which was presumed to burden interstate
commerce. The Moorman Court emphasized that because mismatches
arise from differences between different states’ rules, no one state
hardly be thought to create a constitutional problem. As I have argued previously, uniformity of
commercial regulation is not a constitutional value.”).
245
S.C. State Highway Dep’t v. Barnwell Bros., Inc., 303 U.S. 177, 189 (1938).
246
Id. at 183 (reciting lower court finding that the challenged regulations “would seriously
impede motor truck traffic passing to and through the state”); Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437
U.S. 267, 277 (1978) (acknowledging risk of burdens due to tax “duplication”).
247
Barnwell, 303 U.S. at 191.
248
Id. at 195.
249
Id. at 196.
250
Id. at 189–90 (“Congress . . . may determine whether the burdens . . . are too great, and
may, by legislation designed to secure uniformity . . . curtail . . . the states’ regulatory power.”);
Moorman, 437 U.S. at 280 (“It is to [Congress], and not this Court, that the Constitution has
committed such policy decisions.”); id. at 279 (noting that any uniform rule “would require a
policy decision based on political and economic considerations that vary from State to State”).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 48 24-FEB-23 14:13
48 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
could be held responsible for them “in a constitutional sense.”
251
Moreover, the Moorman Court observed that harmonizing state rules
was a legislative, not a judicial, function.
252
Dissenting in Southern Pacific, Justice Black likewise argued that
courts had no authority to second-guess the state legislature regarding
nondiscriminatory commercial regulations—particularly when the
challenged regulation was designed to promote public safety.
253
In Jus-
tice Black’s view, if interstate commerce truly required uniform regu-
lation of train lengths, then Congress had the power to affirmatively
establish such uniform rules. Until then, the Supreme Court could not
“den[y] to the state . . . power to protect life and property within its
borders.”
254
Moreover, Justice Black argued that the correct inference
to draw from congressional inaction in the area was that Congress
chose to leave the regulatory decision to the states.
255
Likewise, in his
view, the Supreme Court should “leave that choice to the elected leg-
islative representatives of the people themselves, where it properly
belongs both on democratic principles and the requirements of effi-
cient government.”
256
Dissenting for himself and two others in Kassel, Justice Rehnquist
concluded that “a court is not called upon, as are state legislatures, to
determine what, in its judgment, is the most suitable restriction to be
applied of those that are possible, or to choose that one which in its
opinion is best adapted to all the diverse interests affected.”
257
In
Rehnquist’s view, by striking down Iowa’s truck-length limits, the ma-
jority “oversteps our ‘limited authority to review state legislation
251
Moorman, 437 U.S. at 277 (holding that the challenged state (Iowa) was no more at
fault for the mismatch than was Illinois, the challenger’s home state).
252
Id. at 280; id. at 279 (noting that the only way to prevent burdens arising from mis-
matches in apportionment formulas would be to “require national uniform rules. . . . The Consti-
tution, however, is neutral with respect to the content of any uniform rule.”); Barnwell, 303 U.S.
at 189–90 (“Congress . . . may determine whether the burdens imposed on [interstate commerce]
by state regulation, otherwise permissible, are too great, and may, by legislation designed to
secure uniformity or in other respects to protect the national interest in the commerce, curtail to
some extent the state’s regulatory power. But that is a legislative, not a judicial, function . . . .”).
253
S. Pac. Co. v. Ariz. ex rel. Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761, 789 (1945) (Black, J., dissenting).
254
Id. at 791.
255
Id. at 792 (“[T]o leave the state free in this field was a deliberate choice, which was
taken with a full knowledge of the complexities of the problems and the probable need for
diverse regulations in different localities.”).
256
Id. at 789; see also Eule, supra note 9, at 442 n.89 (“If democracy means anything, it is R
that the choice between competing substantive political values must be made by representatives
of the people rather than by unelected judges.”).
257
Kassel v. Consol. Freightways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 691 (1981) (Rehnquist, J., dissenting)
(quoting Barnwell, 303 U.S. at 190).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 49 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 49
under the commerce clause’ and seriously intrudes upon the funda-
mental right of the States to pass laws to secure the safety of their
citizens.”
258
He emphasized that “[t]he Commerce Clause is, after all,
a grant of authority to Congress, not to the courts.”
259
In addition, noninterventionists underscore other problems with
what we call Bibb balancing—including the problem of choosing a
benchmark and the phenomenon that intervention in such cases typi-
cally involves choosing one state’s law over another. Sections III.B
and III.C below discuss both of these issues. For all of these reasons,
the noninterventionists would sustain state regulatory mismatches re-
gardless of the magnitude of the burden they impose on interstate
commerce, unless it was clear that a state devised a mismatch for pro-
tectionist purposes.
260
b. Interventionist View
The interventionist view, by contrast, draws normative support
from implicit and explicit limits the Constitution places on state power
in the name of preserving the union. Justice Cardozo captured these
themes in his frequently repeated line from Baldwin v. G. A. F. Seelig,
Inc.
261
that “[t]he Constitution was framed . . . upon the theory that
the peoples of the several states must sink or swim together, and that
in the long run prosperity and salvation are in union and not divi-
sion.”
262
This Cardozo quotation suggests that, more than merely
preventing protectionism, a goal of our constitutional order is to ac-
tively forge the states into a federal union with a single national mar-
ket, including by eliminating even non-tariff barriers to a free
interstate market.
263
258
Id. at 687 (citation omitted) (quoting Locomotive Firemen v. Chi., Rock Island & Pac.
R.R. Co., 393 U.S. 129, 136 (1968)).
259
Id. at 690.
260
For example, although Justice Rehnquist strongly backed the noninterventionist view in
Kassel, he observed that intervention would be appropriate if the mismatch were a mere “pre-
text for discrimination against interstate commerce.” Id. at 692 (Rehnquist, J., dissenting).
261
294 U.S. 511 (1935). In Baldwin, the Court precluded a New York regulation that re-
quired out-of-state milk sold into the state to have been purchased at not less than the New York
statutory minimum price for milk. Id. at 528.
262
Id. at 523; see also Am. Trucking Ass’ns, Inc. v. Mich. Pub. Serv. Comm’n, 545 U.S. 429,
433 (2005); W. Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy, 512 U.S. 186, 206 (1994); Healy v. Beer Inst., 491
U.S. 324, 336 n.12 (1989); H. P. Hood & Sons, Inc. v. Du Mond, 336 U.S. 525, 532 (1949); Kassel,
450 U.S. 662 at 687 (Brennan, J., concurring); Exxon Corp. v. Governor of Md., 437 U.S. 117,
152 (1978) (Blackmun, J., concurring in part, dissenting in part).
263
See Daniel Halberstam, Of Power and Responsibility: The Political Morality of Federal
Systems, 90 V
A
. L. R
EV
. 731, 809–811 (2004). For more on the implications of structural federal-
ism for state obligations under the dormant Commerce Clause, see generally Erin F. Delaney &
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 50 24-FEB-23 14:13
50 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
Justices propounding the interventionist view have concluded
that taking the federalism limits on state power seriously requires pre-
clusion of mismatched regulations that—while not intentionally pro-
tectionist—nevertheless unduly burden interstate commerce.
Interventionist justices emphasize the perils of “economic Balkaniza-
tion,”
264
which refers to segmentation of the national marketplace into
smaller markets delineated by state boundaries. Interventionists also
emphasize the impropriety of leaving it to state legislatures to take
adequate account of national and federal interests when enacting leg-
islation. For instance, the Court in Southern Pacific wrote:
For a hundred years it has been accepted constitutional doc-
trine that the commerce clause, without the aid of Congres-
sional legislation, thus affords some protection from state
legislation inimical to the national commerce, and that in
such cases, where Congress has not acted, this Court, and not
the state legislature, is under the commerce clause the final
arbiter of the competing demands of state and national
interests.
265
Jurists taking the interventionist view would not preclude all mis-
matches, no matter how slight their effects on interstate commerce
nor how compelling their justifications.
266
But interventionists do not
see the dormant Commerce Clause as limited to protecting the na-
tional marketplace from only intentionally protectionist mismatches.
Ruth Mason, Solidarity Federalism, 98 N
OTRE
D
AME
L. R
EV
. 617 (2022); Allan Erbsen, Hori-
zontal Federalism, 93 M
INN
. L. R
EV
. 493 (2008).
264
See, e.g., South Dakota v. Wayfair, Inc., 138 S. Ct. 2080, 2089 (2018).
265
S. Pac. Co. v. Ariz. ex rel. Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761, 769 (1945) (citations omitted). Justice
Kennedy, writing for the majority in 2018 in Wayfair, used almost the same language: “Of
course, when Congress exercises its power to regulate commerce by enacting legislation, the
legislation controls. But this Court has observed that ‘in general Congress has left it to the courts
to formulate the rules’ to preserve ‘the free flow of interstate commerce.’Wayfair, 138 S. Ct. at
2089–90 (quoting Southern Pacific, 325 U.S. at 769).
266
For example, the Southern Pacific Court also contrasted its decision to preclude the
challenged train-length rule with its holdings in other train-safety cases in which it upheld the
challenged laws, either because the burden was lower than in Southern Pacific, the safety interest
more compelling, or both. Upheld safety regulations, governed, for example, full crews, head-
lights, heated cabins, and the like. Southern Pacific, 325 U.S. at 782 (“While the full train crew
laws undoubtedly placed an added financial burden on the railroads in order to serve a local
interest, they did not obstruct interstate transportation or seriously impede it. They had no ef-
fects outside the state beyond those of picking up and setting down the extra employees at the
state boundaries; they involved no wasted use of facilities or serious impairment of transporta-
tion efficiency, which are among the factors of controlling weight here. In sustaining those laws
the Court considered the restriction a minimal burden on the commerce comparable to the law
requiring the licensing of engineers as a safeguard against those of reckless and intemperate
habits . . . .”).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 51 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 51
Instead, as the Southern Pacific Court put it, when Congress has not
acted, the Supreme Court must act as “the final arbiter of the compet-
ing demands of state and national interests.”
