u n i t e d s t a t e s c o p y r i g h t o f f i c e
Copyright and the Music Marketplace
a report of the register of copyrights february 2015
u n i t e d s t a t e s c o p y r i g h t o f f i c e
Copyright and the Music Marketplace
a report of the register of copyrights february 2015
Second printing (May 2016)
For a list of corrections from initial printing,
see http://www.copyright.gov/policy/musiclicensingstudy/errata.pdf.
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Preface
Few would dispute that music is culturally essential and economically important to the
world we live in, but the reality is that both music creators and the innovators that
support them are increasingly doing business in legal quicksand. As this report makes
clear, this state of affairs neither furthers the copyright law nor befits a nation as creative
as the United States.
The Copyright Office has previously highlighted the outmoded rules for the licensing of
musical works and sound recordings as an area in significant need of reform.
1
Moreover, the Office has underscored the need for a comprehensive approach to
copyright review and revision generally.
2
This is especially true in the case of music
licensingthe problems in the music marketplace need to be evaluated as a whole,
rather than as isolated or individual concerns of particular stakeholders.
While this view is hardly a surprising one for the U.S. Copyright Office, it is no simple
matter to get one’s arms around our complex system of music licensing, or to formulate
potential avenues for change. For this reason, in early 2014, the Office undertook this
study—with all industry participants invited to participate—to broadly consider the
existing music marketplace.
3
This report is the result of that effort. In addition to identifying the shortcomings of the
current methods of licensing music in the United States, it offers an in-depth analysis of
the law and industry practices, as well as a series of balanced recommendations to
improve the music marketplace.
Acknowledgments
This report was prepared by the Office of the General Counsel, U.S. Copyright Office,
following an exhaustive analysis of industry practices and considerable dialogue with
music creators and the businesses that represent and invest in their interests, as well as
music services and distributors and other interested parties. I am indebted to the staff
who worked so tirelessly and thoughtfully to see the report to fruition and am confident
that it will be a major resource for both Congress and the public.
1
See Maria A. Pallante, The Next Great Copyright Act, 36 COLUM. J.L. & ARTS 315, 334-35 (2013)
(“To make a long story short, Congress could make a real difference regarding gridlock in the
music marketplace.”).
2
See The Register’s Call for Updates to U.S. Copyright Law: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Courts,
Intell. Prop. and the Internet of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 113th Cong. 6 (2013) (statement of
Maria A. Pallante, Register of Copyrights).
3
See 17 U.S.C. § 701(b)(4) (noting that the Register of Copyrights shall conduct studies regarding
copyright and other matters arising under Title 17 or the administration of the Copyright Office).
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
I doubt the report would have been possible without Jacqueline C. Charlesworth,
General Counsel and Associate Register, who oversaw the complex research, public
hearings, writing, and recommendations. It is difficult to say with certainty whether it is
Jacqueline’s outstanding skill set as a lawyer or her extensive background in the music
industry that proved most valuable for this project, but either way she has produced a
report that is fair, rational, and forward-thinking, a fitting framework for a field as
culturally beloved and economically important as music is to the United States.
I am similarly indebted to Sarang (Sy) Damle, Deputy General Counsel, who provided
additional leadership and numerous critical contributions, including deft drafting,
dispassionate analysis, and deep regard for the intersection of music and technology.
I am very grateful as well for the contributions of Regan Smith, Assistant General
Counsel, who oversaw the editing process and the final production of the report.
Assistant General Counsel Steve Ruwe helped with the hearings and provided
substantial research and analysis, especially in the area of statutory licensing. Likewise,
Attorney-Advisors Rick Marshall and John Riley assisted with hearings, research and
writing; John also prepared the helpful and impressive charts on the licensing and
ratesetting processes that are included in the report. I also wish to recognize Michelle
Choe, who is with the Copyright Office as a Barbara A. Ringer Honors Program Fellow,
for her substantial research and writing efforts. Donald Stevens, also a Ringer Fellow,
assisted with particular questions of international law, and Law Clerks Andrew Moore,
Kyle Petersen, Maryna Koberidze, and Megan Hartnett provided valuable research
support, for which I am thankful.
As always, the Copyright Office received significant and timely support from colleagues
outside of Washington, D.C. I so appreciate Professor Rush Hicks and Luke Gilfeather
of the Mike Curb College of Entertainment and Music Business at Belmont University
for facilitating the roundtable held in historic Columbia Studio A on Music Row in
Nashville. My thanks and appreciation, as well, to Professors David Nimmer and Neil
Netanel of the UCLA School of Law for helping to facilitate the Los Angeles roundtable,
and Professor Barton Beebe of NYU School of Law for his assistance with the New York
City roundtable. I would particularly like to acknowledge Representative Jerrold
Nadler, who visited the New York roundtable to share his views about the importance
of these issues.
Last but not least, I am indebted to the many organizations and individuals who
provided written commentary and shared their frustrations, insights, and experiences in
the roundtable discussions. I hope this report helps.
Maria A. Pallante
Register of Copyrights and Director
U.S. Copyright Office
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
TABLE OF CONTENTS
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ............................................................................................................. 1
I. INTRODUCTION .............................................................................................................. 12
A. Study History .......................................................................................................... 14
B. Licensing and Ratesetting Charts ......................................................................... 15
II. MUSIC LICENSING LANDSCAPE ................................................................................ 16
A. Copyright Overview ............................................................................................... 16
1. Brief History of Copyright Protection for Music ...................................... 16
2. Musical Works Versus Sound Recordings ................................................. 18
3. Key Players in the Music Marketplace ....................................................... 18
a. Songwriters .......................................................................................... 18
b. Music Publishers ................................................................................. 19
c. Performing Rights Organizations (“PROs”) .................................... 20
d. Mechanical Rights Administrators ................................................... 21
e. Recording Artists and Producers ...................................................... 21
f. Record Companies .............................................................................. 22
g. Music Providers ................................................................................... 23
h. Consumers ............................................................................................ 24
B. Licensing Musical Works ....................................................................................... 25
1. Exclusive Rights in Musical Works ............................................................ 25
2. Reproduction and Distribution Rights ....................................................... 26
a. Historical Background ........................................................................ 26
b. Mechanical Rights Licensing ............................................................. 28
Statutory Licensing ............................................................................. 28
Voluntary Licenses .............................................................................. 30
Recent Reform Efforts ......................................................................... 31
3. Public Performance Rights ........................................................................... 32
a. The PROs .............................................................................................. 32
b. Antitrust Oversight ............................................................................. 34
Department of Justice Consent Decrees ........................................... 35
Key Antitrust Cases ............................................................................. 38
c. Consent Decree Procedures ............................................................... 40
4. Statutory License for Public and Noncommercial Broadcasting ............ 42
C. Licensing Sound Recordings ................................................................................. 43
1. Exclusive Rights in Sound Recordings ....................................................... 43
2. Reproduction and Distribution Rights ....................................................... 43
3. Public Performance Rights......................................................................... 43
a. Lack of Terrestrial Performance Right .............................................. 43
i
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
b. Section 112 and 114 Licenses ............................................................. 46
Interactive/Noninteractive Distinction ............................................. 48
Ratesetting Standards ......................................................................... 49
CRB Ratesetting Proceedings............................................................. 50
Royalty Rates ........................................................................................ 51
c. Privately Negotiated Licenses ........................................................... 52
4. Pre-1972 Sound Recordings ......................................................................... 53
D. Synchronization Rights .......................................................................................... 55
E. Licensing Efficiency and Transparency ............................................................... 58
1. Data Standards .............................................................................................. 59
2. Public Data ..................................................................................................... 62
3. Non-Government Databases ....................................................................... 63
4. International Efforts ...................................................................................... 65
5. Data Sharing Initiatives ................................................................................ 66
III. CHALLENGES OF THE CURRENT SYSTEM .............................................................. 68
A. Compensation and Licensing Disparities ............................................................ 69
1. Effect of Market Trends on Creator Income .............................................. 69
From Physical Formats to Downloads to Streaming ...................... 70 a.
Impact of Music Streaming Models .................................................. 73 b.
Non-Performing Songwriters ............................................................ 78 c.
Additional Considerations ................................................................. 78 d.
Piracy ..................................................................................................... 78
Impact of DMCA Safe Harbors ......................................................... 79
2. Disparate Treatment of Analogous Rights and Uses ............................... 81
Inconsistent Ratesetting Standards ................................................... 81 a.
Different Ratesetting Bodies .............................................................. 83 b.
Pre-1972 Sound Recordings ............................................................... 85 c.
Full Federalization Considerations ................................................... 85
Partial Federalization Alternative ..................................................... 86
Terrestrial Radio Exemption .............................................................. 87 d.
B. Government’s Role in Music Licensing ............................................................... 90
1. PRO Consent Decrees ................................................................................... 90
Royalty Rates ........................................................................................ 91 a.
Rate Court Proceedings ...................................................................... 93 b.
Interim Fees .......................................................................................... 94 c.
Inconsistent Regulation of PROs ....................................................... 95 d.
Parties’ Proposals................................................................................. 96 e.
Complete or Partial Withdrawal of Rights....................................... 97
Elimination Versus Expansion of Consent Decrees ...................... 101
Rate Court Changes .......................................................................... 102
Bundled Licensing ............................................................................. 103
Elimination of Section 114(i) Prohibition ....................................... 104
ii
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
2. Mechanical Rights Licensing ..................................................................... 105
Royalty Rates and Standard ............................................................. 105 a.
Administrative Burdens ................................................................... 107 b.
Perceived Unfairness ......................................................................... 108 c.
Lack of Audit Rights .......................................................................... 108
Administrative Issues ....................................................................... 110
Parties’ Proposals............................................................................... 111 d.
Elimination of Statutory License ..................................................... 111
Blanket Licensing .............................................................................. 112
3. Sections 112 and 114 ................................................................................... 114
Royalty Rates ...................................................................................... 114 a.
Interactive/Noninteractive Divide .................................................. 115 b.
Technical Limitations of Section 112 ............................................... 117 c.
Lack of Termination Provision ........................................................ 117 d.
Royalty Distribution Process ........................................................... 118 e.
4. Public and Noncommercial Broadcasting ............................................... 118
5. Concerns Regarding CRB Procedures ...................................................... 119
Inefficiencies and Expense ............................................................... 119 a.
Settlement Obstacles ......................................................................... 121 b.
Discovery Process .............................................................................. 121 c.
C. Licensing Efficiency and Transparency ............................................................. 123
1. Music Data ................................................................................................... 123
Lack of Reliable Public Data ............................................................ 123 a.
Parties’ Views ..................................................................................... 126 b.
2. Usage and Payment Transparency ........................................................... 128
Advances and Equity Deals ............................................................. 128 a.
PRO Distributions ............................................................................. 130 b.
“Pass-Through” Licensing ............................................................... 131 c.
IV. ANALYSIS AND RECOMMENDATIONS .................................................................. 133
A. Guiding Principles ................................................................................................ 134
B. Licensing Parity and Fair Compensation .......................................................... 134
1. Equitable Treatment of Rights and Uses.................................................. 135
Musical Works Versus Sound Recordings ..................................... 135 a.
Terrestrial Radio ................................................................................ 138 b.
Pre-1972 Sound Recordings ............................................................. 140 c.
2. Consistent Ratesetting Standards ............................................................. 142
C. Role of Government in Music Licensing ........................................................... 145
1. Antitrust Considerations ............................................................................ 146
2. The PROs and the Consent Decrees ......................................................... 150
Pandora Analysis ................................................................................ 151 a.
Publisher Withdrawals ..................................................................... 151
Rate Decision ...................................................................................... 153
iii
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Availability of Song Data .................................................................. 155
PRO Ratesetting Process ................................................................... 155 b.
Migrate to Copyright Royalty Board .............................................. 155
Section 114(i) ...................................................................................... 157
Interim Fees ........................................................................................ 157
Partial Withdrawal of Rights ........................................................... 158 c.
Bundled Licensing ............................................................................. 160 d.
3. Mechanical Licensing and Section 115 ..................................................... 162
Free Market Negotiation Versus Collective Administration ....... 162 a.
Publisher Opt-Out Right .................................................................. 164
Full Market Coverage ....................................................................... 165
Cover Recordings .............................................................................. 166
Audiovisual Uses ............................................................................... 167
Shift to Blanket Licensing ................................................................. 169 b.
Ratesetting .......................................................................................... 170 c.
“A s -Needed” Ratesetting .................................................................. 171
Use of Benchmarks ............................................................................ 172
Interim Rates ...................................................................................... 173
Audit Right ......................................................................................... 173 d.
Sunset of Existing Section 115 Licenses .......................................... 174 e.
4. Section 112 and 114 Licenses ..................................................................... 175
Scope of Licenses ............................................................................... 176 a.
Adjust to Include Terrestrial ............................................................ 176
Qualifying Versus Nonqualifying Services ................................... 177
Ratesetting .......................................................................................... 179 b.
Producer Payments ........................................................................... 180 c.
Termination Provision ...................................................................... 181 d.
5. Public and Noncommercial Broadcasting ............................................... 181
D. Licensing Efficiency and Transparency ............................................................. 183
1. Industry Data ............................................................................................... 183
Publicly Accessible Database ........................................................... 183
a.
Adoption of Data Standards ............................................................ 184 b.
2. Fair Reporting and Payment ...................................................................... 186
Writer and Artist Shares ................................................................... 186 a.
Best Practices for Transparency ....................................................... 189 b.
E. An Updated Music Licensing System ................................................................ 189
1. MROs ............................................................................................................ 190
2. The GMRO ................................................................................................... 192
Data-Related Responsibilities .......................................................... 193 a.
Default Licensing and Payment ...................................................... 194 b.
Resources and Funding .................................................................... 196 c.
3. The CRB ........................................................................................................ 197
New Ratesetting Protocol ................................................................. 197 a.
iv
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
All-In Rates for Noninteractive Streaming .................................... 198 b.
GMRO Surcharge .............................................................................. 199 c.
Procedural Improvements................................................................ 199 d.
4. Regulatory Implementation ....................................................................... 201
5. Further Evaluation ...................................................................................... 202
APPENDICES
Appendix A: Federal Register Notices
Appendix B: Commenting Parties and Roundtable Participants
Appendix C: Abbreviations
Appendix D: Licensing and Ratesetting Charts
v
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Executive Summary
The United States has the most innovative and influential music culture in the world,
but much of the legal framework for licensing of music dates back to the early part of the
twentieth century, long before the digital revolution in music. Our licensing system is
founded on a view that the music marketplace requires a unique level of government
regulation, much of it reflected in statutory licensing provisions of the Copyright Act.
The Copyright Office believes that the time is ripe to question the existing paradigm for
the licensing of musical works and sound recordings and consider meaningful change.
There is a widespread perception that our licensing system is broken. Songwriters and
recording artists are concerned that they cannot make a living under the existing
structure, which raises serious and systemic concerns for the future. Music publishers
and performance rights organizations are frustrated that so much of their licensing
activity is subject to government control, so they are constrained in the marketplace.
Record labels and digital services complain that the licensing process is burdensome and
inefficient, making it difficult to innovate.
While there is general consensus that the system needs attention, there is less agreement
as to what should be done. In this report, after reviewing the existing framework and
stakeholders’ views, the Copyright Office offers a series of guiding principles and
preliminary recommendations for change. The Office’s proposals are meant to be
contemplated together, rather than individually. With this approach, the Office seeks to
present a series of balanced tradeoffs among the interested parties to create a fairer,
more efficient, and more rational system for all.
A. Guiding Principles
The Copyright Office’s study revealed broad consensus among study participants on
four key principles:
Music creators should be fairly compensated for their contributions.
The licensing process should be more efficient.
Market participants should have access to authoritative data to identify and
license sound recordings and musical works.
Usage and payment information should be transparent and accessible to
rightsowners.
1
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
In addition to the above, based on the record in the proceeding, the Office has identified
several additional principles that it believes should also guide any process of reform.
These are:
Government licensing processes should aspire to treat like uses of music alike.
Government supervision should enable voluntary transactions while still
supporting collective solutions.
Ratesetting and enforcement of antitrust laws should be separately managed and
addressed.
A single, market-oriented ratesetting standard should apply to all music uses
under statutory licenses.
The Office was guided by all of the above principles in developing its recommendations,
which are summarized below.
B. Licensing Parity and Fair Compensation
Questions of licensing parity and fair compensation are closely tied to the relative
treatment of music rights and rightsholders under the law. The Copyright Office
believes that any overhaul of our music licensing system should strive to achieve greater
consistency in the way it regulates (or does not regulate) analogous platforms and uses.
With that goal in mind, the Office recommends the following:
Regulate musical works and sound recordings in a consistent manner. The
Office believes that, at least in the digital realm, sound recordings and the
underlying musical works should stand on more equal footing. The Copyright
Office’s approach would offer a free market alternative to musical work owners,
in the form of an opt-out right to withdraw specific categories of rights from
government oversight in key areas where sound recording owners enjoy such
benefitsnamely, interactive streaming uses and downloads.
Extend the public performance right in sound recordings to terrestrial radio
broadcasts. As the Copyright Office has stated repeatedly for many years, the
United States should adopt a terrestrial performance right for sound recordings.
Apart from being inequitable to rightsholdersincluding by curtailing the
reciprocal flow of royalties into the United States—the exemption of terrestrial
radio from royalty obligations harms competing satellite and internet radio
providers who must pay for the use of sound recordings. Assuming Congress
adopts a terrestrial performance right, it would seem only logical that terrestrial
uses should be included under the section 112 and 114 licenses that govern
internet and satellite radio.
2
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Fully federalize pre-1972 sound recordings. As it concluded in its 2011 report on
the topic, the Copyright Office believes that pre-1972 recordingscurrently
protected only under state lawshould be brought within the scope of federal
copyright law, with the same rights, exceptions, and limitations as more recently
created sound recordings. The lack of federal protection for pre-1972 sound
recordings impedes a fair marketplace. Record labels and artists are not paid for
performances of these works by digital services, which (at least until recent court
rulings under state law) were considered free from copyright liability on the
sound recording side. At the same time, the owners of the musical works
embodied in these sound recordings are paid for the same uses.
Adopt a uniform market-based ratesetting standard for all government rates.
While in some cases the law provides that the ratesetting authority should
attempt to emulate a free market, in other cases it imposes a more policy-
oriented approach that has led to below-market rates. There is no policy
justification for a standard that requires music creators to subsidize those who
seek to profit from their works. Accordingly, the Office calls for adoption of a
single rate standard—whether denominated “willing buyer/willing seller” or
“fair market value”—that is designed to achieve rates that would be negotiated
in an unconstrained market.
C. Government’s Role in Music Licensing
The government’s involvement in the music marketplace is unusual and expansive
relative to other kinds of works created and disseminated under the Copyright Act. In
many cases, it compels copyright owners to license their works at government-set rates.
Regulation of music publishers and songwriters is particularly pervasive: the two most
significant areas of their market (mechanical and performance licensing) are subject to
mandatory licensing and ratesetting. Antitrust concerns have been the traditional
rationale for government intervention. To be sure, where particular actors engage in
anticompetitive conduct in violation of antitrust laws, that conduct should be addressed.
But compulsory licensing does more than thatit removes choice and control from all
copyright owners that seek to protect and maximize the value of their assets.
Regardless of the historical justifications for government intervention, the Copyright
Office believes that in today’s world, certain aspects of the compulsory licensing
processes can and should be relaxed. The below recommendations offer some ideas for
how that might be accomplished in the various areas of the market where there is
government involvement.
Performing Rights Organizations (“PROs”) and the Consent Decrees
Many important issues have been raised in the Department of Justice’s (“DOJs”)
parallel consideration of the American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers
(“ASCAP”) and Broadcast Music, Inc. (“BMI”) consent decrees. The Office endorses that
3
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
review, and—in light of the significant impact of the decrees in today’s performance-
driven music market—hopes it will result in a productive reconsideration of the 75-year-
old decrees. At the same time, the Copyright Office observes that it is Congress, not the
DOJ, that has the ability to address the full range of issues that encumber our music
licensing system, which go far beyond the consent decrees. In the area of performance
rights, the Office offers the following recommendations:
Migrate all ratesetting to the Copyright Royalty Board (“CRB”). The Copyright
Office believes that allegations of anticompetitive conduct are worthy of
evaluation (and, if appropriate, remedial action) separate and apart from the
determination of fair rates for musical works. Each of these two critical policy
objectives merits government attention in its own right. Accordingly, the Office
proposes that the function of establishing rates for the public performance of
musical works—currently the province of federal district courts under the
consent decrees—be migrated to the CRB. Industry ratesetting is, of course, a
primary function of the CRB, and the CRB has the benefit of experience assessing
a broader spectrum of rate-related questions than the federal rate courts, as well
as specific expertise in copyright law and economics.
Repeal section 114(i) prohibition. Regardless of whether PRO ratesetting is
migrated to the CRB, as further discussed below, the Copyright Office endorses
the proposal that the prohibition in section 114(i) that currently prevents
ratesetting tribunals from considering sound recording performance royalties be
eliminated. Originally designed as a protective measure to benefit songwriters
and publishers, it appears to be having the opposite effect.
Streamline interim ratesetting and require immediate payment of royalties.
Under the consent decrees, anyone who applies for a license has the right to
perform musical works in a PRO’s repertoire—without paying the PRO any
compensationpending the completion of negotiations or rate court proceedings
resulting in an interim or final fee. The problem is exacerbated by the substantial
burden and expense of litigating even an interim rate in federal court. The
Copyright Office believes that to the extent a licensing entity is required to grant
a license upon request, there should be a streamlined mechanism to set an
interim royalty rate, and that the licensee should have to start paying
immediately.
Permit opt-out from PROs for interactive streaming. The Office believes that
music publishers should be able to withdraw specific categories of licensing
rights from their authorizations to the PROs. At least for now, the Office believes
that withdrawal of performance rights should be limited to digital rights
equivalent to those that the record labels are free to negotiate outside of sections
112 and 114—essentially, interactive streaming rights for digital services.
Publishers that chose to opt out would be required to provide a list of their
4
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
withdrawn works and other pertinent information to a central source, such as the
general music rights organization (“GMRO”) discussed below. In addition, the
Office believes that songwriters affiliated with that publisher should retain the
option of receiving their writer’s share of royalties directly through their chosen
licensing collective.
Allow bundled licensing of mechanical and performance rights. Industry
participants support increased bundling of rightsi.e., reproduction,
distribution, and performance rights—in unified licenses to facilitate greater
licensing efficiency. Although bundling of sound recording rights occurs as a
matter of course, various legal restrictions have prevented that same
development on the musical work side. The Office believes that the government
should pursue appropriate changes to the legal framework to encourage bundled
licensing, which could eliminate redundant resources on the part of both
licensors and licensees. This could include allowing the PROs and other entities
to become music rights organizations (“MROs”), which would be authorized to
license both performance and mechanical rights.
Mechanical Licensing and Section 115
Study participants highlighted the serious shortcomings of the 106-year old compulsory
license for “mechanical” reproductions of musical works (e.g., CDs, vinyl records and
downloads) in section 115. On the copyright owner side, parties complained that the
mandatory nature of the license does not permit them to control their works or seek
higher royalties. On the licensee side, parties criticized section 115’s requirement of
song-by-song licensing, a daunting task in a world where online providers seek licenses
for millions of works. In light of these concerns, the Office offers the following
recommendations:
Permit collective licensing of mechanical rights but with an opt-out right for
interactive streaming and download uses. The Office is sympathetic to music
publishers’ arguments for elimination of the compulsory license in section 115 in
favor of free market negotiations. But in light of the diffuse ownership of
musical works, it seems clear that some sort of collective system would be
necessary even in section 115’s absence. The Office thus believes that, rather than
eliminating section 115 altogether, section 115 should instead become the basis of
a more flexible collective licensing system that will presumptively cover all
mechanical uses except to the extent individual music publishers choose to opt
out. At least initially, the mechanical opt-out right would extend to interactive
streaming rights and downloading activities—uses where sound recording
owners operate in the free market (but not physical goods, which have somewhat
distinct licensing practices). As envisioned by the Office, the collective system
would include MROs (as noted, with the ability to represent both performance
and mechanical rights), a GMRO (that would collect for works or shares not
5
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
represented by an MRO or covered by a direct deal), and individual publishers
that choose to opt out. Licensees could thus achieve end-to-end coverage
through the combination of MROs, the GMRO, and direct licensors.
Establish blanket licensing for digital uses under section 115. To further facilitate
the rights clearance process and eliminate user concerns about liability to
unknown rightsowners, the Office believes that mechanical licensing, like
performance licensing, should be offered on a blanket basis by those that
administer it. This would mean that a licensee would need only to file a single
notice with an MRO to obtain a repertoire-wide performance and mechanical
license from that licensing entity. The move to a blanket system would allow
marketplace entrants to launch their services—and begin paying royaltiesmore
quickly.
CRB ratesetting on an “as-needed” basis. The Office believes that the CRB
should continue to set rates under the section 115 license, though with an
important modification: as is now the case under the PRO consent decrees, rather
than establish rates across the board every five years, the CRB would set rates for
particular uses only on an as-needed basis when an MRO and licensee were
unsuccessful in reaching agreement. Other interested parties (such as other
MROs and other users) could choose to join the relevant proceeding, in which
case those parties would be bound by the CRB-determined rate.
Ensure copyright owners possess audit rights. Publishers have long complained
about the lack of an audit right under section 115. In that regard, section 115 is
an outlier—such audit rights have been recognized under other statutory
licenses. The Office believes that the mechanical licensing system should be
amended to provide for an express audit right, with the particular logistics to be
implemented through regulation.
Maintain audiovisual uses in the free market. Record companies proposed
extending compulsory blanket licensing to certain consumer audiovisual
products—such as music videos, album cover videos, and lyric videos—uses that
have traditionally required a synchronization license negotiated in the free
market. The Office is sympathetic to the labels’ concerns, but cannot at this time
recommend that consumer synch uses be incorporated into a government-
supervised licensing regime. The Office does not perceive a market failure that
justifies creation of a new compulsory license, and the market appears to be
responding to licensing needs for consumer audiovisual products.
Section 112 and 114 Licenses
One of the few things that seems to be working reasonably well in our licensing system
is the statutory license regime under sections 112 and 114, which permits qualifying
digital services to engage in noninteractive streaming activities at a CRB-determined (or
6
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
otherwise agreed) rate. Although the differing ratesetting standards for these licenses—
as well as some of the rates established under those standards—have been a source of
controversy, from the record in this study, the licensing framework itself is generally
well regarded. Notwithstanding the comparatively positive reviews of the section 112
and 114 licenses, there are a few relatively minor improvements that the Office believes
should be considered:
Consider ratesetting distinction between custom and noncustom radio. In 2009,
the Second Circuit ruled that personalized radio services are eligible for the
section 112 and 114 licenses. Although the Office has some reservations about
that interpretation, there appears to be no overwhelming call to remove custom
radio from the statutory regime. Nonetheless, within that regime, it may be
appropriate to distinguish between custom and noncustom radio, as the
substitutional effect of personalized radio on potentially competing interactive
streaming services may be greater than that of services offering a completely
noncustomized experience. While the issue could be addressed legislatively, this
does not appear to be necessary, as the CRB has the discretion to set different rate
tiers today when the record supports such an outcome.
Allow fine-tuning of technical aspects of the license through the exercise of
regulatory authority. Internet services have criticized a number of the detailed
limitations that section 114 imposes on compulsory licensees. These include the
so-called “sound recording performance complement,” a restriction that limits
the frequency with which songs from the same album or by the same artist may
be played by the service, as well as a prohibition against announcing upcoming
selections. But for the fact that they appear in the statute itself, such details
would seem to be more appropriately the province of regulation. As suggested
more generally below, Congress may wish to commit nuances like these to
administrative oversight by the Copyright Office.
Consider permitting SoundExchange to process record producer payments.
Record producerswho make valuable creative contributions to sound
recordings—are not among the parties entitled by statute to direct payment by
SoundExchange. In some cases, an artist may provide a letter of direction
requesting SoundExchange to pay the producer’s share of income from the artist
royalties collected by SoundExchange, which SoundExchange will honor. It has
been suggested that this informal practice be recognized through a statutory
amendment. Though it would be beneficial to hear more from artists on this
issue, the Office agrees that in many instances producers are integral creators
and that the proposal therefore merits consideration.
Allow SoundExchange to terminate noncompliant licensees. Unlike section 115,
sections 112 and 114 do not include a right to terminate a licensee that fails to
account for and pay royalties. The Office does not see a justification for
7
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
continued licensing of a user that is not meeting its obligations, and agrees that
the section 112 and 114 statutory licenses should be amended to include a
termination provision akin to that in section 115.
Public Broadcaster Statutory License
Create a unified statutory licensing scheme for public broadcasters. Public
broadcasters must engage in a multitude of negotiations and ratesetting
proceedings in different fora to clear rights for their over-the-air and online
activities. Especially in light of the relatively low royalty rates paid by public
broadcasters, the Office suggests that the ratesetting processes applicable to
public broadcasters be consolidated within a unified license structure under
section 118 under the auspices of the CRB, where they would likely be much
more efficiently resolved.