267
The Southern Pacific
Court also observed that “in general Congress has left it to the courts
to formulate the rules thus interpreting the commerce clause in its
application, doubtless because it has appreciated the destructive con-
sequences to the commerce of the nation if [the courts’] protection
were withdrawn.”
268
And three dissenters in Moorman perceived it as
the Court’s “duty . . . ‘to make the delicate adjustment between the
national interest in free and open trade and the legitimate interest of
the individual States.’
269
A majority of the modern Supreme Court
endorsed the interventionist view taken in Southern Pacific as recently
as 2018, noting that “‘in general Congress has left it to the courts to
formulate the rules’ to preserve ‘the free flow of interstate
commerce.’
270
The interventionist and noninterventionist camps thus diverge
based on their answer to the following question: in the absence of con-
gressional action, should courts intervene in mismatch cases? Nonin-
terventionists see congressional inaction as an implicit grant of
regulatory power to the states, which the courts should not obstruct.
But interventionists view congressional inaction as an implicit charter
for the courts to carefully review state actions that adversely impact
interstate commerce.
3. Comparing Intervention in Single-State and Mismatch Cases
That strong normative arguments support both the intervention-
ist and noninterventionist approaches may help explain why the Su-
preme Court has not steadily committed to one approach over the
other in mismatch cases. Indeed, in the mismatch cases described
above, individual justices were not even consistent in following either
an interventionist or noninterventionist approach. Specifically, more
than half of the justices in the mismatch cases considered above signed
267
Id. at 769.
268
Id. at 770; see also Kassel v. Consol. Freightways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 671 (1981) (“In
the absence of congressional action to set uniform standards,” the Court will not tolerate state
regulations for which the “safety interest has been found to be illusory” and that “impair signifi-
cantly the federal interest in efficient and safe interstate transportation.”).
269
Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. 267, 283 (1978) (Powell, J., dissenting) (quoting
Bos. Stock Exch. v. State Tax Comm’n, 429 U.S. 318, 329 (1977)).
270
Wayfair, 138 S. Ct. 2080, 2090 (2018) (quoting Southern Pacific, 325 U.S. at 770).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 52 24-FEB-23 14:13
52 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
on to both decisions intervening and those not intervening.
271
There is
no obvious partisan valence to the voting patterns in the mismatch
cases described above; both views have been endorsed by justices ap-
pointed by Democrats and by Republicans.
272
Spread out over forty
years, those cases reveal that individual members of the Court do not
seem to regard the doctrinal approach in mismatch cases as a matter
of stare decisis or settled law. This allows the Court—and even indi-
vidual justices—to move back and forth between interventionist and
noninterventionist approaches to mismatches.
In contrast, there seems to be much less normative disputation
surrounding single-state cases, even though, for reasons we discuss
presently, the outcome of single-state cases may not be easy to pre-
dict. Other than Justice Thomas, who rejects the dormant Commerce
Clause outright, justices generally have accepted both that judicial in-
tervention in single-state cases is appropriate and that the goal of such
intervention is to prevent states from inhibiting free trade by enacting
protectionist regulations. Hence the Court’s focus in single-state cases
on protectionist intent. A finding of protectionist intent, which the
Court may feel comfortable ascribing to a state when the immediate
effect of its regulation is to protect in-state economic actors from out-
of-state competitors, enables the Court to resolve a single-state case
easily under Pike balancing. Because protectionism is not a valid state
interest, it supplies no counterweight to offset the challenged regula-
tion’s impact on interstate commerce, and so the Court can easily pre-
clude the regulation. On the other hand, the absence of such
immediately obvious protectionist intent forces the Court to engage in
more robust Pike balancing. And because the justices’ views may dif-
fer on how to evaluate the relevant considerations in the balance—
including how much the challenged regulation burdens interstate com-
merce, whether and to what extent the regulation benefits the enact-
ing state, and whether that benefit could be achieved with lesser
impact on interstate commerce—the outcome of this more robust
Pike balancing in single-state cases can be difficult to predict.
273
This is
the difficulty the late Justice Scalia identified when he wrote in his
Bendix concurrence that Pike balancing involved weighing “incom-
271
The seven cases, in chronological order, were: Barnwell, Southern Pacific, Bibb, Hunt,
Moorman, Clover Leaf, and Kassel.
272
See infra Table.
273
Adding to the uncertainty, before they get to balancing, justices may disagree over
whether the state had protectionist intent (which would trigger analysis akin to strict scrutiny) or
whether the state had no such protectionist intent (which would trigger less searching review).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 53 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 53
mensurables” against each other.
274
This criticism led Justice Scalia to
urge the Court to abandon Pike balancing altogether as inappropriate
for courts, as opposed to the legislature.
275
Justice Thomas shares this
view, but would go further. Whereas Justice Scalia agreed that courts
should preclude discriminatory state regulations, Justice Thomas en-
tirely rejects the dormant Commerce Clause at all. Despite the views
of these two justices, and notwithstanding that the outcome in a Pike
balancing case can be difficult to predict, there otherwise appears to
be little disagreement about whether the Supreme Court is entitled to
consider single-state cases, whether balancing is the right approach to
those cases, and whether the normative goal in such analysis is main-
taining and promoting a national market.
276
Appreciating the differences between single-state and mismatch
cases allows us to conclude that the most biting scholarly criticisms of
dormant Commerce Clause doctrine—that it is arbitrary and that its
rationale is unstated or variable—apply with more force to mismatch
than single-state cases.
277
The normative grounding of single-state
cases has been consistent over time—the dormant Commerce Clause
prevents states from interfering with free trade because such interfer-
ence undermines the national market, erodes interstate unity, and in-
spires retaliation. Differences in outcomes and inability to predict
outcomes reflect disagreement over how to apply the law to the facts
of the particular case. Such differences generally do not reflect funda-
mental disagreement about whether courts are entitled to intervene in
single-state cases.
In contrast, justices disagree over whether mismatch cases war-
rant judicial review at all. The clash between the interventionist and
noninterventionist approaches in mismatch cases generates at least
two problems. First, disagreement over how to resolve mismatch cases
can lead (and has led) to diametrically opposed decisions in cases with
similar facts. For example, the Barnwell Court, citing limits on its insti-
tutional authority, upheld South Carolina’s mismatch on truck widths
and weights,
278
whereas the Kassel Court, citing impediments to inter-
274
Bendix Autolite Corp. v. Midwesco Enters., Inc., 486 U.S. 888, 897 (1988) (Scalia, J.,
concurring).
275
Id. at 898.
276
As noted previously, Justice Gorsuch raised concerns about undue-burden analysis, but
we do not know whether, like Justice Thomas and the late Justice Scalia, he would eschew dor-
mant Commerce Clause balancing, and if so, whether he would disapply it in both single-state
and mismatch cases. See supra note 51.
277
See supra Section I.B.
278
See S.C. State Highway Dep’t v. Barnwell Bros., Inc., 303 U.S. 177, 189 (1938).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 54 24-FEB-23 14:13
54 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
state commerce arising from regulatory diversity, precluded Iowa’s
mismatch on truck lengths.
279
Second, the failure to settle whether bal-
ancing is or is not appropriate in mismatch cases does a disservice to
both courts and state legislatures. State courts and inferior federal
courts are required to follow Supreme Court precedent, and state leg-
islatures are expected to enact constitutional laws. If the Supreme
Court cannot resolve such a basic and fundamental question as
whether intervention is appropriate in mismatch cases, how can infer-
ior courts and legislatures fulfill their obligations?
B. Benchmarking
At a high level of generality, the analysis in every dormant Com-
merce Clause case is the same, namely, the Court balances the burden
on interstate commerce against the state’s interest in the regulation.
280
But significant differences characterize balancing in single-state and
mismatch cases. This Section highlights that the Supreme Court uses
internal benchmarking in single-state cases, but external benchmark-
ing in mismatch cases. This Section also discusses special problems
raised by external benchmarking.
279
See Kassel v. Consol. Freightways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 671 (1981); see also Raymond
Motor Transp., Inc. v. Rice, 434 U.S. 429, 445–46 (1978) (striking down a truck-length limit using
reasoning similar to that in Kassel).
280
The Court also sometimes, but not always, engages in narrow tailoring, although such
narrow tailoring is not a major focus of this Article. See generally Jud Mathews & Alec Stone
Sweet, All Things in Proportion? American Rights Review and the Problem of Balancing, 60
E
MORY
L.J. 797 (2011). “In constitutional systems across the globe, proportionality balancing
today constitutes the dominant, ‘best practice’ judicial standard for resolving disputes that in-
volve either a conflict between (a) two rights claims or (b) a rights provision and a legitimate
government interest.” Id. at 802. Proportionality analysis, which can be traced to German law
but has since spread widely, involves (1) suitability, or what Americans would call rational basis
review, (2) necessity, including a least-restrictive-means test, which is equivalent to what Ameri-
cans would call narrow tailoring, and lastly, (3) “balancing stricto sensu,” or proportionality in
which “the judge weighs, in light of the facts, the benefits of the act (already found to have been
narrowly tailored) against the costs incurred by infringement of the right, in order to decide
which side shall prevail.” Id. at 802–03.
As with single-state cases, the Court uses narrow tailoring in some mismatch cases. Thus,
the Hunt Court considered whether North Carolina could have fulfilled its interest in protecting
consumers from confusion in a less restrictive manner than by forbidding the display of other
states’ apple grades. Hunt v. Wash. State Apple Advert. Comm’n, 432 U.S. 333, 354 (1977) (sug-
gesting that North Carolina allow Washington growers to display the Washington and federal
grades). Likewise, when the California District Court examined the avocado fat-content rule
that had been challenged in Florida Lime, it considered whether California could achieve its goal
to assure that California consumers bought ripe avocados by less restrictive means, including by
using federal days-to-maturity and size standards. Fla. Lime & Avocado Growers, Inc. v. Paul,
197 F. Supp. 780, 787 (N.D. Cal. 1961).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 55 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 55
1. Single-State Cases
As in any dormant Commerce Clause case, in single-state cases,
the Supreme Court must determine the asymmetrical burden the chal-
lenged regulation imposes on interstate commerce. To do so, it em-
ploys what we call an “internal benchmark,” under which it compares
the impact of the challenged state’s rule on in-state commerce with
the impact of the same state’s rule on interstate commerce. For exam-
ple, in a case involving facially discriminatory rules, the Court com-
pares the state’s (worse) treatment of nonresidents or interstate
commerce with the same state’s (better) treatment of residents or in-
state commerce. The difference between the two constitutes the asym-
metrical burden on interstate commerce. There is thus no need in a
facial discrimination case for the Court to learn about or consider the
laws of any state other than the challenged state.