D. Licensing Efficiency and Transparency
The Office believes that accurate, comprehensive, and accessible data, and increased
transparency, are essential to a better functioning music licensing system. Authoritative
data would benefit all participants in the marketplace for sound recordings and musical
works, and facilitate a more efficient system. In addition, it is essential to make reliable
usage and payment information available to rightsholders. To achieve these twin goals,
the Office offers the following recommendations:
Establish incentives through the statutory licensing scheme for existing market
players to create an authoritative public database. The Copyright Office believes
that any solution to the music data problem should not be built from scratch by
the government but should instead leverage existing industry resources.
Accordingly, the Office recommends that the government establish incentives
through the statutory licensing regime to encourage private actors to coordinate
their efforts and contribute to a publicly accessible and authoritative database,
including by encouraging the adoption and dissemination of universal data
standards. To facilitate this process, the Copyright Office should provide
regulatory oversight regarding standards and goals.
Establish transparency in direct deals. Throughout the study, a paramount
concern of songwriters and recording artists has been transparency in the
reporting and payment of writer and artist shares of royalties, especially in the
context of direct deals negotiated by publishers and labels outside of the PROs
and SoundExchange, which may involve substantial advances or equity
arrangements. These concerns should be addressed as part of any updated
licensing framework, especially one that allows publishers to opt out of the
statutory licensing system and pursue direct negotiations. In the case of direct
deals for rights covered by an MRO or SoundExchange, the Office recommends
8
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
allowing songwriters and artists to elect to receive their shares of royalties from
the licensee through their chosen licensing entity.
E. An Updated Music Licensing System
To implement the principles and recommendations laid out above, the Copyright Office
is proposing an updated framework for the licensing of musical works. The basic
components of this proposal are as follows:
MROs. Under the Office’s proposal, except to the extent they chose to opt out of
the blanket statutory system, publishers and songwriters would license their
public performance and mechanical rights through MROs.
o An MRO could be any entity representing the musical works of
publishers and songwriters with a market share in the mechanical and/or
performance market above a certain minimum threshold, for example,
5%. Existing rights organizations, such as ASCAP, BMI, HFA and others,
could thus qualify as MROs.
o Each MRO would enjoy an antitrust exemption to negotiate performance
and mechanical licenses collectively on behalf of its membersas would
licensee groups negotiating with the MROs—with the CRB available to
establish a rate in case of a dispute. But MROs could not coordinate with
one another and would be subject to at least routine antitrust oversight.
o Each MRO would be required to supply a complete list of the publishers,
works, percentage shares and rights it represented, as well as the MRO’s
licensing contact information, to the GMRO, and would be obligated to
keep that information current. MROs would not have to share all of their
data for purposes of the public database. For example, there would be no
need for an MRO to provide contact information for its members (other
than those that opted out) since the MRO would be responsible for
distributing royalties under the licenses it issued.
o MROs would also be responsible for notifying the GMRO of any
members that had exercised opt-out rights by providing the relevant opt-
out information, including where a direct license might be sought, so
potential licensees would know where to go for license authority.
GMRO. Even though most licensing activity would be carried out by the MROs
and directly licensing publishers, the hub of the new licensing structure would
be the “general” MRO or GMRO. The GMRO would have certain important
responsibilities:
o First, the GMRO would be responsible for maintaining a publicly
accessible database of musical works represented by each MRO, which
9
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
would incorporate data supplied by the MROs and other authoritative
sources. The GMRO would actively gather missing data, reconcile
conflicting data, and correct flawed data, and would also provide a
process to handle competing ownership claims. In addition to musical
work data, the GMRO would also incorporate sound recording data
presumably from SoundExchange—into the public database, and be
responsible for developing additional data that matched sound
recordings with musical works to facilitate more efficient licensing.
o Second, the GMRO would also serve as the default licensing and
collection agent for musical works (or shares of works) that licensees
were unable to associate with an MRO or opt-out publisher. Services
with usage-based payment obligations would transmit records of use for
unmatched works, along with associated payments and an administrative
fee, to the GMRO. The GMRO would then attempt to identify the MRO
or individual copyright owners and, if successful, pay the royalties out. If
unsuccessful, the GMRO would add the usage record to a public
unclaimed royalties list and hold the funds for some period of time—e.g.,
three years—to see if a claimant came forward. As is the case with
SoundExchange, after that period, the GMRO could use any remaining
unclaimed funds to help offset the costs of its operations.
GMRO funding and resources. The Copyright Office believes that both
copyright owners and users should provide support for the GMRO, as both
groups will benefit from its activities. Under the Office’s proposal, every MRO,
as well as SoundExchange, would be required to contribute key elements of data
to create and maintain a centralized music database. MROs would be
responsible for allocating and distributing the vast majority of royalties. In
exchange for these contributions on the part of copyright owners, the Office
believes that most direct financial support for the GMRO should come from fees
charged to users of the section 112, 114 and 115 licenses. Thus, although
licensees would be paying royalties to MROs and individual publishers
directlyand SoundExchange as well—they would have a separate obligation to
pay a licensing surcharge to the GMRO. The surcharge to be paid by statutory
licensees could be determined by the CRB based on the GMRO’s costs (and
without consideration of royalty rates) through a separate administrative
process. The surcharge would be offset by administrative fees and other sources
of income for the GMRO, including any “black box” funds unclaimed by
copyright owners.
Copyright Royalty Board improvements. Under the Copyright Office’s proposal,
ratesetting by the CRB would shift from a five-year cycle to a system under
which the CRB would step in only as necessary when an MRO or
SoundExchange and a licensee could not agree on a rate. The new model would
10
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
create opportunities for combined ratesetting proceedings for noninteractive
services (e.g., internet, terrestrial, and satellite radio) encompassing both sound
recordings and musical works. The Office recommends other procedural
adjustments to the CRB as well—including adjustments to the statutorily
prescribed litigation process and its settlement procedures. It would also be
worthwhile to remove unnecessary procedural details in the statute that are
better left to regulation by the CRB.
Regulatory implementation. The Copyright Office recommends that if Congress
acts to restructure the music licensing system, it would be most productive for
the legislation to set out the essential elements of the updated system but leave
the details to be implemented through regulation by the Copyright Office and, in
ratesetting matters, the CRB. Such a construct would likely be more realistic to
enact than a highly detailed statutory prescription—especially in the case of
music licensing, where the particulars can be overwhelming.
Further evaluation. Should Congress choose to embark upon a series of changes
to the licensing system as described above, the Office recommends that the new
system be evaluated by the Copyright Office after it has been in operation for a
period of several years. Assuming the new licensing framework includes an opt-
out mechanism, the efficacy of that process would be of particular interest.
Congress could choose to narrow or expand opt-out rights as appropriate.
11
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
I. Introduction
The United States has the most innovative and influential music culture in the world,
but our system for enabling the paid use of music—and ensuring compensation for its
creators—lags far behind. The structures that evolved in the previous century to
facilitate the lawful exploitation of musical works and sound recordings, while perhaps
adequate for the era of discs and tapes, are under significant stress. From a copyright
perspective, we are trying to deliver bits and bytes through a Victrola.
It is a testament to the irresistible power of music that industry and market participants
have done their best to adapt the old methods, including pre-digital government
policies, to embrace current technologies and consumer expectations. But the costs of
failing to update our outmoded licensing methods are escalating. Even when
distributors are perfectly willing to pay licensing fees, they may find it difficult to
identify the owners of the music they use. Those seeking to launch new delivery
platforms are constrained—and sometimes even defeatedby the complexities and
expense of convoluted clearance processes. Perhaps most concerning is that many
deeply talented songwriters and developing artists now question whether a career in
music is realistic under the current regime.
As might be expected, many of the issues raised by the participants in this study of the
music marketplace revolved around government mandates, in particular the role of the
antitrust consent decrees governing the licensing of performance rights in musical works
by performing rights organizations (“PROs”), the section 115 “mechanical” license for
the reproduction and distribution of musical works, and the section 112 and 114 licenses
for the digital performance of sound recordings.
There is a profound conviction on the part of music publishers and songwriters that
government regulation of the rates for the reproduction, distribution, and public
performance of musical works has significantly depressed the rates that would
otherwise be paid for those uses in an unrestricted marketplace. The standards
employed for the section 115 and PRO ratesetting proceedings—section 801(b)(1)’s four-
factor test for mechanical uses and the “reasonable fee” standard of the consent decrees
(which cannot take into account sound recording performance rates)are perceived as
producing below-market rates, especially when compared to rates paid for analogous
uses of sound recordings. On the other side of the fence, licensees urge that government
oversight is essential to forestall alleged monopolistic practices on the part of the PROs
and large music publishers.
The PROs are viewed as both as a blessing and a threat. Licensees laud the efficiencies
of the blanket licenses they offer while at the same time bemoaning the societies’
perceived bargaining position as a result of that very breadth. Songwriters, for their
part, are deeply concerned about the potential loss of transparency in reporting and
12
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
payment should major publishers opt to withdraw from the PROs and license
performance rights directly—as some publishers have suggested they may do in a quest
for higher rates than those set by the rate courts under the consent decrees.
With respect to the section 112 and 114 licenses for the performance of sound recordings,
the debate has centered on the disparate rate standards for differing classes of digital
users—the more malleable 801(b)(1) standard that is applied to satellite radio versus the
willing buyer/willing seller standard for competing online radio services—as well as the
overall burden and expense of the CRB ratesetting process. Internet radio providers
complain that the CRB process has yielded rates that have required them to seek
congressional intervention.
There are differing opinions as to how to handle pre-1972 sound recordings, which are
currently outside of the ambit of federal copyright law but protected in varying degrees
under differing state regimes. Some concur with the Copyright Office’s 2011
recommendation that pre-1972 recordings should be brought fully within the scope of
federal copyright protection, but others argue for a more limited fix, or no fix at all.
Meanwhile, since the inception of the study, three courts have held that the public
performance of pre-1972 recordings is subject to protection under applicable state law,
further complicating the licensing landscape.
And last but not least is the longstanding issue of whether terrestrial radio broadcasters
should continue to be exempted under the Copyright Act from paying royalties for the
performances of sound recordings that drive their multibillion dollar industry—a debate
that has been sharpened as online radio services seek to compete with their terrestrial
counterparts.
At the same time, stakeholders widely acknowledge that there is a need for universal
data standards to facilitate the identification of musical works and sound recordings,
and the licensing process generally. In particular, there is broad recognition of the
necessity for reliable data to match sound recordings to the musical works they embody.
But there is discord as to how to address these problems. Some market participants are
willing to share the data they accumulate with the world, while others are reluctant to
do so.
Despite the wide range of viewpoints expressed in the course of this study, the Office’s
review of the issues has confirmed one overarching point: that our music licensing
system is in need of repair. The question, then, is how to fix it, in light of the often
conflicting objectives of longtime industry participants with vested interests in
traditional business models and infrastructure; digital distributors that do not produce
or own music and for which music represents merely a cost of doing business;
consumers whose appetite for music through varied platforms and devices only
continues to grow; and individual creators whose very livelihoods are at stake. This
report seeks to chart a path forward.
13
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Given their complexity and significance, many of the issues addressed below would
themselves be worthy of a separate report. But instead of focusing on each particular
licensing process as an isolated problem, the goal of this study is to illuminate the
system as a whole—including interrelated issues and concernsto see if there may be a
balanced set of changes that could provide benefits to all. Rather than present a detailed
legislative proposal, then, with all of the intricacy that would entail, the report instead
suggests some key principles and modifications that the Copyright Office believes
would be useful in framing a better system.
The ideas described below are thus intended to serve as a useful framework for
continuing discussion of how we might reinvent our music licensing system, rather than
a fully developed answer. As Congress considers a range of potential amendments to
our copyright laws, the Office hopes that interested parties will take advantage of this
unique opportunity to improve our music licensing process for the digital age.
A. Study History
In April 2013, Congress, led by the House Judiciary Committee, announced a
comprehensive review of the nation’s copyright laws to evaluate “whether the laws are
still working in the digital age.”
1
The myriad issues affecting the music industry have
been a significant focus of that review.
2
The Office initiated this study to illuminate critical concerns of the music marketplace
and to identify potential avenues for change. On March 17, 2014, the Office published
an initial Notice of Inquiry in the Federal Register (the “First Notice”) requesting public
comment on twenty-four subjects affecting the existing music licensing environment.
3
1
Press Release, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Chairman Goodlatte Announces Comprehensive
Review of Copyright Laws (Apr. 24, 2013), http://judiciary.house.gov/index.cfm/2013/4/
chairmangoodlatteannouncescomprehensivereviewofcopyrightlaw.
2
Of the seventeen hearings that have been held so far as part of the congressional review, two
were specifically dedicated to music licensing. Music Licensing Under Title 17 (Part I & II): Hearing
Before the Subcomm. on Courts, Intell. Prop., and the Internet of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 113th
Cong. (2014) (“Music Licensing Hearings”). Music industry representatives also participated in a
number of other hearings. See, e.g., Moral Rights, Termination Rights, Resale Royalty, and Copyright
Term: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Courts, Intell. Prop. and the Internet of the H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, 113th Cong. (2014); Section 512 of Title 17: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Courts, Intell.
Prop. and the Internet of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 113th Cong. (2014); The Scope of Fair Use:
Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Courts, Intell. Prop. and the Internet of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
113th Cong. (2014).
3
Music Licensing Study: Notice and Request for Public Comment, 78 Fed. Reg. 14,739 (Mar. 17,
2014). This Notice of Inquiry, along with the Office’s second Notice of Inquiry and Notice of
Public Roundtables, are attached as Appendix A. A list of the parties who responded to the
14
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The Office received 84 written comments in response to its notice, spanning a broad
spectrum of interested parties, including music industry associations, service providers
and technology companies, legal scholars, public interest groups, and individual artists
and creators.
4
In June 2014, the Office conducted three two-day public roundtables in Nashville, Los
Angeles, and New York City.
5
The roundtables provided participants with the
opportunity to share their views on the topics identified in the First Notice and other
issues pertaining to our music licensing system and how it might be improved.
In addition, on July 23, 2014, the Office published a second Notice of Inquiry (“Second
Notice”) requesting further comments on a number of significant issues raised in earlier
comments and discussed at the roundtables.
6
The Office received 51 substantive written
comments in response to the Second Notice, again representing a wide variety of
viewpoints, on these subjects.
7
B. Licensing and Ratesetting Charts
The Office has prepared a series of charts to illustrate our current systems for the
licensing of musical works and sound recordings and the ratesetting procedures under
the several statutory licenses, as well as how those processes would be altered as a result
of the modifications proposed by the Office. These appear at the back of the study in
Appendix D. The Office hopes that these charts will prove helpful to readers as they
make their way through this report.
Office’s Notices of Inquiry, along with a list of participants in the Office’s public roundtables, is
attached as Appendix B.
4
The comments received in response to the First Notice are available on the Copyright Office
website at http://copyright.gov/docs/musiclicensingstudy/comments/Docket2014_3/index.html.
References to these comments in this document are by party name (abbreviated where
appropriate) followed by “First Notice Comments” (e.g., “DiMA First Notice Comments”).
5
See Music Licensing Study, 79 Fed. Reg. 25,626 (May 5, 2014). Transcripts of the proceedings at
each of the three roundtables are available on the Copyright Office website at http://copyright.
gov/docs/musiclicensingstudy/transcripts/.
6
Music Licensing Study: Second Request for Comments, 79 Fed. Reg. 42,833 (July 23, 2014).
7
The comments received in response to the Second Notice are available on the Copyright Office
website at http://copyright.gov/docs/musiclicensingstudy/comments/Docket2014_3/
extension_comments/. References to these comments in this document are by party name
(abbreviated where appropriate) followed by “Second Notice Comments” (e.g., “RIAA Second
Notice Comments”).
15
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
II. Music Licensing Landscape
Our rules for music licensing are complex and daunting even for those familiar with the
terrain. To begin with, our licensing structures must address two different species of
copyrightthe sound recording and the musical workresiding in a single product.
Each of these separate copyrights, in turn, itself represents several different exclusive
rights that may be separately licensed, including the rights of reproduction, distribution,
public performance, as well as the right to synchronize works with visual content.
The situation is further complicated by the fact that many licensing transactions are
regulated by the government. But the government rules have not been implemented in
a unified or systematic fashion. Instead, they represent a series of statutory and judicial
mandates that came into effect at various points during the last century to address
particular concerns of the day. And still more challenging is that not all licensing is
conducted according to these government-mandated protocols. Some licensing is
permitted to transpire in the private marketplace without government oversight. In
addition, there are voluntary workarounds to the government processes—more efficient
alternatives that have grown up like trees around the government rules and are now
deeply rooted.
This section provides an introduction to our music licensing system and those who
participate in it.
8
Before turning to the challenges we face and how they might be
addressed, it is important to understand where we are and how we got here.
A. Copyright Overview
1. Brief History of Copyright Protection for Music
Congress passed the first federal copyright act in 1790.
9
That act did not provide express
protection for musical compositions (or “musical works” in the parlance of the current
Copyright Act), though such works could be registered as “books.”
10
Then, in 1831,
Congress amended the law to provide expressly that musical works were subject to
federal copyright protection.
11
8
As noted above, the Office has included charts in Appendix D of this report that provide a
bird’s-eye view of the licensing and ratesetting systems for music. The charts are intended as
high-level references and do not capture every nuance or quirk of the system. A list of
abbreviations used in the report is included as Appendix C.
9
Act of May 31, 1790, ch. 15, 1 Stat. 124.
10
See Clayton v. Stone, 5 F. Cas. 999, 1000 (C.C.S.D.N.Y. 1829) (No. 2872); I. Trotter Hardy,
Copyright and New Use Technologies, 23 N
OVA L. REV. 659, 664 (1999).
11
Act of Feb. 3, 1831, ch. 16, 4 Stat. 436.
16
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The 1831 amendment, however, provided owners of musical works with only the
exclusive right to reproduce and distribute their compositions, i.e., to print and sell sheet
music, because, “[a]t the time, performances were considered the vehicle by which to
spur the sale of sheet music.”
12
In 1897, Congress expanded the rights of music owners
to include the exclusive right to publicly perform their works.
13
With the 1909 Copyright
Act, federal copyright protection for musical works was further extended by adding an
exclusive right to makemechanicalreproductions of songs in “phonorecords”in
those days, piano rolls, but in the modern era, vinyl records and CDs. At the same time,
Congress limited the new phonorecord right by enacting a compulsory license for this
use, a topic that is addressed in greater depth below.
14
And in 1995, Congress confirmed
that an owners exclusive right to reproduce and distribute phonorecords of musical
works extends to digital phonorecord deliveries (“DPDs”)—that is, the transmission of
digital files embodying musical works.
15
Over time, new technologies changed the way people consumed music, from buying
and playing sheet music, to enjoying player pianos, to listening to sound recordings on a
phonograph or stereo system.
16
But it was not until 1971, several decades after the
widespread introduction of phonorecords, that Congress recognized artists’ sound
recordings as a distinct class of copyrighted works that were themselves deserving of
federal copyright protection.
17
This federal protection, however, was limited to sound
recordings fixed on or after February 15, 1972, and, until more recently, protected only
the exclusive rights of reproduction, distribution, and preparation of derivative works.
No exclusive right of public performance was granted.
18
Then, in 1995, Congress
granted sound recording owners a limited public performance right for digital audio
12
See Maria A. Pallante, ASCAP at 100, 61 J. COPYRIGHT SOCY 545, 545-46 (2014).
13
Act of Mar. 3, 1897, ch. 392, 29 Stat. 694; see also Zvi S. Rosen, The Twilight of the Opera Pirates: A
Prehistory of the Exclusive Right of Public Performance for Musical Compositions, 24 C
ARDOZO ARTS &
ENT. L.J. 1157, 1158-59 (2007).
14
This report uses both the term “compulsory” and the term “statutory” when describing the
section 112, 114, and 115 licenses.
15
Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings Act of 1995 (“DPRSRA”), Pub. L. No. 104-39,
§ 4, 109 Stat. 336, 344-48; see also 17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(3)(A).
16
See U.S. COPYRIGHT OFFICE, FEDERAL COPYRIGHT PROTECTION FOR PRE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS
7, 11 (2011) (“PRE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT”); Michael Erlinger, Jr., An Analog Solution in a
Digital World: Providing Federal Copyright Protection for Pre-1972 Sound Recordings, 16 UCLA
ENT. L.
REV. 45, 57-58 (2009).
17
Pub. L. No. 92-140, 85 Stat. 391 (1971) (“Sound Recording Act of 1971”); see generally PRE-1972
SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT at 7-12.
18
See PRE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT at 12-14.
17
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
transmissionsthough, as discussed below, that right was made subject to compulsory
licensing under sections 112 and 114 of the Copyright Act.
19
2. Musical Works Versus Sound Recordings
As the above history indicates, a musical recording encompasses two distinct works of
authorship: the musical work, which is the underlying composition created by the
songwriter or composer along with any accompanying lyrics, and the sound recording,
which is the particular performance of the musical work that has been fixed in a
recording medium such as a CD or digital file. Because of this overlap, musical works
and sound recordings are frequently confused. It is important to keep in mind,
however, that these are separately copyrightable works.
A musical work can be in the form of sheet music, i.e., notes and lyrics written on a page,
or embodied in a phonorecord, i.e., in a recording of the song.
20
A sound recording
comprises the fixed sounds that make up the recording. The musical work and sound
recording are separately protected, and can be separately owned, under copyright law.
3. Key Players in the Music Marketplace
Musical works and sound recordings can beand often arecreated, owned, and
managed by different entities.
a. Songwriters
The authors of a musical work are composers, lyricists and/or songwriters.
21
A
songwriter may contribute music, lyrics, or both.
19
DPRSRA §§ 2, 3. In 1998, as part of the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (“DMCA”), Congress
extended the section 114 compulsory license to include webcasting and amended section 112 of
the Act to cover the server copies necessary for digital transmissions. Pub. L. No. 105-304, §§ 402,
405, 112 Stat. 2860, 2888-02 (1998). The digital performance right is also subject to a number of
exceptions, including for transmissions to or within a business for use in the ordinary course of
its business, for nonsubscription broadcast transmissions, and for certain geographically limited
retransmissions of nonsubscription broadcast transmissions. 17 U.S.C. § 114(d)(1)(A), (B), (C)(ii),
(C)(iv).
20
The Copyright Act sometimes draws a distinction between “dramatic” musical worksthat is,
musical works that are part of a dramatic show such as an opera, ballet, or musicaland
“nondramatic” musical works. For example, the compulsory license under section 115 for the
making and distributing of phonorecords applies only to nondramatic works. See 17 U.S.C.
§ 115. In practice, however, the distinction drawn in section 115 does not appear especially
consequential except when a licensee is seeking to use the work in the context of the dramatic
production; for instance, a show tune that is recorded for release as an individual song is
understood to be licensable under section 115.
21
For ease of reference, this report will collectively refer to these creators of musical works as
“songwriters.”
18
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The Songwriters Guild of America (“SGA”) and Nashville Songwriters Association
International (“NSAI”) are well-known trade organizations that represent the general
interests of songwriters. Another group, the Society of Composers and Lyricists
(“SCL”), represents the interests of songwriters working specifically in the motion
picture and television industries.
b. Music Publishers
Songwriters often enter into publishing agreements with music publishers. Under such
an arrangement, the publisher may pay an advance to the songwriter against future
royalty collections to help finance the songwriter’s writing efforts. In addition, the
publisher promotes and licenses the songwriter’s works and collects royalties on the
songwriter’s behalf. In exchange, the songwriter assigns a portion of the copyright in
the compositions he or she writes during the deal term to the publishertraditionally
50%, but sometimes less—and the publisher is compensated by receiving a royalty
share.
22
In some cases, a musical work has a single songwriter and a single publisher,
and dividing royalties is relatively straightforward. But many songs have multiple
songwriters, each with his or her own publisher and publishing deal. In such cases, it
may be challenging to determine royalty shares—or “splits”—among the various
parties.
23
The three majormusic publishersSony/ATV Music Publishing (“Sony/ATV”),
Warner/Chappell Music, and Universal Music Publishing Group (“UMPG”)together
control over 60% of the music publishing market.
24
There are also a handful of mid-
sized music publishers, such as Kobalt Music Group and BMG Chrysalis, and thousands
of smaller music publishers, among them self-published songwriters. The National
Music Publishers Association (“NMPA”) and the Association of Independent Music
Publishers (“AIMP”) are two major trade organizations representing the interests of
music publishers.
25
Another group, Interested Parties Advancing Copyright (“IPAC”),
was established in Nashville in 2014 and includes independent publishers,
administrators, business managers, and entertainment attorneys.
26
22
DONALD S. PASSMAN, ALL YOU NEED TO KNOW ABOUT THE MUSIC BUSINESS 220 (8th ed. 2013)
(“P
ASSMAN”).
23
See generally AL KOHN & BOB KOHN, KOHN ON MUSIC LICENSING 329-44 (4th ed. 2010)
(“K
OHN).
24
See Ed Christman, First-Quarter Music Publishing Rankings: SONGS Surges Again, BILLBOARD
(May 12, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/publishing/6084783/first-quarter-
music-publishing-rankings-songs-surges-again.
25
NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 1.
26
Nate Rau, New Nashville Group to Push for Copyright Reform, THE TENNESSEAN (May 25, 2014),
http://www.tennessean.com/story/money/industries/music/2014/05/25/nashville-copyright-
group-emerges/9513731.
19
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
c. Performing Rights Organizations (“PROs”)
Songwriters and publishers almost always associate themselves with a PRO, which is
responsible for licensing their public performance rights. The two largest PROs—the
American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers (“ASCAP”) and Broadcast
Music, Inc. (“BMI”)together represent more than 90% of the songs available for
licensing in the United States.
27
ASCAP and BMI operate on a not-for-profit basis and,
as discussed below, are subject to antitrust consent decrees that impose constraints on
their membership and licensing practices. In ASCAP’s case, this includes an express
prohibition on licensing any rights other than public performance rights.
In addition to these larger PROs, there are two considerably smaller, for-profit PROs
that license performance rights outside of direct government oversight. Nashville-based
SESAC, Inc. was founded in the 1930s.
28
SESAC’s market share of the performance
rights market is unclear, but appears to be at least 5% and possibly higher.
29
Global
Music Rights (“GMR”), a newcomer to the scene established in 2013, handles
performance rights licensing for a select group of songwriters.
30
While ASCAP and
BMI’s consent decrees prohibit them from excluding potential members who are able to
meet fairly minimal criteria,
31
SESAC and GMR have no such restriction and add new
members by invitation only.
32
27
See Ben Sisario, Pandora Suit May Upend Century-Old Royalty Plan, N.Y. TIMES (Feb. 13, 2014),
http://www.nytimes.com/2014/02/14/business/media/pandora-suit-may-upend-century-old-
royalty-plan.html.
28
About Us, SESAC, http://www.sesac.com/about/about.aspx (last visited Jan. 26, 2015).
29
See Chris Versace, The Future of Streaming Music Rests With Congress, FOX BUSINESS (June 23,
2014), http://www.foxbusiness.com/technology/2014/06/23/future-streaming-music-rests-with-
congress (SESAC “controls approximately 5% of the market”); In re Pandora Media, Inc. (“Pandora
Ratesetting”), 6 F. Supp. 3d 317, 351 & n.55 (S.D.N.Y. 2014) (noting that during license negotiations
SESAC had used a 10% figure to describe its market share, but that the actual figure “is
impossible to know with certainty”).
30
See GMR, http://www.globalmusicrights.com (last visited Jan. 30, 2015); see also Ed Christman,
Gail Mitchell, and Andrew Hampp, Pharrell to Leave ASCAP for Irving and Grimmet’s Global Music
Rights, B
ILLBOARD (July 25, 2014), www.billboard.com/articles/business/6188942/pharrell-to-
leave-ascap-for-irving-and-grimmets-global-music-rights; Ben Sisario, New Venture Seeks Higher
Royalties for Songwriters, N.Y.
TIMES (Oct. 29, 2014), http://www.nytimes.com/2014/10/30/
business/media/new-venture-seeks-higher-royalties-for-songwriters.html.
31
ASCAP must admit anyone who has published a single musical work or is actively engaged in
the music publishing business; BMI similarly accepts anyone who has written at least one
musical work that is likely to be “performed soon.” See United States v. ASCAP, No. 41-1395, 2001
WL 1589999, 2001-02 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 73,474, § XI (S.D.N.Y. June 11, 2001) (“ASCAP Consent
Decree”); United States v. BMI, No. 64-civ-3787, 1966 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 10449, 1966 Trade Cas.
(CCH) ¶ 71,941, § V (S.D.N.Y. 1966), as amended by, 1994 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 21476, 1996-1 Trade Cas.
20
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
d. Mechanical Rights Administrators
As examined in more depth below, the right to make and distribute phonorecords of
musical worksi.e., the mechanical right—is subject to compulsory licensing under
section 115 of the Act. But in practice, because of the administrative burdens imposed
by the licenseincluding service of a notice on the copyright owner and monthly
reporting of royalties on a song-by-song basis—mechanical licensing is often handled
via third-party administrators.