Likewise, the Court need not use external benchmarks in single-
state cases that involve facially neutral rules. For example, in Pike, the
Supreme Court compared Arizona’s interest in ensuring that the mar-
ket understood that the cantaloupes were grown in Arizona to the
burden on interstate commerce arising from the requirement to pack
cantaloupes in Arizona. One may agree or disagree with the Court’s
judgment in Pike that the burden on interstate commerce outweighed
the state’s interest, but the balancing exercise did not require the
Court to examine, or know, the law of any state other than Arizona to
determine either the burden on interstate commerce or the strength of
the state’s proffered interest in the challenged regulation. By contrast,
as the next Section discusses, balancing in mismatch cases requires the
Court to refer to external benchmarks consisting of other states’ ac-
tual laws.
2. Mismatch Cases
In contrast with dormant Commerce Clause balancing in single-
state cases, balancing in mismatch cases uses external benchmarks
consisting of other states’ actual laws. By definition, the asymmetrical
burden on interstate commerce in a mismatch case is conditional. It
arises due to differences between two or more states’ law. Thus, to
know what the mismatch consists of, the Supreme Court must ex-
amine the laws of another state or states. Consider Southern Pacific, in
which the Court expressly compared Arizona’s regulation to that of
other states, concluding that:
Enforcement of the law in Arizona, while train lengths re-
main unregulated or are regulated by varying standards in
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 56 24-FEB-23 14:13
56 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
other states, must inevitably result in an impairment of uni-
formity of efficient railroad operation because the railroads
are subjected to regulation which is not uniform in its appli-
cation. Compliance with a state statute limiting train lengths
requires interstate trains of a length lawful in other states to
be broken up and reconstituted as they enter each state ac-
cording as it may impose varying limitations upon train
lengths. The alternative is for the carrier to conform to the
lowest train limit restriction of any of the states through
which its trains pass.
281
In this way, the Court measured the burden that Arizona imposed on
interstate commerce by reference to the content of other state’s rules.
Likewise in Bibb, the Court understood Illinois’s curved-mudflap re-
quirement to require trucks traveling interstate to weld on curved
mudflaps at the Illinois border.
282
This view of the issue implicitly
takes other states’ laws as the benchmark for measuring the burden
imposed by Illinois’s curved mudflap rule. Similarly, in Kassel, the Su-
preme Court understood the burden Iowa imposed on interstate com-
merce with its more restrictive truck-length rule to include the need
for interstate truckers to switch trucks or to divert around Iowa.
283
Thus, the Court determined the burden Iowa imposed on interstate
commerce against a background of other states’ preexisting regula-
tions. This kind of external benchmarking uses other states’ laws as the
standard for determining the burden the challenged rule imposes on
interstate commerce.
Just as it uses external benchmarking to determine burdens, in
mismatch cases the Supreme Court also uses external benchmarking
to assess the state interest. Specifically, the Court considers whether a
deviating regulation provides any benefit over and above the benefit
conferred by other states’ preexisting regulations. For example, the
Southern Pacific Court measured Arizona’s safety interest relative to
other state’s regimes before it concluded that Arizona’s regulation
“affords at most slight and dubious advantage, if any, over unregu-
lated train lengths.”
284
The Bibb Court likewise conducted a relative
state-interest analysis, comparing the safety of curved mudflaps to the
281
S. Pac. Co. v. Ariz. ex rel. Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761, 773 (1945).
282
Bibb v. Navajo Freight Lines, 359 U.S. 520, 527 (1959) (noting that the case raised the
question “whether one State could prescribe standards for interstate carriers that would conflict
with the standards of another State, making it necessary, say, for an interstate carrier to shift its
cargo to differently designed vehicles once another state line was reached”).
283
Kassel, 450 U.S. at 667.
284
Southern Pacific, 325 U.S. at 779.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 57 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 57
safety of straight mudflaps,
285
and it concluded that the advantage of
curved mudflaps as “a new safety device—out of line with the require-
ments of the other States . . . [was] far too inconclusive” to justify its
burden on interstate commerce.
286
Likewise, in Kassel, the Court ex-
pected Iowa to show that the fifty-five-foot trucks it permitted were
markedly safer than the sixty-five-foot trucks permitted in other
states.
287
3. Comparing Benchmarking in Single-State and Mismatch Cases
External benchmarking raises at least three issues. First, judges
may not agree about which external benchmark to use, which injects
uncertainty into Bibb balancing. Most of the time, the Court uses the
nationally dominant practice as the benchmark. Although Justice
Powell explained that “there can be no rule of 26 States, of 35, or of
45,”
288
it is equally clear that consensus among the other states is im-
portant for choosing the external benchmark for Bibb balancing.
289
But such consensus is not always present. For example, in Kassel, the
dissent noted that there was no real consensus among other states in
their truck-length rules, which called into question whether sixty-five
feet was the appropriate baseline for evaluating Iowa’s rule.
290
Moreo-
ver, even if all other states had identical rules, the question arises as to
why the challenged state’s rule should have to be tested against the
dominant rule. As Justice Rehnquist put it, “there is nothing in the
laws of nature which make 65-foot doubles an obvious norm” for
judging appropriate truck lengths.
291
Identifying the baseline also seems to be problematic when one
state has a rule, but other states have no rule. For example, in South-
ern Pacific, the Court used the absence of regulation in other states as
a baseline to attribute to Arizona all the costs associated with Ari-
zona’s limits on train lengths. But in an interstate transportation case
decided in 1960, Huron Portland Cement Co. v. Detroit,
292
the fact that
other states had no regulation in the area covered by the challenged
285
Bibb, 359 U.S. at 523–30.
286
Id. at 530.
287
Kassel, 450 U.S. at 677.
288
Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. 267, 296 (1978) (Powell, J., dissenting) (arguing
that the majority should have removed the mismatch burden generated by Illinois’s outlier tax
apportionment formula).
289
See Hunt v. Wash. State Apple Advert. Comm’n, 432 U.S. 333, 337 (1977); Bibb, 359
U.S. at 523; Kassel, 450 U.S. at 671; Southern Pacific, 325 U.S. at 774.
290
Kassel, 450 U.S. at 688 (Rehnquist, J., dissenting).
291
Id. at 699.
292
362 U.S. 440 (1960).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 58 24-FEB-23 14:13
58 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
state’s regulation meant that the Supreme Court failed to perceive
that it was even dealing with a mismatch. In Huron, the Supreme
Court considered whether Detroit violated the dormant Commerce
Clause by forbidding ships docked in its ports from emitting more
than a maximum amount of air pollution.
293
Complying with the regu-
lation required ship owners to install pollution-mitigation equipment.
Distinguishing Huron from Bibb, the Court concluded that although
the challenger complained that “local governments might impose dif-
fering requirements as to air pollution, [the challenger] has pointed to
none. The record contains nothing to suggest the existence of any such
competing or conflicting local regulations.”
294
Stating that the dormant
Commerce Clause question “needs no extended discussion,”
295
the
Court easily upheld Detroit’s “[e]venhanded”
296
regulation, which had
been “enacted for the manifest purpose of promoting the health and
welfare of the city’s inhabitants.”
297
Notwithstanding the Court’s conclusion that Huron involved no
regulatory conflict, under our definition, Detroit’s regulation created
a mismatch burden in the same way that Arizona’s did in Southern
Pacific. Specifically, if all ports had Detroit’s rule, then all ships every-
where would comply with it and out-of-state shippers would face no
additional costs to dock in Detroit that they did not face in their home
ports. But because other ports had not adopted the same rule as De-
troit, out-of-state shippers had to buy special equipment just to dock
in Detroit. Because the Detroit regulation did not affirmatively con-
flict with laws adopted by other states or cities, however, the Supreme
Court was unable to perceive a mismatch burden.
298
In Southern Pa-
cific, by contrast, the Court perceived the mismatch and employed an
external reference base consisting of the absence of regulation to mea-
sure the burden Arizona imposed on interstate commerce. Because
the choice of the benchmark often will be determinative under Bibb
293
Id. at 448.
294
Id. (providing a “compare,” that is, “cf.,” reference to Bibb); id. at 444 (citing Southern
Pacific and Bibb for the proposition that “a state may not impose a burden which materially
affects interstate commerce in an area where uniformity of regulation is necessary”).
295
Id. at 448.
296
Id. at 443.
297
Id. at 442.
298
If the Court had perceived the mismatch in Huron, and had it engaged in Bibb balanc-
ing, it presumably would have weighed the burden, which it would have calculated against an
external benchmark consisting of other states’ nonregulation, against Detroit’s interest in reduc-
ing pollution and against other states’ interests in nonregulation, which might include the inter-
est in keeping costs low for shippers.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 59 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 59
balancing, if that choice is unpredictable or arbitrary, so may be the
outcome of the case.
Second, external benchmarking in Bibb cases is properly dynamic
and depends on factors outside the control of any one state. This is
due to the conditional nature of regulatory mismatches. Mismatches
arise from differences between the laws of the challenged state and
the actual present configuration of the laws of other states. As laws
change, the benchmark also changes. Moreover, this is not only the
proper, but the only way to analyze a mismatch case; the crux of a
mismatch case is the difference between the challenged state’s laws
and those of other states. Thus, the exact same law may be constitu-
tional today, but unconstitutional at some point in the future, depend-
ing on intervening changes to other states’ laws. The reverse is also
true: a law deemed unconstitutional today because it conflicts with the
laws of other states could become constitutional in the future if more
states adopted it. This seeming paradox—that widespread adoption of
an unconstitutional regulation could transform it into a constitutional
regulation—is a straightforward implication of the Court’s willingness
to engage in balancing with external benchmarks in mismatch cases.
As with the normative uncertainty regarding whether or not courts
should intervene in mismatch cases, the additional variables and con-
tingencies that arise from external benchmarking make mismatch
cases more vulnerable than are single-state cases to charges of
arbitrariness.
Third, as the next Section explains, external benchmarking leads
to greater policy impacts than does internal benchmarking.
C. Judicial Legislation
This Section explains that eliminating a mismatch requires some
form of regulatory harmonization across the states, whereas no such
harmonization is needed to cure a single-state burden. Thus, preclu-
sion in mismatch—but not single-statecases drives not only changes
in law, but substantive regulatory harmonization. Moreover, for rea-
sons explained here, this harmonization has a deregulatory bias; con-
versely, allowing mismatches to remain will tend to have a pro-
regulatory bias, as discussed later.
299
These phenomena suggest that
criticism that dormant Commerce Clause review leads to judicial law-
299
See infra text accompanying notes 303–04. R
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 60 24-FEB-23 14:13
60 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
making applies with more force to mismatch than to single-state
cases.
300
On the surface, the remedy in single-state and mismatch cases is
the same, namely, preclusion. Differences emerge after preclusion. In
single-state cases, the state typically can cure the constitutional infir-
mity either by equalizing the treatment of insiders and outsiders—as
in cases of facial discrimination—or by reducing or eliminating the of-
fending state’s barrier to interstate commerce—as for regulations that
function equivalently to tolls, like Pike.
301
Preclusion thus creates no
implicit preference for adopting any particular substantive rule. Cur-
ing mismatch burdens, by contrast, requires removing regulatory di-
versity through forbearance, conformity, or coordination. Specifically,
a state could practice forbearance by repealing the offending regula-
tion and replacing it with nothing, or it could conform by adopting the
same substantive regulation as that used by other states. Finally, the
states acting together could coordinate their regulations, for example,
by adopting a rule that would determine which state’s law should ap-
ply in cases of potential conflict.
302
As a practical matter, all three op-
tions involve some form of regulatory harmonization.
When the Court strikes a mismatched state law under the dor-
mant Commerce Clause, in effect it forces the state to harmonize its
rule with the rule of one or more sister states.
303
In particular, preclu-
sion tends to force the challenged state to adopt—or at least permit
the benchmark rule, a phenomenon that could be called harmoniza-
tion by preclusion. Regulatory harmonization is thus an important
outcome of mismatch, but not necessarily single-state, cases. As in any
dormant Commerce Clause case, preclusion in mismatch cases implic-
300
For criticisms of dormant Commerce Clause cases for judicial lawmaking, see discussion
supra Section I.B.
301
Trade law calls this “national treatment;” the Supreme Court calls it “leveling.” See
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade art. III, Oct. 30, 1947, 61 Stat. A-11, 55 U.N.T.S. 194
[hereinafter GATT] (“National Treatment on Internal Taxation and Regulation.”); Comptroller
of Treasury of Maryland v. Wynne, 575 U.S. 542, 598 (2015) (Ginsburg, J., dissenting) (“When-
ever government impermissibly treats like cases differently, it can cure the violation by either
‘leveling up’ or ‘leveling down.’ Whenever a State impermissibly taxes interstate commerce at a
higher rate than intrastate commerce, that infirmity could be cured by lowering the higher rate,
raising the lower rate, or a combination of the two.”).
302
The corporate internal-affairs doctrine, under which other states defer to the charter
state regarding certain corporate regulations, represents a coordination rule. See CTS Corp. v.
Dynamics Corp. of Am., 481 U.S. 69, 89 (1987). For more on coordination rules, see discussion
infra Section IV.B.2.
303
Halberstam, supra note 263, at 810 (criticizing undue-burden cases generally, without R
distinguishing between single-state and mismatch cases, because undue burden cases represent
“a naked effort to contain democratic politics by harmoniz[ation]”).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 61 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 61
itly, if not explicitly, rejects the tradeoffs that the offending state chose
in its political process. But only in mismatch cases does judicial preclu-
sion reject the challenged state’s tradeoffs in favor of different trade-
offs made by other states. For example, in Kassel, Iowa’s legislature at
the margin would have traded less efficient trucking for safer roads.
But other states at the margin chose commerce over safety. When the
Supreme Court determined that Iowa’s shorter maximum truck length
impermissibly burdened interstate commerce as compared to an ex-
ternal benchmark consisting of other states’ longer maximums, the
Court implicitly chose other states’ democratic tradeoffs over Iowa’s.
Some justices object to this type of harmonization by preclusion. For
example, in his dissent in Kassel, Justice Rehnquist criticized the
Court for “essentially . . . compelling Iowa to yield to the policy
choices of neighboring States.”
304
Beyond forcing harmonization, this Article shows that preclusion
in mismatch cases will tend to be deregulatory in ways that preclusion
in single-state cases is not. On the surface, judicial preclusion in both
single-state and interaction cases is deregulatory because after either,
the state must eliminate or revise its regulation. However, because
mismatch cases implicitly involve selecting one regulation over another,
and because commercial actors will tend to challenge stricter and
novel regulations, but not laxer and common regulations, when mis-
match cases end in preclusion, they tend to preclude stricter and novel
regulations. Again, Kassel serves as a good example. Private litigants
challenged Iowa’s stricter law, and the Court used other states’ laxer
laws as the benchmark for evaluating the benefit and burden of Iowa’s
law. In this way, stricter and newer laws face challenges that older and
laxer laws do not; the role of private litigants in dormant Commerce
Clause cases will thus tend to make preclusion on those cases
deregulatory.
The most obvious deregulatory impact of preclusion in mismatch
cases occurs when the challenged state simply repeals its own stricter
rule and adopts the laxer benchmark rule. But deregulation following
preclusion in a mismatch case can work through other mechanisms as
well. Return to Kassel. After the Supreme Court precluded its short-
truck rule, Iowa had to allow other states’ sixty-five-foot trucks on its
roads. Iowa could do this by repealing its own truck-length limit and
conforming to the sixty-five-foot benchmark rule. But Iowa could try
to advance its residents’ preferred tradeoff between safety and com-
304
Kassel v. Consol. Freightways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 699 (1981) (Rehnquist, J., dissenting)
(arguing that only Congress could prescribe a uniform national rule for truck lengths).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 62 24-FEB-23 14:13
62 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
mercial efficiency while simultaneously satisfying its obligations under
the dormant Commerce Clause by retaining its shorter limit for Iowa-
licensed trucks while permitting longer trucks from other states to
drive on its roads. If Iowa maintains its shorter limit for Iowa-licensed
trucks, out-of-state truckers will have a competitive advantage over
Iowa truckers whenever longer trucks are more efficient. This will
tend to advantage out-of-state truckers and will likely lead to more
non-Iowa-licensed trucks on Iowa highways. Thus, out-of-state truck-
ers, who are subject to laxer regulations, can be expected to constitute
a larger share of the Iowa market. In-state truckers, now disadvan-
taged in competition with out-of-state truckers, in turn, can be ex-
pected to lobby for the laxer rule to apply to themselves as well. In
this way, even if it does not lead directly to adoption of the laxer rule
by the precluded state, preclusion pursuant to Bibb balancing will
tend over time to lead to deregulation and to encourage legal harmo-
nization. Economists call this phenomenon—under which laxer regu-
lations spill over to other jurisdictions—the “Delaware Effect” or a
“race to the bottom.”
305
In contrast with mismatch cases, state responses to preclusion in
single-state cases are relatively straightforward. Preclusion of single-
state burdens leads to “equalization” of the in-state and out-of-state
case, or it leads to disapplication of the offending state’s rule in whole
or part. What a state need not do to cure a single-state violation, how-
ever, is to examine—much less accept or adoptthe laws of other
states. Thus, harmonization is not a necessary outcome of single-state
cases.
D. Complexity of Balancing
A persistent criticism of dormant Commerce Clause review con-
cerns the difficulty of conducting balancing analysis.
306
Acknowledg-
305
See generally D
AVID
V
OGEL
, T
RADING
U
P
: C
ONSUMER AND
E
NVIRONMENTAL
R
EGULA-
TION IN A
G
LOBAL
E
CONOMY
5 (1995) (using the terms “Delaware Effect” and “race to the
bottom”). Note that adopting a coordination rule will also tend towards deregulation, as multis-
tate commercial actors respond to the coordination rule. See infra Section IV.B.2. Indeed, the
term “Delaware Effect” refers to the private response to the internal-affairs doctrine, under
which states defer to certain corporate regulation of a company’s charter state. The internal-
affairs doctrine has led multistate companies to disproportionately incorporate in Delaware. See
V
OGEL
, supra, at 5–6. Under the early view of this phenomenon, corporations favored Delaware
because managers sought to take advantage of the state’s management-favorable corporate law.
Under the more recent view, corporations choose Delaware because Delaware’s rules maximize
the value of the firm, which benefits both shareholders and managers.
306
Justice Scalia famously compared balancing state interests and impacts on interstate
commerce to comparing the length of a line to the heaviness of a rock. Bendix Autolite Corp. v.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 63 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 63
ing these concerns, this Section considers whether there is any reason
to expect that balancing would be easier or harder in mismatch cases
than in single-state cases.
First, determining the burden in Bibb cases may be harder than in
Pike cases because determining the magnitude of any disruptive effect
on the national market of a mismatch—as opposed to a single-state
rule that functions equivalently to a toll—requires knowledge of the
law in multiple states and of the goods and services produced by dif-
ferent firms in different states. It also requires knowledge—possibly
deep knowledge—of the marketplace, including competing products,
production techniques, marketing practices, and consumer percep-
tions. These are not assessments that courts are well-equipped to
make. Second, mismatch cases are dynamic—that is, the benchmark
will change as states change their regulations, and as economic actors
adjust their commercial practices. This, in turn, may necessitate more
frequent judicial consideration in mismatch than single-state cases. Put
differently, whereas a decision in a single-state case generally may be
regarded as final, a decision in a mismatch case is only final as long as
the benchmark remains unchanged.