33
The oldest and largest such organization is the Harry
Fox Agency, Inc. (“HFA”), which was established by the NMPA in 1927 and today
represents over 48,000 publishers in licensing and collection activities.
34
Mechanical
licenses issued by HFA incorporate the terms of section 115, but with certain variations
from the statutory provisions.
35
Another entity that assists with mechanical licensing is
Music Reports, Inc. (“MRI”), which prepares and serves statutory notices on behalf of its
clients and administers monthly royalty payments in keeping with the requirements of
section 115.
36
Mechanical licenses are also issued and administered directly by music
publishers in many instances.
e. Recording Artists and Producers
The creators of sound recordings typically include recording artiststhat is, the singer
or members of the band who are featured in the recording. The recording process is
often managed by a producer, who supervises and contributes overall artistic vision to
the project. Othernonfeatured” musicians and vocalists may add their talents to the
recording as well. Except with respect to digital performance rights falling under the
section 114 statutory license,
37
featured artists are typically paid under their record
company contracts, while nonfeatured performers are usually compensated at an hourly
(CCH) ¶ 71,378 (S.D.N.Y. 1994). The most readable version of the current BMI consent decree is
the version provided on the Department of Justice’s (“DOJ’s”) website, and is the version cited
throughout this report. See United States v. BMI, No. 64-civ-3787 (S.D.N.Y. Nov. 18, 1994) (final
judgment) (“BMI Consent Decree”), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/
f307400/307413.pdf.
32
Radio Music License Comm., Inc. v. SESAC, 29 F. Supp. 3d 487, 498 (E.D. Pa. 2014); Pandora
Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 351; GMR, http://www.globalmusicrights.com (last visited Jan. 30,
2015).
33
KOHN at 771-72, 808-10.
34
HARRY FOX AGENCY, http://www.harryfox.com (last visited Jan. 9, 2015).
35
KOHN at 803-806. For example, HFA licenses allow licensees to account for royalties on a
quarterly basis, as opposed to the monthly reporting required under section 115. Become an HFA
Licensee, H
ARRY FOX AGENCY, http://www.harryfox.com/license_music/become_hfa_
licensee.html (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
36
See MRI First Notice Comments at 1-3.
37
See 17 U.S.C. § 114(g) (dividing statutory royalty proceeds among these groups).
21
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
rate based on their work on specific projects.
38
Producers may be paid a flat fee for their
efforts and/or may be paid a royalty share by the featured artist out of the artist’s
earnings.
39
The organization SoundExchange collects and pays royalties owed to featured and
nonfeatured artists (as well as to record companies) for noninteractive streaming uses
under the section 112 and 114 statutory licenses, and advocates for their interests in
relation to those uses.
40
The Recording Academy, also known as the National Academy
of Recording Arts and Sciences (“NARAS”)the organization responsible for the
GRAMMY awardsrepresents musicians, producers, recording engineers, and other
recording professionals on a wide range of industry matters.
41
The Future of Music
Coalition (“FMC”) advocates on behalf of individual music creators.
42
The American
Federation of Musicians of the United States and Canada (“AFM”) and Screen Actors
Guild-American Federation of Television and Radio Artists (“SAG-AFTRA”) are labor
unions that represent the interests of nonfeatured musicians and vocalists.
43
f. Record Companies
Most commercially successful sound recordings are the product of contractual
relationships between recording artists and record labels.
44
Though levels of
responsibility vary according to the specifics of individual recording contracts, a record
label’s usual role is to finance the production of sound recordings, promote the
recordings (and sometimes the recording artists themselves), and arrange to distribute
the recordings via physical and digital distribution channels.
45
Except in the case of
noninteractive streaming uses that qualify for the section 112 and 114 licenses, record
labels typically handle the licensing for the sound recordings they own.
38
See Sound Recordings at a Glance, SAG-AFTRA, http://www.sagaftra.org/files/sag/
documents/soundrecordings_ataglance_2014.pdf (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
39
See Dan Daley, Points of Survival: Producers Adapt to a New Economic Landscape in the Music
Industry, G
RAMMY.COM (Sept. 1, 2010), http://www.grammy.com/news/points-of-survival;
NARAS First Notice Comments at 5-6.
40
Unlike royalties paid under section 114, royalties under the 112 license are not distributed
directly to featured and nonfeatured artists, but instead are paid to the sound recording owner.
See 17 U.S.C. § 114(g)(2); see also 17 U.S.C. § 112(e).
41
NARAS First Notice Comments at 1.
42
About Us, FUTURE OF MUSIC COALITION, https://www.futureofmusic.org/about (last visited Jan.
25, 2015).
43
SAG-AFTRA & AFM First Notice Comments at 1-2.
44
KOHN at 1454.
45
PASSMAN at 63. Labels also secure mechanical rights to musical works embodied in sound
recordings.
22
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
In modern industry parlance, there are two classes of record labels: “majorlabels and
independentlabels.
46
There are currently three major record labels: Universal Music
Group (“UMG”), Sony Music Entertainment, Inc. (“SME”), and Warner Music Group
(“WMG”).
47
Independent labels are entities that are not wholly owned by one of the
three major record labels. In the United States, there are currently hundreds of
independent labels, which account for roughly 35% of domestic recording industry
revenues.
48
One notable feature of the modern music marketplace is the extent of common corporate
ownership of major record labels and major music publishers: UMPG is owned by
UMG (which in turn is owned by French media conglomerate Vivendi); the Sony
Corporation owns SME and half of Sony/ATV; and Warner/Chappell Music is a division
of WMG.
49
The Recording Industry Association of America (“RIAA”) and the American Association
of Independent Music (“A2IM”) are the two primary trade organizations representing
the interests of record labels. The International Federation of the Phonographic Industry
(“IFPI”) represents record labels globally.
50
As noted above, SoundExchangeoriginally
a division of the RIAA and later spun off as an independent entity
51
—represents the
interests of the record labels in relation to the section 112 and 114 licenses.
g. Music Providers
There are a number of organizations that represent the interests of the thousands of
music broadcasters and distributors—including radio and television stations, digital
music companies, and physical and online record stores.
46
A2IM, the U.S. trade association that represents the interests of independent record labels,
objects to the term “major label.” According to A2IM, independent labels, collectively, represent
34.6% of the U.S. music market, making them “the largest music label industry segment.” A2IM
First Notice Comments at 1, 3.
47
The three major labels all own and operate smaller labels. For example, Atlantic Records and
Rhino Entertainment Company are both owned by WMG.
48
A2IM First Notice Comments at 1, 3.
49
Sebastian Torrelio, Jody Gerson Appointed Chairman and CEO of Universal Music Publishing Group,
V
ARIETY (Aug. 1, 2014), http://variety.com/2014/biz/news/jody-gerson-appointed-chairman-and-
ceo-of-universal-music-publishing-group-1201273829; Profile: Sony Corp, R
EUTERS, http://www.
reuters.com/finance/stocks/companyProfile?symbol=SNE.N (last visited Jan. 25, 2015); About Us,
W
ARNER/CHAPPELL MUSIC, http://www.warnerchappell.com/about (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
50
IFPI, http://www.ifpi.org (last visited Jan. 15, 2015).
51
Glenn Peoples, SoundExchange Distributes Record $153 Million in Q3, Celebrates 10-Year
Anniversary, B
ILLBOARD (Oct. 4, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/5748060/
soundexchange-distributes-record-153-million-in-q3-celebrates-10-year.
23
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The National Association of Broadcasters (“NAB”) is the main trade organization
representing terrestrial (AM/FM) radio and television broadcasters.
52
Broadcasters have
also established a number of “music license committees” that collectively negotiate
licensing arrangements with the PROs. These include the Radio Music License
Committee (“RMLC”),
53
the Television Music License Committee (“TMLC”),
54
the
National Religious Broadcasters Music License Committee (“NRBMLC”) and the
National Religious Broadcasters Noncommercial Music License Committee
(“NRBNMLC”).
55
National Public Radio (“NPR”) operates and advocates on behalf of
public radio stations.
The Digital Media Association (“DiMA”) is a national trade organization that advocates
for digital music and media companies, such as Pandora, Rhapsody, Apple, and
YouTube.
56
CTIAThe Wireless Association (“CTIA”)
57
represents the wireless communications
industry, and the Computer and Communications Industry Association (“CCIA”)
represents a broad range of technology companies.
58
Music Business Association (“Music Biz”), formerly the National Association of
Recording Merchandisers, includes many physical and digital distributors of music in its
membership.
59
h. Consumers
Last but not least, there are music fans. As digital technologies continue to evolve,
individual users interact with music more and more in ways that implicate copyright
they copy it, share it, and remix it with other content.
52
NAB First Notice Comments at 1.
53
RMLC First Notice Comments at 1.
54
TMLC First Notice Comments at 1.
55
NRBMLC First Notice Comments at 2-3; NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 1-2. The
National Cable & Telecommunications Association (“NCTA”), which represents cable operators,
has its own music license committee to negotiate PRO licenses for public performances of music
in cable operators’ local programming. See NCTA, Comments Submitted in Response to the
DOJ’s Antitrust Consent Decree Review at 1 (Aug. 6, 2014), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/
cases/ascapbmi/comments/307982.pdf.
56
DiMA First Notice Comments at 1.
57
CTIA First Notice Comments at 2-4.
58
CCIA Second Notice Comments at 1.
59
About, MUSIC BUSINESS ASSOCIATION, http://musicbiz.org/about (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
24
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
A number of groups represent the interests of music consumers in policy matters,
including Public Knowledge and the Consumer Federation of America (“CFA”).
60
B. Licensing Musical Works
1. Exclusive Rights in Musical Works
The owner of a musical work possesses exclusive rights under the Copyright Act,
including the right to authorize others to exploit these exclusive rights: the right to
make and distribute copies (e.g., sheet music) or phonorecords (e.g., CDs and digital
audio files) of the work (the so-called “mechanical” right);
61
the right to create derivative
works (e.g., a new work based on an existing composition);
62
the right to display the
work publicly (e.g., by posting lyrics on a website);
63
and the right to perform the work
publicly (e.g., in a live venue or broadcast).
64
Although it is not specified in section 106
of the Act, as a matter of business practice, the music industry also recognizes the right
to synchronize musical works to visual content (e.g., in a music video). The
synchronization (or “synch” right) is a species of the reproduction right and may also
implicate the derivative work right.
65
The music industry relies on different entities to license and administer rights in musical
works, principally because of a variety of legal restrictions and industry practices that
have grown up over time. This balkanized licensing scheme was not overly problematic
during the analog age, when determining the boundaries between rights was relatively
straightforward. In pre-digital days, radio and record distributors represented distinct
commercial channels with different licensing needs. Today, however, digital providers
often merge these roles. As a result, the demarcations between traditional licensing
categories are no longer as clearespecially with respect to the relation between
reproduction and distribution rights, on the one hand, and public performance, on the
other. The current complexity of the music licensing marketplace is attributable at least
in part to the blurring of the traditional lines of exploitation.
60
CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at 1; About Us, PUBLIC KNOWLEDGE,
https://www.publicknowledge.org/about-us (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
61
17 U.S.C. § 106(1), (3).
62
Id. § 106(2).
63
Id. § 106(5).
64
Id. § 106(4).
65
See Buffalo Broad. Co., Inc., v. ASCAP, 744 F.2d 917, 920 (2d Cir. 1984) (“The ‘synch’ right is a
form of the reproduction right also created by statute as one of the exclusive rights enjoyed by the
copyright owner.” (citing 17 U.S.C. § 106(1))); Agee v. Paramount Commc’ns, Inc., 59 F.3d 317, 321
(2d Cir. 1995) (observing that a defendant “might have infringed [plaintiff’s] exclusive right to
prepare derivative works” by synchronizing music to an audiovisual work, but the court “need
not resolve that question” as copying (and a defense to this right) were already proven).
25
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
2. Reproduction and Distribution Rights
a. Historical Background
Until the early twentieth century, owners of musical works were compensated primarily
through the reproduction and distribution of sheet music. Sales of sheet music were a
significant source of revenue for music publishers for a long time.
66
And prices for sheet
music were, as they are today, set in the free market.
67
By the early 1900s, however, technological advances made music available for the first
time via “mechanical” renderings of songs captured in player piano rolls and
phonograph records.
68
Although music publishers insisted that physical embodiments
of their works were copies, the Supreme Court held otherwise in the 1908 case White-
Smith Music Publishing v. Apollo, reasoning that such reproductions were not in a form
that human beings could “see and read.”
69
With the enactment of the 1909 Copyright Act, however, Congress overrode the Court’s
decision and recognized copyright owners’ exclusive right to make and distribute, and
authorize the making and distribution, of phonorecordsi.e., mechanical
reproductionsof musical works.
70
At the same time, Congress was concerned about a
lack of competition in the marketplace—in particular, it was alleged that the Aeolian
Company, a manufacturer of player pianos, was seeking to buy up exclusive rights from
publishers to create a monopoly in piano rolls.
71
To address that concern, Congress
simultaneously created a compulsory license for mechanical reproductions of musical
works—the first compulsory license in U.S. copyright law—establishing a statutory rate
of 2 cents per copy.
72
66
See KOHN at 674. By 1919, a single department store chainWoolworth’swas selling over 200
million copies of sheet music annually. Id. at 6.
67
Sheet music was generally sold for 10 cents per copy. Id. at 6.
68
Id. at 6-7.
69
White-Smith Music Publ’g Co. v. Apollo Co., 209 U.S. 1, 8-9, 17-18 (1908).
70
H.R. REP. NO. 60-2222, at 6-8 (1909); see also Miller v. Goody, 139 F. Supp. 176, 182 (S.D.N.Y. 1956).
71
H.R. REP. NO. 59-7083, pt. 2, at 5 (1907); RUSSELL SANJEK UPDATED BY DAVID SANJEK, PENNIES
FROM HEAVEN 22-23 (1996).
72
H.R. REP. NO. 60-2222, at 7-8; Copyright Act of 1909, Pub. L. No. 60-349, §1(e), 35 Stat. 1075,
1075-76. Adjusted for inflation, the 2 cent rate would be more than 50 cents today. Music
Licensing Hearings (statement of David M. Israelite, President and Chief Executive Officer,
NMPA).
26
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Though it has been amended several times, the 1909 compulsory license, originally set
forth in section 1(e) of the Act,
73
continues in force today. In the Copyright Act of 1976,
Congress recodified the compulsory license in section 115, and raised the statutory rate
to 2.75 cents.
74
At that time, Congress also created the Copyright Royalty Tribunal
(“CRT”)—with five commissioners appointed by the President—to adjust the royalty
rate thereafter.
75
The CRT was replaced in 1993 by the Copyright Arbitration Royalty
Panel (“CARP”) system; rather than permanent appointees, the CARP arbitrators were
convened for specific rate proceedings.