307
Third, mismatch cases are more
Midwesco Enters., Inc., 486 U.S. 888, 897 (1988) (Scalia, J., concurring). We have no special
response to this impossibility or “incommensurability” argument, which applies not only to dor-
mant Commerce Clause review, but to all areas in which courts use balancing to trade off consti-
tutional rights, entitlements, and values. Instead, we merely observe, as have others before us,
that if constitutional courts are the correct institution to make tradeoffs among such interests,
then those courts inevitably will have to balance among them. See generally Mathews & Stone
Sweet, supra note 280, at 803 (defending balancing, which they call by its European name, pro- R
portionality). We also observe that the types of comparisons called for in dormant Commerce
Clause review are less problematic than Justice Scalia’s quip would suggest. As more cases are
heard and more decisions are rendered, earlier decisions provide context for later decisions, so
later decisions can more readily and reasonably be evaluated for their consistency with earlier
decisions. Id. at 820 (“One of the virtues of proportionality balancing is that it allows a court to
claim doctrinal consistency while retaining flexibility across time and cases.”).
307
The fifty-year battle over collection of state sales taxes by remote sellers, which required
the Supreme Court to revisit substantively the same legal issue three times under changing mar-
ket, legal, and technological conditions, provides a nice demonstration of the perils of dynamic
baselines. See Ruth Mason, Implications of Wayfair, 46 I
NT
L
T
AX
R
EV
. 810, 810–14 (2018)
(describing three Supreme Court cases dealing with tax-compliance mismatches, decided over
fifty years, in which the outcome on the dormant Commerce Clause issue changed principally
due to shifting technological and market conditions that altered both burdens and interests).
Although these cases involved dormant Commerce Clause nexus, rather than dormant Com-
merce Clause undue burdens, the legal issues considered were so similar that in dicta in South
Dakota v. Wayfair, the last of the three cases, the Supreme Court concluded by noting that the
Court might have to take up analysis of the burdens and benefits of mismatched tax-compliance
rules in the future under Pike. See South Dakota v. Wayfair, Inc., 138 S. Ct. 2080, 2098 (2018).
Specifically pointing to Pike, the Court stated that “other aspects of the Court’s Commerce
Clause doctrine can protect against any undue burden on interstate commerce, taking into con-
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 64 24-FEB-23 14:13
64 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
difficult for courts to resolve than single-state cases for the simple rea-
son that mismatch cases involve balancing among a larger number of
competing interests than do single-state cases. Single-state cases in-
volve weighing only two interests against each other—the burden on
interstate commerce against one particular state’s regulatory interest.
In this way, single-state cases represent a simple tug-of-war between
the national-market interests and the regulatory interest of the chal-
lenged state. In contrast, mismatch cases involve multifactor analysis.
In addition to implicating national-market interests and the regulatory
interests of the challenged state, mismatch cases also effectively in-
volve a contest among two (or more) states for regulatory control of a
single commercial act that affects both states. In mismatch cases, un-
less the reviewing court sees a clear case of intentional protectionism
(as with California’s fat-content rule for avocados), Bibb-balancing re-
quires adjudicating disputes about whether, in the name of national
market efficiency, one state’s regulations should prevail over another
state’s regulations. When different states adopt different policies,
resolving impediments to interstate commerce that result from those
policy differences implicitly means choosing among the different regu-
lations.
308
Thus, balancing in mismatch cases is more complicated than
in single-state cases. The next Part discusses these issues at greater
length.
IV. T
HE
F
UTURE OF
M
ISMATCH
C
ASES UNDER THE
D
ORMANT
C
OMMERCE
C
LAUSE
So far, this Article has sought to reframe dormant Commerce
Clause doctrine by emphasizing the differences between single-state
and mismatch burdens that, in turn, motivate differences in Pike and
Bibb balancing. This Article also explained how traditional criticisms
of dormant Commerce Clause doctrine apply differently to single-
state and mismatch cases. This Part uses an example from a recent
case involving a challenge to California’s cage-free egg regulation to
consider the most important disputes surrounding regulatory mis-
matches, namely, whether the Supreme Court should intervene in
them, and if so, how it should decide which state’s law prevails. This
sideration the small businesses, startups, or others who engage in commerce across state lines.”
Id.
308
Reticence about refereeing between competing state regulations can be seen elsewhere
in constitutional law. For example, the Supreme Court largely has withdrawn from active inter-
vention in interstate conflicts-of-laws disputes. See Allstate Ins. Co. v. Hague, 449 U.S. 302,
310–13 (1981) (holding that state’s decision to apply its own law will conform to Constitution
provided it is “neither arbitrary nor fundamentally unfair”).
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 65 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 65
Part also suggests ways that the Supreme Court could modify its anal-
ysis in mismatch cases to produce more predictable outcomes, or, in
the alternative, it suggests different decision-making paradigms that
the Court could use to resolve mismatch cases. These alternatives de-
rive from EU law, trade law, and scholarship.
A. A Current Example: Cage-Free Eggs
There are several pending dormant Commerce Clause challenges
to regulatory mismatches—on topics ranging from product stan-
dards
309
to corporate-board composition
310
—that will give courts, in-
cluding the Supreme Court, the opportunity to formally recognize the
distinction between single-state and mismatch cases. To make our ar-
guments about the differences between Pike and Bibb balancing con-
crete, this Section considers one such dispute. In response to
California recently banning the production or sale in California of
non-cage-free eggs, six other states, led by Missouri, challenged the
regulation, arguing that, as applied to eggs produced outside Califor-
nia, the regulation was discriminatory, or, in the alternative, that it
imposed an undue burden on interstate commerce.
311
The Ninth Cir-
cuit dismissed the challenge, holding that the six states lacked standing
to challenge California’s rule. But injured farmers will have standing,
and they presumably will bring their own challenges. If so, any court
that hears the case would consider whether the California cage-free
egg rule violates the dormant Commerce Clause. The law is not
facially discriminatory; California treats in-state and out-of-state eggs
the same; to be sold in California, they must be produced by cage-free
chickens.
312
Notwithstanding its facial neutrality, our analysis suggests
that if the regulation had been enacted with protectionist intent, then
309
See Nat’l Pork Producers Council v. Ross, 6 F.4th 1021, 1025 (9th Cir. 2021), cert.
granted, 142 S. Ct. 1413 (2022) (challenging as a mismatch a California law requiring sows to be
kept in cages larger than those required by other states); see also Jessica Berch, If You Don’t
Have a Cow (or Chicken or Pig), You Can’t Call It Meat: Weaponizing the Dormant Commerce
Clause to Strike Down Anti-Animal-Welfare Legislation, 2021 U
TAH
L. R
EV
. 73, 73 (2021)
(tracking pending dormant Commerce Clause cases related to “the animal-protection move-
ment,” such as labeling laws and laws related to the humane treatment of farm animals).
310
See Joseph Grundfest, Mandating Gender Diversity in the Corporate Boardroom: The
Inevitable Failure of California’s SB 826, at 3 (Stanford L. Sch. & Rock Ctr. for Corp. Govern-
ance, Working Paper Series 232, 2018) (arguing that recent legislation requiring companies head-
quartered in California, regardless of where incorporated, to appoint women and minorities to
their boards violates the dormant Commerce Clause because it conflicts with regulations in the
companies’ incorporation state).
311
Missouri ex rel. Koster v. Harris, 847 F.3d 646, 650–52 (9th Cir. 2017), cert. denied sub.
nom. Missouri v. Becerra, 137 S. Ct. 2188 (2017) (dismissing the case for lack of standing).
312
See id. at 651–52.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 66 24-FEB-23 14:13
66 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
courts typically would preclude it for that reason alone. Some judges
would go no farther, concluding that, after exhausting the inquiry into
intentional protectionism, further judicial intervention into mis-
matches cases is improper. Notice that the consequence of such a view
is that the principal remaining limits on a state’s ability to use mis-
matched rules to burden interstate commerce would be extraterritori-
ality principles developed under the dormant Commerce Clause, the
possibility of federal preemption, and due process limits on the reach
of a state regulatory authority.
Other judges, however, would go on to evaluate the California
regulation as a mismatch burden—namely, a mismatch between Cali-
fornia’s regulation requiring eggs to be cage-free and other states’, in-
cluding Missouri’s, laxer regulations. These judges would apply what
we call Bibb balancing (but which courts typically describe as Pike
balancing).
313
Such Bibb balancing involves choosing an external
benchmark against which to measure the burden of the California
rule. Although this Article noted earlier that there is no obvious, well-
grounded method for selecting external benchmarks for evaluating
mismatched regulations, past experience tells us that the reviewing
court likely would pick an external benchmark consisting of the domi-
nant egg regulation applicable in other states, if one exists, or perhaps
the regulation of the complainant’s state, such as Missouri. In either
case, the reviewing court would judge the California rule against a
baseline consisting of the regulation of another state or states.
Suppose the reviewing court identifies Missouri law as the rele-
vant benchmark. It would then measure the burden that the California
rule imposes on interstate commerce relative to that benchmark. The
resulting burden, which would include the need for out-of-state egg
producers to, for example, buy larger crates, would be attributed
solely to California. Only then, to justify this burden on interstate
commerce, would California be able to bring in its regulatory inter-
ests, such as preventing cruelty to animals and any human health ben-
efits from cage-free over non-cage-free eggs. Assuming these are
legitimate local interests,
314
they too would be judged by an external
benchmark consisting of the laws of other states. California would
313
Interventionist judges also might apply narrow tailoring in mismatch cases, either before
or after balancing. Narrow tailoring is not our main focus.
314
Determining California’s interest could be contentious because California is protecting
not only California chickens, but chickens outside of California as well. Id. at 650–51. Whether
the welfare of egg-laying hens residing in other states is a legitimate state concern in our federal
system is an unanswered question. One reason that an interest in the welfare of animals outside
California might not be a legitimate interest of California is that, in a federation, such an interest
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 67 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 67
thus have to show that its regulation actually advanced California’s
legitimate local public interests—such as improving animal welfare or
human health—compared to the benchmark rule, and that the regula-
tion did so in a manner that did not unnecessarily burden interstate
commerce. As we have explained, precluding the regulation would im-
plicitly endorse the Delaware Effect, under which economic actors
would arrange their affairs to take advantage of the laxest state regu-
lation and in which states competing for economic activity would relax
their regulatory standards. On the other hand, upholding the regula-
tion would implicitly endorse the California Effect, under which strict
state regulations would spill over to other states.