76
The CARP system, in turn, was replaced in
2005 by the current system, the Copyright Royalty Board (“CRB”), which is composed of
three administrative judges appointed by the Librarian of Congress.
77
In 1995, Congress enacted the Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings Act of
1995 (“DPRSRA”), which, in addition to granting a digital performance right for sound
recordings, amended section 115 to expressly cover the reproduction and distribution of
musical works by digital transmission, or DPDs.
78
The 1995 legislation recognized what
73
Copyright Act of 1909 § 1(e).
74
H.R. REP. NO. 94-1476, at 111 (1976), reprinted in 1976 U.S.C.C.A.N. 5659, 5726. Notably, the
Register of Copyrights had proposed elimination of the compulsory license in the process leading
up to the adoption of the 1976 Copyright Act, but music publishers and composers ultimately
chose to oppose such a change, opting instead for the three-quarter cent rate increase. See U.S.
COPYRIGHT OFFICE, 88TH CONG., REP. OF THE REGISTER OF COPYRIGHTS ON THE GENERAL REVISION
OF THE
U.S. COPYRIGHT LAW 33, 36 (Comm. Print 1961) (“GENERAL REVISION OF COPYRIGHT
REPORT); S. REP. NO. 94-473, at 91-92 (1975); see also Music Licensing Reform: Hearing Before the
Subcomm. on Intell. Prop. of the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 109th Cong. (2005) (“Music Licensing
Reform Hearing”) (statement of Marybeth Peters, Register of Copyrights), available at
http://copyright.gov/docs/regstat071205.html (stating that publishers and songwriters were
concerned that elimination of the statutory license would cause “unnecessary disruptions in the
music industry”).
75
Copyright Act of 1976, Pub. L. No. 94-553, §§ 801-802, 90 Stat. 2541, 2594-96.
76
Copyright Royalty Tribunal Reform Act of 1993, Pub. No. 103-198, § 802, 107 Stat. 2304, 2305
(1993).
77
17 U.S.C. §§ 801-805; Copyright Royalty and Distribution Reform Act of 2004, Pub. L. No. 108-
419, 118 Stat. 2341. The statute calls the ratesetting body the “Copyright Royalty Judges.” See 17
U.S.C. § 801. But it is more commonly referred to as the “Copyright Royalty Board,” including in
the regulations, and this report uses that convention. See 37 C.F.R. § 301.1 (“The Copyright
Royalty Board is the institutional entity in the Library of Congress that will house the Copyright
Royalty Judges . . . .”).
78
See S. REP. NO. 104-128, at 10 (1995), reprinted in 1995 U.S.C.C.A.N. 356, 357 (“The purpose of
[this Act] is to ensure that performing artists, record companies and others whose livelihood
depends upon effective copyright protection for sound recordings, will be protected as new
technologies affect the ways in which their creative works are used. . . . In addition, the bill
clarifies the application of the existing reproduction and distribution rights of musical work and
27
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
is often referred to as “pass-through” licensing for DPDs, in that it allows a section 115
licensee, such as a record label, to authorize a third-party service to distribute DPDs of
the works covered under its license.
79
Significantly, the express recognition of digital transmissions of musical works as a right
covered by section 115 led to a lengthy rulemaking proceeding commenced by the
Copyright Office in 2001 to determine the scope and application of the section 115
compulsory license with respect to various uses, which included the question of whether
interactive streaming services were required to procure mechanical licenses in addition
to performance licenses.
80
In 2008, recognizing that streaming services make and rely
upon server copies and other reproductions of musical works in order to operate, the
Office concluded that streaming services could utilize the section 115 compulsory
licensing process to cover the reproductions made to facilitate streaming.
81
In 2009, the
CRB adopted the first rates and terms under section 115 for interactive streaming
services.
82
As a result of these developments, on-demand streaming services seek both
mechanical and PRO licenses for the musical works they use.
b. Mechanical Rights Licensing
Statutory Licensing
Under section 115, those who seek to make and distribute reproductions of a musical
work may obtain a license to do so by serving a notice of intent (“NOI) on the
copyright owner, no later than thirty days after making, and before distributing, any
phonorecords.
83
Once a person has served the NOI, the person must provide statements
of account and pay the statutorily prescribed royalties on a monthly basis.
84
If the name
and address of the owner of the work cannot be identified from the public records of the
sound recording copyright owners in the context of certain digital transmissions.”); see also 17
U.S.C. § 115(c)(3)(A).
79
17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(3)(A).
80
Compulsory License for Making and Distributing Phonorecords, Including Digital
Phonorecord Deliveries, 73 Fed. Reg. 40,802, 40,804-05 (July 18, 2008).
81
Compulsory License for Making and Distributing Phonorecords, Including Digital
Phonorecord Deliveries, 73 Fed. Reg. 66,173, 66,174 (Nov. 7, 2008) (“The interim regulation
clarifies that (1) whenever there is a transmission that results in a DPD, all reproductions made
for the purpose of making the DPD are also included as part of the DPD, and (2) limited
downloads qualify as DPDs.”).
82
Mechanical and Digital Phonorecord Delivery Rate Determination Proceeding, 74 Fed. Reg.
4510, 4514-15 (Jan. 26, 2009); 37 C.F.R. §§ 385.1-385.5, 385.10-385.17.
83
17 U.S.C. § 115(b)(1).
84
17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(5).
28
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Copyright Office, the user may file the NOI with the Office.
85
In that case, the user must
pay a filing fee to the Office but does not need to deposit royalties.
86
The compulsory license under section 115 is available only after a recording has been
made and distributed to the public under the authority of the copyright owner.
87
Consequently, the initial recording of a musical work, or “first use,” does not fall under
the compulsory license, and the copyright owner has the authority to determine whether
and how the work is first reproduced and distributed. Once a work is eligible for
statutory licensing, section 115 limits the way the work can be exploited. A section 115
license includes the right to make a musical arrangement of the song but does not permit
the user to change the basic melody or fundamental character of the work.
88
As noted above, the CRB is the administrative body responsible for establishing
statutory rates and terms under the section 115 license, a process that by statute takes
place every five years.
89
While copyright owners and users are free to negotiate
voluntary licenses that depart from the statutory rates and terms, in practical effect the
CRB-set rate acts as a ceiling for what the owner may charge. Rates for the license are
established under a standard set forth in section 801(b)(1) of the Copyright Act, which
requires the CRB to weigh several policy-oriented objectives:
(A) To maximize the availability of creative works to the public.
(B) To afford the copyright owner a fair return for his creative work and
the copyright user a fair income under existing economic conditions.
(C) To reflect the relative roles of the copyright owner and the copyright
user in the product made available to the public with respect to
relative creative contribution, technological contribution, capital
investment, cost, risk, and contribution to the opening of new markets
for creative expression and media for their communication.
(D) To minimize any disruptive impact on the structure of the industries
involved and on generally prevailing industry practices.
90
The rates currently applicable under section 115 were the result of an industry-wide
negotiated agreement that was submitted to the CRB as a settlement of the most recent
85
17 U.S.C. § 115(b)(1).
86
See 17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(1); 37 C.F.R. § 201.18(f)(3).
87
KOHN at 792-93; see 17 U.S.C. § 115(a)(1).
88
17 U.S.C. § 115(a)(2).
89
KOHN at 742; 17 U.S.C. § 804(b)(4).
90
17 U.S.C. § 801(b)(1).
29
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
ratesetting proceeding.
91
The current rate to make and distribute permanent downloads
or physical phonorecords of a musical work is 9.1 cents per copy.
92
For ringtones, the
rate is 24 cents per use.
93
The royalty rate to make reproductions of musical works in
connection with interactive streaming, limited download services, and certain other
services is a percentage of the service’s revenue ranging from 10.5% to 12%, subject to
certain minimum royalty floors, and after deducting royalties paid by the service for the
public performance of those works.
94
It may seem counterintuitive that ringtones—which typically use only short excerpts of
musical workshave a significantly higher royalty rate than full-length reproductions.
Because ringtones abbreviate the full-length work, it was not immediately clear whether
ringtones were eligible for the section 115 license. As a result, many ringtone sellers
entered into privately negotiated licensing arrangements with publishers at rates well
above the statutory rate for the full use of the song.
95
In 2006, the Copyright Office
resolved the section 115 issue, opining that ringtones were subject to compulsory
licensing.
96
But in the ensuing ratesetting proceeding before the CRB, music publishers
were able to introduce the previously negotiated agreements as marketplace
benchmarks, and as a result secured a much higher rate for ringtones than the rate for
full songs.
97
Voluntary Licenses
Section 115 provides that a license that is voluntarily negotiated between a copyright
owner and user will be given effect in lieu of the rates and terms set by the CRB.
98
Although the use of the section 115 statutory license has increased in recent years with
the advent of digital providers seeking to clear large quantities of licenses, mechanical
licensing is still largely accomplished through voluntary licenses that are issued through
91
Adjustment of Determination of Compulsory License Rates for Mechanical and Digital
Phonorecords, 78 Fed. Reg. 67,938, 67,939 (Nov. 12, 2013).
92
For songs over five minutes, the rate is higher1.75 cents per minute or fraction thereof. 37
C.F.R. § 385.3(a).
93
37 C.F.R. § 385.3(b).
94
37 C.F.R. §§ 385.12-385.14, 385.23.
95
Mechanical and Digital Phonorecord Delivery Rate Adjustment Proceeding, 71 Fed. Reg. 64,303,
64,308-09 (Nov. 1, 2006) (discussing “voluntary license agreements granting the labels the right to
create ringtones at specified mutually-negotiated royalty rates”).
96
Id. at 64,303.
97
Mechanical and Digital Phonorecord Delivery Rate Determination Proceeding, 74 Fed. Reg. at
4517-18; id. at 4522 (explaining that those licenses constitute “valuable rate evidence from the
marketplace for” ringtones but not for “other products at issue in this proceeding (i.e., CDs and
permanent downloads)”).
98
17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(3)(E)(i).
30
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
a mechanical licensing agency such as HFA or by the publisher directly.
99
While HFA
and other licensors typically incorporate the key elements of section 115 into their direct
licenses, they may also vary those terms to some degree, such as by permitting quarterly
accountings rather than the monthly statements required under the statute.
100
That said,
as observed above, the terms of the statutory license act as a ghost in the attic, effectively
establishing the maximum amount a copyright owner can seek under a negotiated
mechanical license.
101
Recent Reform Efforts
The last significant legislative effort to modernize mechanical licensing took place nearly
a decade ago. In 2006, Representatives Lamar Smith and Howard Berman introduced
the Section 115 Reform Act (“SIRA”).
102
SIRA would have created a blanket mechanical
license for digital services, while leaving the remainder of section 115 intact for physical
reproductions (and also not affecting performance rights).
SIRA included several notable features.
103
It would have established a “general
designated agent” with the possibility of additional designated agents, provided they
represented at least 15% of the music publishing market. Copyright owners would elect
to be represented by a designated agent, with the general designated agent representing
any copyright owners that failed to make such an election. Each designated agent
would have been required to maintain a searchable electronic database of musical works
represented by that agent. The cost of establishing such databases would have been
shared by designated agents and licensees, with cost-sharing amounts determined by
the CRB. The CRB would also have established rates and terms for the license itself, and
there would have been an interim ratesetting mechanism for new types of services.
There were also provisions addressing distribution of unclaimed funds and audit rights.
SIRA enjoyed support from key industry participants, including NMPA, DiMA, SGA,
and the PROs.
104
Although the bill was forwarded to the full Judiciary Committee, due
to opposition from other parties, it was not reported out.
105
99
W. Jonathan Cardi, Über-Middleman: Reshaping the Broken Landscape of Music Copyright, 92 IOWA
L. REV. 835, 841-42 (2007).
100
KOHN at 771.
101
Id. at 771-72.
102
SIRA, H.R. 5553, 109th Cong. (2006). SIRA was later incorporated into the Copyright
Modernization Act of 2006, H.R. 6052, 109th Cong. (2006).
103
See generally Copyright Modernization Act of 2006, H.R. 6052; Skyla Mitchell, Reforming Section
115: Escape from the Byzantine World of Mechanical Licensing, 24 C
ARDOZO ARTS & ENT. L.J. 1239,
1271 (2007).
104
Mitchell, Reforming Section 115: Escape from the Byzantine World of Mechanical Licensing at 1277.
Groups such as Public Knowledge and the Electronic Frontier Foundation opposed SIRA because
31
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
SIRA followed—and was perhaps an industry response to—an earlier 2005 proposal
from the Copyright Office. Then-Register of Copyrights Marybeth Peters testified before
Congress to propose a “21st Century Music Reform Act.”
106
Among other things, that
proposal would have effectively repealed the section 115 statutory license, and would
have authorized the establishment of “music rights organizations” (“MROs”) that could
license both performance and mechanical rights on a blanket basis. The proposal also
conditioned an MRO’s recovery of statutory damages on the MRO having made publicly
available the list of works it was authorized to license. While industry participants
agreed in principle with the basic goals of the Copyright Office’s proposal, they
expressed concerns about many of its specifics, including the lack of a limit on the
number of MROs, antitrust issues, and administrative burdens.
107
3. Public Performance Rights
a. The PROs
As mentioned above, although musical compositions were expressly made subject to
copyright protection starting in 1831, Congress did not grant music creators the
exclusive right to publicly perform their compositions until 1897.
108
Though this right
represented a new way for copyright owners to derive profit from their musical works,
the sheer number and fleeting nature of public performances made it impossible for
copyright owners to individually negotiate with each user for every use, or detect every
case of infringement.
109
ASCAP was established in 1914, followed by other PROs, to
of its provisions regarding temporary copies and recognition that interactive streaming involves
the making of DPDs. Id. at 1277-81.
105
See Reforming Section 115 of the Copyright Act for the Digital Age: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on
Courts, the Internet, and Intell. Prop. of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 110th Cong. 4 (2007)
(“Reforming Section 115 Hearing”) (statement of Rep. Howard Coble).
106
See generally Copyright Office Views on Music Licensing Reform: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on
Courts, the Internet, and Intell. Prop. of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 109th Cong. 21-36 (2005)
(“Copyright Office Views on Music Licensing Reform Hearing”) (statement of Marybeth Peters,
Register of Copyrights).
107
Id. at 56-57 (letter from Jonathan Potter, Executive Director, DiMA); id. at 59-60 (letter from
Steven M. Marks, RIAA); id. at 99 (comments of ASCAP); id. at 62-64 (comments of NMPA).
108
See Steve Wilf, The Making of the Post-War Paradigm in American Intellectual Property Law, 31
C
OLUM. J.L. & ARTS 139, 176 (2008); Noel L. Hillman, Intractable Consent: A Legislative Solution to
the Problem of Aging Consent Decrees in United States v. ASCAP and United States v. BMI, 8 F
ORDHAM
INTELL. PROP. MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 733, 737 (1998).
109
BMI v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1, 4-5 (1979); see also Alden-Rochelle, Inc. v. ASCAP, 80 F. Supp. 888, 891
(S.D.N.Y. 1948).
32
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
address the logistical issue of how to license and collect payment for the public
performance of musical works in a wide range of settings.
110
Today, the PROs provide various different types of licenses depending upon the nature
of the use. Anyone who publicly performs a musical work may obtain a license from a
PRO, including terrestrial, satellite and internet radio stations, broadcast and cable
television stations, online services, bars, restaurants, live performance venues, and
commercial establishments that play background music.
Most commonly, licensees obtain a blanket license, which allows the licensee to publicly
perform any of the musical works in a PRO’s repertoire for a flat fee or a percentage of
total revenues.
111
Some users opt for a blanket license due to its broad coverage of
musical works and relative simplicity as compared to other types of licenses. Large
commercial establishments such as bars, restaurants, concert venues, stores, and hotels
often enter into blanket licenses to cover their uses, paying either a percentage of gross
revenues or an annual flat fee, depending on the establishment and the type and amount
of use.
112
Terrestrial radio stations obtain blanket licenses from PROs as well, usually by
means of the RMLC.
113
Many television stations, through the TMLC, also obtain blanket
licenses.
114
Less commonly used licenses include the per-program or per-segment license, which
allows the licensee to publicly perform any of the musical works in the PRO’s repertoire
for specified programs or parts of their programming, in exchange for a flat fee or a
percentage of that program’s advertising revenue.
115
Unlike a blanket license, the per-
program or per-segment license requires more detailed reporting information, including
program titles, the specific music selections used, and usage dates, making the license
more burdensome for the licensee to administer.
116
Users can also license music directly from music publishers through a direct license or a
source license. A direct license is simply a license agreement directly negotiated
110
BMI v. CBS, 441 U.S. at 4-5; see also Alden-Rochelle, 80 F. Supp. at 891.
111
Meredith Corp., 1 F. Supp. 3d at 190; BMI v. CBS, 441 U.S. at 5.
112
See KOHN at 1263, 1275-80. The Copyright Act exempts many small commercial establishments
from the need to obtain a public performance license. See 17 U.S.C. § 110(5).
113
David Oxenford, What is the RMLC, And Why Should a Radio Station Pay Their Bill?, BROAD. L.
BLOG (Aug. 24, 2012), http://www.broadcastlawblog.com/2012/08/articles/what-is-the-rmlc-and-
why-should-a-radio-station-pay-their-bill.
114
Meredith Corp., 1 F. Supp. 3d at 189-90.
115
See generally Lauren M. Bilasz, Note: Copyrights, Campaigns, and the Collective Administration of
Performance Rights: A Call to End Blanket Licensing of Political Events, 32 C
ARDOZO L.REV. 305, 323 &
nn.111-112 (2010) (descriptions of each license).
116
See, e.g., KOHN at 1266 (discussing per-program licenses).
33
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
between the copyright owner and the user who intends to publicly perform the musical
work. Source licenses are commonly used in the motion picture industry, because the
PROs are prohibited from licensing public performance rights directly to movie theater
owners.
117
Instead, film producers license public performance rights for the music used
in films at the same time as the synchronization rights, and pass the performance rights
along to the theaters that will be showing their films.
118
In the context of motion
pictures, source licenses do not typically encompass non-theatrical performances, such
as on television. Thus, television stations, cable companies, and online services such as
Netflix and Hulu must obtain public performance licenses from the PROs to cover the
public performance of musical works in the shows and movies they transmit to end
users.
119
b. Antitrust Oversight
Basic Antitrust Principles
Unlike the mechanical right, the public performance of musical works is not subject to
compulsory licensing under the Copyright Act. But, as described below, ASCAP and
BMI are subject to government antitrust regulation through longstanding consent
decrees. And while neither SESAC nor GMR is subject to such direct antitrust
regulation, each, of course, must abide by generally applicable antitrust law, which is
enforceable by the government or through private causes of action. SESAC, for example,
has recently been the subject of private antitrust suits, as discussed below. A detailed
explanation of the antitrust rationale that underlies the PRO consent decrees is beyond
the scope of this study. But a brief discussion of some basic antitrust principles may be
helpful in understanding the motivation behind the decrees.
Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act prohibits “[e]very contract, combination in the
form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the
several [s]tates.”
120
As the Supreme Court has opined, however, “Congress could not
have intended a literal interpretation of the word ‘every,’” and as a result, courts
117
This prohibition was a result of antitrust litigation brought by movie theater owners in the
1940s. Alden-Rochelle, 80 F. Supp. 888; see also Christian Seyfert, Copyright and Anti-Trust Law:
Public Performance Rights Licensing of Musical Works into Audiovisual Media 19 (Sept. 1, 2005)
(unpublished LL.M. thesis, Golden Gate University School of Law) (“Seyfert”), available at http://
digitalcommons.law.ggu.edu/theses/13.
118
See Seyfert at 19.
119
Id.; see also Netflix First Notice Comments at 1-2; ASCAP Reports Increased Revenues in 2011,
ASCAP (Mar. 8, 2012), http://www.ascap.com/press/2012/0308_ascap-reports.aspx (reflecting
blanket licenses with Netflix and Hulu). Licensing of performance rights from SESAC and GMR
occurs without direct antitrust oversight, and those smaller PROs may refuse to license their
repertoires to potential licensees.
120
15 U.S.C. § 1.
34
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
“analyze[] most restraints under the so-called ‘rule of reason.’
121
The rule of reason test
requires a court to not only find a restraint of trade, but also determine whether that
restraint is unreasonable.
122
The Supreme Court has also recognized, however, that
“[o]nce experience with a particular kind of restraint enables the Court to predict with
confidence that the rule of reason will condemn it, it has applied a conclusive
presumption that the restraint is unreasonable.”
123
Thus, certain arrangements—
including price-fixing agreementsare deemed per se violations of section 1.
124
A “tying” arrangement is another kind of business practice that raises antitrust concerns.
A tying arrangement is “an agreement by a party to sell one product but only on the
condition that the buyer also purchases a different (or tied) product.”
125
Such
arrangements are unlawful “if the seller has ‘appreciable economic power’ in the tying
product market and if the arrangement affects a substantial volume of commerce in the
tied market.”
126
But as the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) observes, “[t]he law on
tying is changing.”
127
While the Supreme Court “has treated some tie-ins as per se
illegal in the past, lower courts have started to apply the more flexible ‘rule of reason’ to
assess the competitive effects of tied sales.”
128
Department of Justice Consent Decrees
Since 1941, ASCAP and BMI’s licensing practices have been subject to antitrust consent
decrees overseen by the Antitrust Division of the DOJ and enforced by federal district
courts in New York City.
129
Those consent decrees were implemented in reaction to
alleged anticompetitive practices of ASCAP and BMI. Specifically, when originally
formed, both PROs acquired the exclusive right to negotiate members’ public
performance rights, and forbade their members from entering into direct licensing
121
Arizona v. Maricopa Cnty. Med. Soc’y, 457 U.S. 332, 342-43 (1982).
122
Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1, 27 (1945).
123
Arizona, 457 U.S. at 343-44.
124
Id. at 344-45.
125
N. Pac Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958).
126
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 462 (1992).
127
Tying the Sale of Two Products, FTC, http://www.ftc.gov/tips-advice/competition-guidance/
guide-antitrust-laws/single-firm-conduct/tying-sale-two-products (last visited Jan. 26, 2015).
128
Id.
129
See generally United States v. BMI, 275 F.3d 168, 171-72 (2d Cir. 2001) (describing the history); see
also Antitrust Consent Decree Review, U.S.
DOJ, http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/ascap-bmi-decree-
review.html (last visited Jan. 26, 2015).
35
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
arrangements. Additionally, both offered only blanket licenses covering all of the music
in their respective repertoires.
130
In the 1930s, the DOJ’s Antitrust Division investigated ASCAP for anticompetitive
conduct—specifically that ASCAP’s licensing arrangements constituted price-fixing
and/or unlawful tying.
131
The government subsequently filed federal court actions in
1934 and 1941, arguing that the exclusive blanket license—as the only license offered at
the time—was an unlawful restraint of trade and that ASCAP was charging arbitrary
prices as a result of an illegal copyright pool.
132
While the first case was never fully
litigated after the government was granted a mid-trial continuance, the latter action was
settled with the imposition of a consent decree in 1941.
133
That consent decree has been
modified twice, first in 1950 and most recently in 2001.
134
The United States also
pursued antitrust claims against BMI, resulting in a similar consent decree in 1941.
135
The 1941 BMI consent decree was superseded by a new decree in 1966, which was last
amended in 1994.
136
Although the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees are not identical, they share many of the
same features. As most relevant here, the PROs may only acquire nonexclusive rights to
license members’ public performance rights; must grant a license to any user that
applies, on terms that do not discriminate against similarly situated licensees; and must
accept any songwriter or music publisher that applies to be a member, as long as the
writer or publisher meets certain minimum standards.
137
ASCAP and BMI are also required to offer alternative licenses to the blanket license.
One option is the adjustable fee blanket license, a blanket license with a carve-out that
reduces the flat fee to account for music directly licensed from PRO members. Under
the consent decrees, ASCAP and BMI must also provide, when requested, through-to-
the-audience” licenses to broadcast networks that cover performances not only by the
networks themselves, but also by affiliated stations that further transmit those
130
Seyfert at 6, 20; see also Wilf at 177.
131
Seyfert at 20-21.
132
BMI v. CBS, 441 U.S. at 10.
133
Seyfert at 20-21.
134
BMI v. CBS, 441 U.S. at 11.
135
Id. at 12 n.20.
136
Seyfert at 22; see also BMI Consent Decree.
137
ASCAP Consent Decree §§ IV.B-C, VI, VIII, XI; BMI Consent Decree §§ IV.A, V, VIII.
36
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
performances downstream.
138
ASCAP and BMI are also required to provide per-
program and per-segment licenses, as are described above.
139
ASCAP is expressly barred from licensing any rights other than its members’ public
performance rights (i.e., ASCAP may not license mechanical or synchronization
rights).
140
Although BMI’s consent decree lacks a similar prohibition, in practice BMI
does not license any rights other than public performance rights.
141
Finally, and perhaps most significantly, prospective licensees that are unable to agree to
a royalty rate with ASCAP or BMI may seek a determination of a reasonable license fee
from one of two federal district court judges in the Southern District of New York.
142
The rate court procedures are discussed in greater detail below.
In response to requests by ASCAP and BMI to modify certain provisions of their decrees,
the DOJ’s Antitrust Division announced in June 2014 that it would be evaluating the
consent decrees, and has solicited and received extensive public comments on whether
and how the decrees might be amended.
143
Specifically, both ASCAP and BMI seek to
modify the consent decrees to permit partial grants of rights to the PROs, to replace the
current ratesetting process with expedited arbitration, and to allow ASCAP and BMI to
provide bundled licenses that include multiple rights in musical works.
144
The DOJ has
expressed its intent to “examine the operation and effectiveness of the Consent Decrees,”
particularly in light of the changes in the way music has been delivered and consumed
since the most recent amendments to those decrees.
145
At the same time, the DOJ is
138
ASCAP Consent Decree § V; BMI Consent Decree § IX.
139
ASCAP Consent Decree §§ II.J-K, VII; BMI Consent Decree § VIII.B. Note that under the
ASCAP consent decree, the per-segment license has a number of conditions that must be met
before it can be used. ASCAP Consent Decree § VII.
140
ASCAP Consent Decree § IV.A.
141
See BMI, Comments on Department of Commerce Green Paper at 4-5 (Nov. 13, 2013), available
at http://www.ntia.doc.gov/files/ntia/bmi_comments.pdf.
142
ASCAP Consent Decree § IX; BMI Consent Decree § XIV.
143
Antitrust Consent Decree Review, U.S. DOJ, http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/ascap-bmi-decree-
review.html (last visited Jan. 26, 2015).
144
ASCAP, Comments Submitted in Response to the DOJ’s Antitrust Consent Decree Review at
18, 22, 31 (Aug. 6, 2014), available at
http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/ascapbmi/comments/307803.pdf (“ASCAP Antitrust Consent
Decree Review Comments”); BMI, Comments Submitted in Response to the DOJ’s Antitrust
Consent Decree Review at 2 (Aug. 6, 2014), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/ascapbmi/
comments/307859.pdf (“BMI Antitrust Consent Decree Review Comments”).
145
Antitrust Consent Decree Review, U.S. DOJ, http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/ascap-bmi-decree-
review.html (last visited Jan. 26, 2015).
37
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
conducting a related investigation to determine whether there has been a coordinated
effort among music publishers and PROs to raise royalty rates.
146
Key Antitrust Cases
In addition to the DOJ actions that led to the adoption of the consent decrees, PRO
practices have been the subject of private antitrust actions, including a number related to
the consent decrees. The decisions in these cases serve to highlight courts’ approach to
the collective licensing of public performance rights and administration of the consent
decrees.
In the 1979 Supreme Court case of BMI v. CBS, CBS had sued ASCAP and BMI, alleging
that the blanket license violated antitrust laws by constituting “illegal price fixing, an
unlawful tying arrangement, a concerted refusal to deal, and a misuse of copyrights.”
147
Rather than declaring the blanket licenses per se unlawful, the Court held that they
should be evaluated under a “rule of reason” test, observing that a blanket license could
be useful to address the problem of negotiating thousands of individual licenses. The
Court also noted as relevant the fact that there were no “legal, practical, or conspiratorial
impediment[s]” to obtaining direct licenses, indicating licensees have a real choice to
license directly as an alternative to the blanket license.
148
On remand, the court of
appeals upheld the blanket license under the rule of reason, explaining that it did not
unreasonably restrain competition because CBS could feasibly obtain direct licenses
from copyright owners.
149
After the BMI v. CBS litigation, a number of other courts examined the blanket license,
and sustained it against antitrust challenges under rule-of-reason analysis. In Buffalo
Broadcasting v. ASCAP, for example, the Second Circuit concluded that, in the context of
local television stations, the blanket license did not violate the Sherman Act because per-
program licenses, direct licenses, and source licenses were realistic alternatives to the
blanket license.
150
A federal district court in the District of Columbia reached a similar
conclusion with respect to cable stations.