315
Mismatch cases
thus involve not merely a narrow question of national market effi-
ciency, but also the division of regulatory power among the states.
That is, mismatch cases implicitly involve a contest among two or
more states for regulatory control of a single commercial act that af-
fects multiple states.
B. Reforming Bibb Balancing
As an initial matter, we advocate four minor steps to clarify the
dormant Commerce Clause. First, and at a minimum, the Supreme
Court and lower courts should acknowledge the differences between
single-state and mismatch cases, especially the fact that balancing in
single-state cases involves internal benchmarking, whereas balancing
in mismatch cases involves external benchmarking. The second clarifi-
cation involves deference to trial courts. In several mismatch cases,
the Supreme Court essentially conducted a de novo review of the evi-
dence presented at trial, overturning trial court findings regarding the
presence of intentional protectionism.
316
Because the largest area of
might invade the policy prerogatives of other states (in this case, the states where the hens
reside).
315
S.C. State Highway Dep’t v. Barnwell Bros., Inc., 303 U.S. 177, 187 (1938) (“Congress
not acting, state regulation of intrastate carriers has been upheld regardless of its effect upon
interstate commerce.”); Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. 267, 277–78 (1978) (rejecting the
argument that judicial invalidation of a nondiscriminatory state statute is required under the
Commerce Clause to alleviate asymmetrical burdens on interstate commerce); S. Pac. Co. v.
Ariz. ex rel. Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761, 795 (1945) (Douglas, J., dissenting) (“I have expressed my
doubts whether the courts should intervene in situations like the present and strike down state
legislation on the grounds that it burdens interstate commerce.”); Kassel v. Consol. Freightways
Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 705 (1981) (Rehnquist, J., dissenting) (acknowledging that “[w]henever a
State enacts more stringent safety measures than its neighbors, in an area which affects com-
merce, the safety law will have the incidental effect of deflecting interstate commerce to the
neighboring States,” but refusing to strike down the state law).
316
See, e.g., Minnesota. v. Clover Leaf Creamery Co., 449 U.S. 456, 476 (1981) (Powell, J.,
concurring) (noting that “this Court has no basis for inferring a rejection of the quite specific
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 68 24-FEB-23 14:13
68 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
agreement under the dormant Commerce Clause is that it prevents
intentional protectionism, it would seem particularly important for the
Court to defer to trial court determinations regarding such findings, as
long as such determinations are truly independent.
317
Third, to avoid
dormant Commerce Clause challenges to mismatched regulations, the
Supreme Court, where possible, could broadly construe federal laws
that create uniform products standards so as to preempt inconsistent
state standards.
318
Finally, the Court should confirm that because Bibb
balancing is dynamic and depends on facts on the ground, stare decisis
should not attach firmly to decisions in mismatch cases. Changing con-
ditions on the ground—whether economic, regulatory, or commer-
cial—properly affect Bibb balancing.
C. Alternatives to Bibb Balancing
1. Mutual Recognition and Harmonization
One potential alternative solution to mismatch cases would be for
the Supreme Court to adopt (or endorse) coordination rules, which
are rules for picking the prevailing rule. CTS Corp. v. Dynamics Corp.
of America
319
is an example of the Supreme Court deferring to a pre-
existing coordination rule in use by the states.
320
Under the internal
affairs doctrine, states defer to the state of incorporation regarding
regulations that govern a corporation’s “internal affairs.” In CTS, the
Supreme Court determined that, as a practical matter, a state that ap-
plied its antitakeover rules only to companies chartered in its own ter-
ritory created no unconstitutional mismatch risk. The Court’s
reasoning depended on widespread adherence to the internal affairs
factfindings by the trial court”); Barnwell, 303 U.S. at 192–95 (ignoring the factual findings of the
trial court).
317
The concern with relying on lower courts’ factual findings includes that state judges
might be less willing than federal judges to make factual findings against the interests of state
legislatures and in-state voters because in many states, state judges lack the independence of
federal judges. See, e.g., Paul M. Friedman, Threats to Judicial Independence and the Rule of
Law, ABA (Nov. 18, 2019), https://www.americanbar.org/groups/litigation/initiatives/committee-
on-american-judicial-system/in-the-news/threats-to-judicial-independence-and-rule-of-law/
[https://perma.cc/J69M-2TH5] (“In contrast to the institutional independence guaranteed to fed-
eral judges by the Constitution, most state court judges are not so insulated from outside
pressures.”).
318
For example, four justices in Florida Lime would have held that California’s fat-content
rule was preempted by federal agricultural standards that determined the ripeness of avocados
based on picking-date and size. Fla. Lime & Avocado Growers, Inc. v. Paul, 373 U.S. 132, 169
(1963) (White, J., dissenting).
319
481 U.S. 69 (1987).
320
Id. at 78.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 69 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 69
doctrine, and the decision in CTS also had the effect of endorsing the
internal-affairs doctrine as an appropriate coordination rule.
321
The Court of Justice of the European Union (“CJEU“) goes fur-
ther by expressly adopting coordination rules of its own devising. The
CJEU interprets a treaty regime that—like our Constitutionassures
both state regulatory autonomy and free movement of goods, business
establishments, and capital throughout the common market.
322
In
1979, in the famous Cassis de Dijon case, France required fruit li-
queurs to contain at most twenty percent alcohol, whereas Germany
required such liqueurs to contain at least twenty-five percent alco-
hol.
323
As a result, products manufactured to French specifications
could not be sold in Germany, and vice versa. Because the treaties of
the European Union unsurprisingly provided no guidance as to the
appropriate alcohol content of liqueur, it was not clear which state’s
rule should prevail.
To resolve the case, the CJEU fashioned the celebrated “mutual
recognition” requirement, under which products that comply with the
regulation of their state of manufacture are putatively free to circulate
in all other EU states.
324
Mutual-recognition rules specify the jurisdic-
tional basis—call it the jurisdictional hook
325
—that will govern a par-
ticular type of regulation for the whole European Union. The state
that possesses that jurisdictional hook is called the origin state, while
all other EU states are destination states for that type of regulation.
Thus, rather than simply precluding mismatched regulations and leav-
ing it to the challenged state to choose among forbearance, conform-
ity, and coordination as a response, the CJEU itself specifies an EU-
wide coordination rule—that is, it specifies the jurisdictional hook
for a given type of regulation. Again, the best-known example is Cas-
321
It is uncertain whether the internal-affairs doctrine represents a constitutional require-
ment. See generally Richard M. Buxbaum, The Threatened Constitutionalization of the Internal
Affairs Doctrine in Corporation Law, 75 C
AL
. L. R
EV
. 29 (1987).
322
For similarities between the dormant Commerce Clause and the EU fundamental free-
doms, see generally Ruth Mason & Michael S. Knoll, What is Tax Discrimination?, 121 Y
ALE
L.J. 1014, 1106–15 (2012).
323
Case 120/78, Rewe-Zentral v Bundesmonopolverwaltung f ¨ur Branntwein (Cassis de Di-
jon), 1979 E.C.R. 649, ¶ 1–3. Although the literature on mutual recognition is very substantial,
especially in Europe, as far as we know, no one has argued that preclusion or affirmation under
the dormant Commerce Clause doctrine may be understood to implicitly endorse mutual-recog-
nition rules. Cf. Mathews & Stone Sweet, supra note 280, at 823–24. R
324
Cassis de Dijon, 1979 E.C.R. at ¶ 14. See generally Jacques Pelkmans, Mutual Recogni-
tion in Goods. On Promises and Disillusions, 14 J. E
UR
.P
UB
. P
OL
Y
699, 703 (2007).
325
The term “jurisdictional hook” is ours; the CJEU does not use it. We use the term to
avoid ambiguity between “origin state” in a mutual-recognition sense and “origin state” in the
ordinary sense.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 70 24-FEB-23 14:13
70 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
sis, in which the CJEU determined that the jurisdictional hook for
consumer-protection regulation would be the state of manufacture,
and all other states (as “destination states”) would have to accept
products that complied with the rules of their state of manufacture.
326
Mutual recognition combines a uniform jurisdictional hook with lim-
ited preclusion of destination states’ rules.
Mutual recognition relies on a crucial assumption, namely that
there exists a fundamental consonance between different states’ poli-
cies that regulate the same subject matter.
327
The notion of regulatory
consonance works as follows: if the rules of both the origin and desti-
nation states are designed to protect consumers, then either state
should be able to rely on the other’s rule. If this is so, then to promote
market integration, rules that aim at the same outcome should be mu-
tually recognized, even if they differ in specification. However, if the
destination state can point to an important state interest that is not
addressed by the origin state’s rule, then mutual recognition does not
apply, and the destination state may apply its own rule.
328
To avoid
unravelling the benefits of mutual recognition, the CJEU construes
this exception narrowly.
329
Mutual recognition represents a bold intervention. Not only does
the CJEU resolve the particular regulatory conflict before it, but it
promulgates the functional equivalent of a conflict-of-law rule for the
whole EU on the regulatory area subject to conflict. Such an approach
is bold because of its broad applicability. But it also avoids what is,
under the current doctrine of the Supreme Court, a stark choice: a
reviewing court faced with a regulatory mismatch must either choose
one state’s rule over another state’s or allow the conflict to remain.
The U.S. product-packaging cases discussed above, Hunt and
Clover Leaf, can be placed into a mutual-recognition paradigm. In
Hunt, the goal of both the North Carolina and Washington apple-la-
beling regimes were ostensibly to inform the consumer of the quality
of the apples, thereby protecting consumers from fraud or confusion.
Although North Carolina preferred the federal grading regime to the
Washington grading regime, the Supreme Court essentially held that
because the Washington regime was sufficient to meet North Caro-
lina’s policy goal, North Carolina had to recognize that regime, rather
326
Cassis de Dijon, 1979 E.C.R. at ¶ 15.
327
Pelkmans, supra note 324, at 703. R
328
See, e.g., Cassis de Dijon, 1979 E.C.R. at ¶ 8 (recognizing exceptions related to tax,
fairness, public health, and consumer protection).
329
Pelkmans, supra note 324, at 711. R
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 71 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 71
than displace it. This is tantamount to requiring mutual recognition.
By contrast, Minnesota’s environmental goals in Clover Leaf could
not be fulfilled by the plastic milk containers that origin states permit-
ted. Other states’ more permissive container regulations were likely
motivated by goals other than environmentalism. Under a European
conception of mutual recognition, the failure of the origin state’s regu-
lation to meet the destination state’s policy goals may entitle the desti-
nation state to displace the origin state’s regulation. Notions of mutual
recognition also may emerge in narrow tailoring analysis in dormant
Commerce Clause cases. For instance, the Court’s conclusion in Dean
Milk that Madison could have relied on out-of-state inspectors to
achieve its milk-safety goals takes a mutual-recognition approach.
330
Although the parallels between the EU’s fundamental freedoms
and the dormant Commerce Clause are obvious, the Supreme Court
never has adopted the concept of origin and destination states, nor
expressly adopted mutual-recognition rules, even when seized with se-
vere regulatory conflicts.
331
Arguably the closest the Supreme Court
has come to mutual recognition was to approve a coordination rule—
the internal-affairs doctrine—that the states had already adopted
themselves.
332
Moreover, mutual recognition would require courts to
develop an approach to decide which state would serve as the origin
state for any particular situation. In some circumstances, such as the
production of goods, the origin state may seem easy to select. How-
ever, in other circumstances, such as online activities, the issue is more
complicated. Courts could choose the origin state by reference to na-
tional welfare,
333
conflict-of-laws rules,
334
general constitutional princi-
ples,
335
or imagined interstate bargaining.
336
330
Dean Milk Co. v. City of Madison, 340 U.S. 349, 356 (1951).
331
Some might regard authorizing legislation as needed to propound mutual-recognition
rules. One reason to doubt that the Supreme Court would seek to impose mutual-recognition
rules in regulatory mismatch cases is the Court’s virtual withdrawal from a constitutional juris-
prudence of conflict of laws. Douglas Laycock, Equal Citizens of Equal and Territorial States:
The Constitutional Foundations of Choice of Law, 92 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. 257–58 (1992) (citing
Allstate Insurance Co. v. Hague, 449 U.S. 302 (1981), as part of a discussion concluding that “the
modern Supreme Court has all but abandoned the field” of constitutional review of state con-
flict-of-laws rules).
332
CTS Corp. v. Dynamics Corp. of Am., 481 U.S. 69, 78 (1987).
333
Harold W. Horowitz, The Commerce Clause as a Limitation on State Choice-of-Law
Doctrine, 84 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 806, 814 (1971) (advocating that under the dormant Commerce
Clause, the Supreme Court should select national regulations that “would best facilitate multis-
tate commercial transactions”).
334
See generally Laycock, supra note 331, at 252–56 (discussing various approaches to con- R
flicts-of-laws questions).
335
See generally id. at 250–51 (observing in the conflict-of-laws context that although the
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 72 24-FEB-23 14:13
72 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
2. Requiring “National Treatment” for “Like Products”
The European Union is not alone in constraining states’ abilities
to enact and enforce mismatched regulations. The international rules
that have underpinned the global economic system since the end of
World War II do likewise. In 1948, the victorious allies, believing that
a multilateral trade framework would both restrain the protectionist
pressures that exacerbated the Great Depression and promote peace
and security, established the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(“GATT”).
337
The drafters’ goals were to create a framework that
would reduce tariffs and establish a basic code of conduct for interna-
tional trade. In a series of negotiations, the GATT members sharply
reduced their tariff rates.
338
In order to meaningfully hold the member
countries to the tariff-reduction commitments they made, the GATT
also included a requirement of “national treatment.”
339
Under the na-
tional treatment provision, members cannot use internal laws, taxes,
or nontax regulations to discriminate against imports from member
states that are “like” domestic goods.
340
An imported product is “like”
a domestic product if it is “a directly competitive or substitutable
product.”
341
Although it is widely recognized that it has been difficult to apply
the concept of “like product” consistently and uniformly because its
Constitution does not “dictate[] a unique set of choice-of-law rules,” federal courts could use
background constitutional principles to develop such rules, including the principles of (1) equal
citizens, (2) equal states, and (3) territorial states, which Laycock defines, respectively, to mean
that states “must treat the citizens of sister states equally with their own . . . must treat sister
states as equal in authority to themselves . . . [and the idea that the] fundamental allocation of
authority among states is territorial”); see also Erbsen, supra note 263, at 568–69 (“[C]ompeting R
state regulatory interests could lead a court to require one state to yield to another by inferring a
[mandatory] comity principle from the structure of horizontal federalism. . . . A constitutional
common law of comity, if applied with a light touch, could arguably help avoid interstate
friction.”).
336
We are grateful to Dan Ortiz for suggesting Coasian bargaining to us.
337
See GATT, supra note 301; see also D
OUGLAS
A. I
RWIN
, P
ETROS
C. M
AVROIDIS
& R
A
LAN
O. S
YKES
, T
HE
G
ENESIS OF THE
GATT 5–8 (2008).
338
See I
RWIN ET AL
., supra note 337, at 18–20. R
339
GATT, supra note 301, art. III. R
340
There are a few narrow exceptions permitted, such as for protecting health and exhaus-
tible resources and for security. GATT, supra note 301, art. XX, XXI. R
341
See The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT 1947), WTO, https://
www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/gatt47_03_e.htm#annexi [https://perma.cc/YD3P-B7QQ]
(providing interpretative notes about provisions of the GATT); see also WTO, G
UIDE TO
GATT
L
AW AND
P
RACTICE
: V
OLUME
1 121, 124 (6th ed. 1995). In 1995, when the World Trade Organi-
zation (“WTO”), which updated the GATT, was created, the national treatment principle and
the concept of “like products” were maintained.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 73 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 73
boundaries are not well defined,
342
there is at least widespread agree-
ment on what are the relevant factors: the products’ physical charac-
teristics, the end uses of the products, how the products are classified
for tariff purposes, and how consumers view the products.
343
Barring
discrimination against foreign products that are “like” domestic prod-
ucts substantially curtails the ability of member states to enact protec-
tionist policies that rely on small differences across products to justify
differential treatment. It also prevents member states from treating
products differently because of differences in the process or method
of production.
344
Thus, for example, the United States was challenged
under the international trade framework when it banned imports of
tuna that were caught using methods that killed more dolphins than
U.S. standards allowed.
345
The United States was found to have vio-
lated the national treatment standard because the tuna it banned was
“like” the tuna that the United States allowed, namely both were
canned yellowfin tuna (none of which contained dolphin meat).
346
Notice, however, that under the logic of “like product” and “na-
tional treatment,” the United States could have completely banned
the sale of canned yellowfin tuna. Such a complete ban would not im-
pact world trade less than did the U.S. ban on non-dolphin-safe tuna.
But the multilateral trade rules do not aim at eliminating every impact
on world trade that might arise from genuine policy differences. In-
stead, the rules aim to prevent invidious discrimination against foreign
products. With a total ban, U.S. and non-U.S. producers would be
equally affected. But when a country uses a process or method of pro-
duction as a basis for differential treatment, the expectation is that
domestic products will comply (and hence be allowed) whereas for-
eign products will not comply (and hence be excluded).
342
See, e.g., Appellate Body Report, Japan–Taxes on Alcoholic Beverages, WTO Doc. WT/
DS8/AB/R (adopted July 11, 1996) (“The concept of ‘likeness’ is a relative one that evokes the
image of an accordion. The accordion of ‘likeness’ stretches and squeezes in different places as
different provisions of the WTO Agreement are applied. The width of the accordion in any one
of those places must be determined by the particular provision in which the term ‘like’ is encoun-
tered as well as by the context and the circumstances that prevail in any given case to which that
provision may apply.”).
343
Panel Report, Japan–Customs, Duties, Taxes and Labelling Practices on Imported Wines
and Alcoholic Beverages, L/6216 (Nov. 10, 1987), GATT B.I.S.D. (34th Supp.), at 93 (1988).
344
See Robert E. Hudec, “Like Product”: The Differences in Meaning in GATT Articles I
and III, in R
EGULATORY
B
ARRIERS AND THE
P
RINCIPLE OF
N
ON
-D
ISCRIMINATION IN
W
ORLD
T
RADE
L
AW
104 (Thomas Cottier & Petros C. Mavroidis eds., 2000).
345
See Panel Report, United States–Restrictions on Imports of Tuna, DS21/R (Sept. 3,
1991), GATT B.I.S.D. (39th Supp.), at 156–57 (1993).
346
Id. at 204–05.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 74 24-FEB-23 14:13
74 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
If the U.S. Supreme Court were to interpret the dormant Com-
merce Clause to include a principle analogous to the multilateral trade
system’s national treatment principle for like products, states would
be prohibited from using narrow distinctions to differentiate among
products. Thus, for example, because caged eggs and cage-free eggs
are like products different only with respect to production process—
that is, they are the same in their physical characteristics, end uses,
and are seen as close substitutes based on consumer tastes and hab-
its—California would not be able to allow the sale of cage-free eggs
while banning the sale of imported caged eggs. At the same time,
however, California could ban the sale of eggs entirely. Although such
a ban might have a larger impact on interstate commerce than would a
ban of non-cage-free eggs, the logic underlying the multilateral trade
rule is that states will not give in to protectionist pressures if the only
way to do so is by enacting comprehensive bans because such bans
would harm domestic producers (and consumers) as much as out-of-
state producers. Thus, any comprehensive bans would likely reflect
policy preferences other than protectionism. Notice also that if Cali-
fornia did enact a complete ban on the sale of eggs, such a complete
ban would not interfere with any other state’s ability to prescribe reg-
ulations for egg production in their own territory. Thus, California’s
outright ban would not interfere with Minnesota’s ability to regulate
its own territory; mediating such interstate disputes is one of the hori-
zontal federalism concerns addressed by dormant Commerce Clause
review of mismatches.
3. Focusing Exclusively on Legislative Intent
Donald Regan’s 1986 article, The Supreme Court and State Pro-
tectionism: Making Sense of the Dormant Commerce Clause, remains
one of the most influential contributions on the dormant Commerce
Clause. He argued that all the Supreme Court does, and all it should
do, in dormant Commerce Clause cases is smoke out intentional pro-
tectionism.
347
Although Regan limited this argument to what he called
the free-movement-of-goods cases, and so did not include many of the
mismatch cases this Article discussed, the same argument also could
be made with respect to mismatch cases. That is, when faced with a
regulatory mismatch, the Supreme Court could consider only whether
the trial court record supports the conclusion that the mismatch was
undertaken for protectionist reasons. Under this approach, if the in-
347
See generally Regan, supra note 16. R
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 75 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 75
tent was protectionist, the regulation would be precluded; otherwise,
the regulation would be upheld. Thus, trial courts would resolve the
main issue in any mismatch case.
There is an obvious appeal to focusing on intent in mismatch
cases; it would avoid balancing. But even setting aside concerns about
whether a legislature can have a single intention,
348
or concerns about
whether trial courts would fail to uncover intentional protectionism,
349
resolving mismatch cases solely by reference to intentional protection-
ism would seem to be insufficient. First, mismatched regulations seg-
ment the national marketplace even when such regulations are not
motivated by protectionism. Second, limiting dormant Commerce
Clause review to cases of intentional protectionism would seem to
supply the states with a roadmap. To segment the market and to pro-
tect insiders from competition, all a state legislature would need to do
348
In Kassel, Justice Brennan pointed to the gubernatorial veto of a bill passed by the Iowa
legislature that would have increased Iowa’s limits to sixty-five feet. Kassel v. Consol. Freight-
ways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 684 (Brennan, J., concurring). In vetoing the bill, the governor noted
that the regulatory change would have increased traffic and accidents in Iowa. Id. Thus, con-
cluded Justice Brennan, “Iowa’s actual rationale” for the regulation had nothing to do with the
difference in safety between trucks of different lengths; instead, “Iowa sought to discourage
interstate truck traffic on Iowa’s highways.” Id. at 681–82 (Brennan, J., concurring). Brennan
regarded the goal to deflect traffic to be an impermissible state interest because it was “protec-
tionist in nature.” Id. at 685 (emphasis in original). In response, Justice Rehnquist first ques-
tioned whether a legislature could even have “one discernible ‘actual’ purpose” capable of being
discovered by a court. Id. at 702 (Rehnquist, J., dissenting). Next, he noted that “[s]triking down
legislation . . . because of asserted impermissible motives for not enacting other legislation, mo-
tives which could not possibly have been present when the legislation under challenge here was
considered and passed,” was “unprecedented in this Court’s history.” Id. at 705 (emphasis
omitted).
349
Bibb may be an example of failure to uncover intentional protectionism. The late Abner
Mikva, congressman, circuit court judge, and White House counsel, noted that when he was in
the Illinois legislature, he frequently voted “present,” rather than “yea” or “nay,” because a bill
just smelled bad. Interview by Mark DePue with Judge Abner Mikva, former Congressman,
D.C. Cir. Judge, and Clinton White House Couns., in Chicago, Ill. (Oct. 22, 2014), https://pre-
sidentlincoln.illinois.gov/Resources/c013a7b0-0931-4c38-83c4-2ff88a7abf12/
Mikva_Abner_EXCPT_TRSCRPT.pdf [https://perma.cc/VTC5-BXFP]. The example Mikva
gave was a 1955 bill requiring curved mudflaps on Illinois roads. Id. Paul Powell, a powerful
Illinois legislator, who twice served as speaker, had introduced the bill. Id. Mikva was not sure
what was going on, but to him the bill smelled bad. Id.
Although the courts that handled Bibb raised no concerns about improper motives, when
Paul Powell died in 1970, it was clear that Mikva’s nose was onto something. Among the many
assets Powell had in his $4.6 million estate when he died, were 17,000 shares in one Illinois
company that produced curved mudflaps and a $55,000 promissory note from another mudflap
company. Dorothy Clune, Powell Estate Inventory Filed, M
OUNT
C
ARMEL
D
AILY
R
EPUBLICAN
R
EG
., Jan. 29, 1971, at 1. A federal investigation determined that Powell acquired much of his
wealth from bribes, and he had been bribed to introduce the bill that advanced the mudflap
companies’ interests. Fender Guard Admits Writing Law, C
HI
. D
AILY
T
RIB
., Feb. 9, 1957, at 7.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 76 24-FEB-23 14:13
76 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
is adopt a mismatch that asymmetrically burdens interstate commerce
without giving as the reason for doing so the desire to reduce or elimi-
nate competition from outsiders. Savvy legislatures could thus impose
intentionally protectionist mismatches with impunity. Third, limiting
review to intentional protectionism would ignore the structural feder-
alism concerns that mismatch cases raise, including questions regard-
ing proper allocation of power among states. Thus, limiting judicial
review of mismatched regulations only to those motivated by protec-
tionist intent would do nothing to limit even severe intentional regula-
tory spillovers (provided such spillovers were not intentionally
protectionist).
350
C
ONCLUSION
Most commentators and, by our estimates, a majority of the
newly constituted Supreme Court, support the nondiscrimination
strand of dormant Commerce Clause doctrine, but much more contro-
versy surrounds undue burdens. Views diverge about whether regula-
tions that are facially neutral should be immune from scrutiny under
the dormant Commerce Clause. That divergence is not surprising
given the important values on both sides—the interest in preventing
state enmities and protecting the national marketplace on the one
hand, and the interests in preserving state autonomy and regulatory
diversity on the other hand. Dormant Commerce Clause cases involve
trading off these values against each other.
It is worth understanding, however, which cases pose the hardest
problems under the dormant Commerce Clause, and which draw the
most justified criticism. This Article sought to supplement the tradi-
350
An example is a California law that prohibits sales in California of pork from the off-
spring of breeding sows confined in a manner California considers cruel. C
AL
. H
EALTH
&
S
AFETY
C
ODE
§ 25990(b) (West 2022). Such law probably cannot be reasonably said to have
been intended to protect California hog farmers from outside competition because there are so
few hog farmers in California. Petition for a Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of
Appeals for the Ninth Circuit at 17, Nat’l Pork Producers Council v. Ross, No. 21-468 (filed Sept.
27, 2021) (noting that 99.9 percent of pork sold in California is derived from sows outside of the
state). However, the law can be understood as intended to impose California standards on hog
farmers outside of California. Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae Supporting Petition-
ers at 19, Nat’l Pork Producers Council v. Ross, No. 21-468 (filed Jun. 1, 2022) (“Proposition 12’s
primary ‘purpose’—and according to the California Department of Food and Agriculture, its
only substantial purpose—is ‘to prevent animal cruelty by phasing out’ what California voters
deem to be ‘extreme methods of farm animal confinement.’” (citations omitted)). One of the
issues in Nat’l Pork Producers Council v. Ross, set for argument in the Court’s 2022-23 term, is
whether California has a constitutionally legitimate interest in housing conditions of out-of-state
animals. The U.S. Solicitor General argues that California has no such interest. Brief for the
United States, supra, at 19–24.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 77 24-FEB-23 14:13
2023] BIBB BALANCING 77
tional discrimination/undue-burden distinction in dormant Commerce
Clause cases with a distinction that takes account of the type of bur-
den imposed by the regulation: whether it is single-state or mismatch.
Reframing the doctrine allowed us to show that (1) mismatch cases
are meaningfully different than single-state cases, which is why they
receive different treatment by the Supreme Court; (2) there are more
sources of doctrinal uncertainty in mismatch cases than single-state
cases, due to fundamental disagreements about whether and how to
resolve such cases; (3) more so than single-state cases, decisions to
preclude or uphold in mismatch cases tend to endorse particular rules
and policy shifts; and (4) unlike single-state cases that principally raise
concerns about the smooth functioning of the national market, mis-
match cases raise fundamental horizontal federalism questions about
the allocation of power between states. Thus, this Article sought to
make clear what is really at stake in mismatch cases, how they differ
from single-state cases, and why they generate so much controversy.
The goal of this Article was not to argue that the Supreme Court
either should abandon undue-burden balancing in mismatch cases or
engage in more balancing in such cases. Instead, the goal was to clarify
what is actually happening in dormant Commerce Clause cases, in-
cluding mismatch cases, to explain why it matters in terms of regula-
tory outcomes, the national economy, and federalism more generally,
and to offer some rational ways of improving or curtailing balancing in
mismatch cases.
\\jciprod01\productn\G\GWN\91-1\GWN101.txt unknown Seq: 78 24-FEB-23 14:13
78 THE GEORGE WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 91:1
T
ABLE
. A
PPROACH OF
J
USTICES IN
M
ISMATCH
C
ASES
D
ISCUSSED IN
P
ART
II (A
UTHOR
C
REATED
)
351
Justice
Party of
Appointing
President
Barnwell
1938
S. Pac.
1945
Bibb
1959
Hunt
1977
Moorman
1978
Kassel
1981
Clover
Leaf
1981
Black D N N I
Blackmun R I I I N
Brandeis D N
Brennan R I I I I N
Burger R I N N N
Butler R N
Clark D I
Douglas D N I
Frankfurter D I I
Harlan R I
Hughes R N
Jackson D I
Marshall D I N I N
McReynolds D N
Murphy D I
Powell R I I I N/A
Reed D I
Rehnquist R N N
Roberts R N I
Rutledge D I
Stevens R I N I I
Stewart R I I N N N
Stone R N I
Warren R I
White D I N I N
Whittaker R I
351
We are grateful to Lawrence Barker, UVA J.D. expected 2023, for this table. In this
table, “N” indicates a noninterventionist approach, “I” indicates an interventionist approach,
and “N/A” indicates that the justice did not reach the mismatch issue.