151
146
Ed Christman, Dept. of Justice Sends Doc Requests, Investigating UMPG, Sony/ATV, BMI and
ASCAP Over Possible “Coordination, B
ILLBOARD (July 13, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/
articles/news/publishing/6157513/dept-of-justice-sends-doc-requests-investigating-umpg-
sonyatv. Members of the DOJ Antitrust Division attended and observed the Office’s roundtables
for this study in Nashville and New York.
147
BMI v. CBS, 441 U.S. at 6.
148
Id. at 24.
149
CBS v. ASCAP, 620 F.2d 930, 938-39 (2d Cir. 1980).
150
Buffalo Broad. v. ASCAP, 744 F.2d at 926-32; see also id. at 934 (Winter, J., concurring) (“[S]o long
as composers or [publishers] have no horizontal agreement among themselves to refrain from
38
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
More recent litigation has involved royalty rate disputes. In 2012, the Second Circuit
addressed rate disputes involving ASCAP and BMI, on the one hand, and DMX, a
background music service, on the other, regarding the rate to be paid for an adjustable-
fee blanket license.
152
In arguing for a lower rate, DMX pointed to direct licenses it had
entered into with a number of copyright owners, most of them smaller publishers, on
relatively favorable terms for DMX.
153
DMX also relied on a direct license from
Sony/ATV, a major music publisher. That deal gave Sony/ATV a pro rata share at the
same annual rate as other smaller publishers, but also provided Sony a $2.4 million
advance and a $300,000 administrative fee.
154
The court found this and the other direct
deals entered into by DMX to be persuasive benchmarks and that the rate courts
reasonably considered DMX’s direct licenses in their rate determinations. Although the
PROs argued that the substantial advance paid to Sony/ATV rendered that license an
inadequate basis to set rates for the remainder of publishers covered by PRO licenses,
the court of appeals affirmed the rates adopted by the rate courts.
155
There has also been recent litigation between the PROs and Pandora, the internet radio
service. In 2011 and 2013, respectively, in response to demands by their major publisher
members, ASCAP and BMI both amended their rules to allow music publishers to
withdraw from PRO representation the right to license their public performance rights
for “new media” usesi.e., digital streaming services—while still allowing the PROs to
license to other outlets on their behalf.
156
As a result, Pandorafaced with a potential
loss of PRO licensing authority for the major publishers’ catalogsproceeded to
negotiate licenses directly with EMI Music Publishing Ltd. (“EMI”),
157
Sony/ATV and
UMPG at varying rates that brought the publishers higher fees than those they were
receiving under the PRO system. Pandora, however, challenged the publishers’ partial
withdrawal of rights before both the ASCAP and BMI rate courts. In each casethough
applying slightly differing logicthe court ruled that under the terms of the consent
source or direct licensing and there is no other artificial barrier, such as a statute, to their use, a
non-exclusive blanket license cannot restrain competition.”).
151
Natl Cable Television Ass’n, Inc. v. BMI, 772 F. Supp. 614, 628 (D.D.C. 1991).
152
BMI v. DMX, 683 F.3d at 35, 43.
153
Id. at 38.
154
Id.
155
Id. at 47-49.
156
In re Pandora Media, Inc., Nos. 12-cv-8035, 41-cv-1395, 2013 WL 5211927, at *2 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 17,
2013); BMI v. Pandora Media, Inc., Nos. 13-cv-4037, 64-cv-3787, 2013 WL 6697788, at *2-3 (S.D.N.Y.
Dec. 19, 2013).
157
Not long afterward, EMI’s music catalog was acquired through a transaction with Sony/ATV.
In re Pandora, 2013 WL 5211927, at *3.
39
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
decree, music publishers could not withdraw selected rights; rather, a publisher’s songs
must be either “all in” or “all out” of the PRO.
158
Following these rulings, the ASCAP rate court held a bench trial and issued a decision
on the merits of the rate dispute between ASCAP and Pandora.
159
Relying on Pandora’s
negotiated agreements with the major publishers as benchmarks, ASCAP had sought a
rate of 1.85% of revenues for 2011-2012, 2.50% for 2013, and 3.00% for 2014-2015.
160
The
court determined that a rate of 1.85% of revenues with no increase was appropriate for
the entire period. In so concluding, the court rejected ASCAP’s reliance on the higher-
priced licensing agreements with the major publishers, concluding that Sony/ATV and
UMPG had engaged in improper negotiation tactics, such as by declining to provide lists
of the works the publishers represented so that Pandora could remove those works from
its service in the event of a failure to reach agreement.
161
The Pandora decision is
addressed in greater depth in Part IV.
SESAC has also recently been the target of antitrust suits by local television stations and
the RMLC, both of which have accused SESAC of engaging in anticompetitive conduct
by taking steps to make its blanket license the only viable option for these users, such as
by unreasonably and steeply raising the cost of the per-program license and imposing
penalties on publishers that engage in direct licensing.
162
In October 2014, the local
television stations and SESAC agreed to a settlement in which SESAC agreed to pay
$58.5 million to the television stations and to provide a per-program license in addition
to a blanket license beginning January 1, 2016.
163
The RMLC suit against SESAC remains
pending.
c. Consent Decree Procedures
As noted, ASCAP and BMI are required by their consent decrees to grant a nonexclusive
license to publicly perform all of the works in their repertoires to any potential licensee
who makes a written application.
164
An entity that seeks a public performance license
begins the process by submitting such a request to the PRO. In the absence of an
established rate for the applicant’s use, the PRO and the applicant may then engage in
158
In re Pandora, 2013 WL 5211927, at *5-7; BMI, v. Pandora, 2013 WL 6697788, at *3-4.
159
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 321-22.
160
Id. at 354.
161
Id. at 357-61.
162
Meredith Corp., 1 F. Supp. 3d at 192-93; RMLC v. SESAC, 29 F. Supp. 3d at 492-94.
163
Memorandum of Law in Support of Plaintiffs’ Unopposed Motion for Preliminary Approval of
Settlement at 1-2, 5, Meredith Corp., 1 F. Supp. 3d 180 (No. 09-cv-9177). TMLC, though not a party
to the litigation, was also a signatory to the settlement. Id. at 1 n.2.
164
ASCAP Consent Decree § VI; BMI Consent Decree § IV.A.
40
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
negotiations regarding the appropriate rate.
165
Significantly, however, under both
consent decrees, the mere submission of the application gives the applicant the right
immediately to begin using the musical works in the PROs repertoire without payment
of any fee or compensation during the pendency of negotiations or a ratesetting
proceeding.
166
If the PRO and licensee are unable to agree on a fee, either party may apply for a
determination of a reasonable fee by the applicable rate court.
167
The term “rate court” is
a bit of a misnomer, however; as noted above, rate disputes are handled by the federal
district judge in the Southern District of New York who has been assigned ongoing
responsibility for administration of the relevant consent decree.
168
Currently, the ASCAP
decree and ratesetting cases are overseen by Judge Denise Cote, and Judge Louis L.
Stanton oversees these matters with respect to BMI.
In a rate court proceeding, the PRO has the burden of proving that the royalty rate it
seeks is “reasonable,” and if the court determines that the proposed rate is not
reasonable, it will determine a reasonable rate itself.
169
In determining a reasonable fee,
the rate court is tasked with assessing the fair market value of the license, i.e., “what a
license applicant would pay in an arm’s length transaction.”
170
But antitrust concerns
also play a direct role: according to the Second Circuit, the rate courts are also obligated
to “tak[e] into account the fact that the PRO, as a monopolist, exercises disproportionate
power over the market for music rights.”
171
Since negotiations between PROs and potential licensees—as well as rate court
proceedings—can be lengthy, an applicant or a PRO may apply to the rate court to fix an
interim rate, pending final determination of the applicable rate. Under the two decrees,
such interim fees are supposed to be set by the court within three to four months.
172
Once the rate court fixes the interim rate, the licensee must pay the interim fee
165
ASCAP Consent Decree § IX.F; BMI Consent Decree § XIV.A.
166
ASCAP Consent Decree § IX.E; BMI Consent Decree § XIV.A.
167
ASCAP Consent Decree § IX.A; BMI Consent Decree § XIV.A.
168
Paul Fakler, Music Copyright Royalty Rate-Setting Litigation: Practice Before the Copyright Royalty
Board and How It Differs from ASCAP and BMI Rate Court Litigation, 33 L
ICENSING J. 1, 5 (2013),
available at http://www.arentfox.com/sites/default/files/FaklerLicensingJournalArticle.pdf.
169
ASCAP Consent Decree § IX.B-D; BMI Consent Decree § XIV.A.
170
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 353 (citation omitted).
171
BMI v. DMX, 683 F.3d at 45 (internal quotation marks, citations, and alterations omitted).
172
The interim fee proceedings are to be completed within 90 days in ASCAP’s case and 120 days
in BMI’s case. See ASCAP Consent Decree § IX(F); BMI Consent Decree § XIV.B.
41
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
retroactively to the date of its license application.
173
Final royalty rates are also applied
retroactively.
174
Significantly, section 114(i) of the Copyright Act prohibits the rate court from
considering the licensing fees paid for digital performances of sound recordings in its
ratesetting proceedings for the public performance of musical works.
175
This provision
was included when Congress created a public performance right for sound recordings
with the 1995 enactment of the DPRSRA.
176
In theory, it was intended to protect
royalties for the public performance of musical works from being diminished as a result
of the grant of a public performance right for sound recordings in digital contexts.
177
4. Statutory License for Public and Noncommercial
Broadcasting
The activities of public and noncommercial educational broadcasters are subject to a
hodgepodge of music licensing protocols. Section 118 provides a statutory license that
covers such entities’ public performances of musical works and reproductions and
distributions that enable such performances.
178
The section 118 license, however, applies
only to over-the-air broadcasts.
179
Noncommercial broadcasters must clear digital
performance rights for musical works (e.g., for internet radio) with the PROs under the
provisions of the consent decrees as applicable.
180
In addition, the section 118 license does not extend to the use of sound recordings by
noncommercial broadcasters. For certain reproduction, distribution, and derivative
rights for sound recordings, noncommercial broadcasters rely on the exemption in
section 114(b), which applies to music “included in educational television and radio
programs . . . distributed or transmitted through public broadcasting entities.”
181
The
173
See id.
174
See id.
175
17 U.S.C. § 114(i).
176
DPRSRA § 3.
177
BMI First Notice Comments at 11.
178
17 U.S.C. § 118(c).
179
Id. § 118(c)(1), (f) (limiting performance license to “noncommercial educational broadcast
station[s]” as defined in 47 U.S.C. § 397); 47 U.S.C. § 397 (defining “noncommercial educational
broadcast station” as a “television or radio broadcast station”); see also NRBNMLC First Notice
Comments at 14 (describing section 118 license as being “confined to over-the-air
transmissions”).
180
See NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 14-15 (explaining that for “digital transmission of
musical works . . . noncommercial broadcasters are required to negotiate with ASCAP, BMI, and
SESAC”).
181
17 U.S.C. § 114(b).
42
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
114(b) exemption does not apply to digital performances and related reproductions,
however.
182
For those uses, noncommercial broadcasters must obtain section 112 and
114 statutory licenses (discussed below).
183
C. Licensing Sound Recordings
1. Exclusive Rights in Sound Recordings
The owner of a sound recording fixed on or after February 15, 1972 possesses a number
of exclusive rights under the Copyright Act, including the right to make and distribute
copies or phonorecords (e.g., CDs and DPDs) of the work;
184
the right to create derivative
works (e.g., a new work based on an existing recording);
185
and the right to perform the
work publicly by means of a digital audio transmission (e.g., via internet or satellite
radio).
186
The Act exempts public performances of sound recordings by terrestrial radio
stations.
187
2. Reproduction and Distribution Rights
Except in the limited case of noninteractive streaming services that qualify for
compulsory licensing under sections 112 and 114, licenses to reproduce and distribute
sound recordings—such as those necessary to make and distribute CDs, transmit DPDs
and ringtones, or operate an interactive music service—are obtained through direct
negotiation between a licensee and the sound recording owner (usually a record label) in
the open market.
188
3. Public Performance Rights
a. Lack of Terrestrial Performance Right
In the 1995 DPRSRA, Congress gave sound recording owners an exclusive public
performance right, but one limited to digital audio transmissions, and created the
182
NPR First Notice Comments at 4-5. Section 114(b) extends to “educational television and radio
programs.” 17 U.S.C. § 114(b). (Note that section 114(b) defines “educational television and
radio programs” by referencing 47 U.S.C. § 397, but Congress deleted that definition from section
397 in 1978 without changing section 114(b). See 47 U.S.C. § 397 note. At the time of § 114(b)’s
enactment in 1976, the term was defined in section 397 as “programs which are primarily
designed for educational or cultural purposes.”).
183
NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 2-3; NPR First Notice Comments at 3-4.
184
17 U.S.C. § 106(1), (3).
185
Id. § 106(2).
186
Id. § 106(6).
187
Id. § 114(d)(1).
188
See DiMA First Notice Comments at 8.
43
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
section 114 statutory license for noninteractive subscription providers, including satellite
radio, engaged in digital performances.
189
In 1998, Congress extended the section 114
compulsory license to expressly include webcasting as a covered activity.
190
It also
expanded the exemption for ephemeral copies in section 112 to cover the server copies
needed to digitally transmit sound recordings.
191
Traditional over-the-air broadcasts,
however, were expressly exempted from the sound recording performance right.
192
Congress drew this legal distinction based on perceived differences between digital and
traditional services, believing at the time that traditional broadcasters posed “no threat”
to the recording industry, in contrast to digital transmission services.
193
A longstanding
justification for the lack of a sound recording performance right has been the
promotional effect that traditional airplay is said to have on the sale of sound
recordings.
194
In the traditional view of the market, broadcasters and labels representing
copyright owners enjoy a mutually beneficial relationship whereby terrestrial radio
stations exploit sound recordings to attract the listener pools that generate advertising
dollars, and, in return, sound recording owners receive exposure that promotes record
and other sales.
195
As discussed in Section III, apart from the fact that sound recordings help generate
billions of dollars annually for terrestrial radio stations, there are significant questions as
to whether the traditional view of the market—even if persuasive in earlier times—
remains credible today. Notably, in 2014, with 298 million active listeners, terrestrial
radio had “more than double the total of Pandora (79 million), Sirius XM (27 million)
and Spotify (14 million) combined.”
196
189
See generally DPRSRA.
190
DMCA § 405(a).
191
Id. §§ 402, 405(b).
192
See 17 U.S.C. § 114(d)(1).
193
See S. REP. NO. 104-128, at 14-15 (“It is the Committee’s intent to provide copyright holders of
sound recordings with the ability to control the distribution of their product by digital
transmissions, without hampering the arrival of new technologies, and without imposing new
and unreasonable burdens on radio and television broadcasters, which often promote, and
appear to pose no threat to, the distribution of sound recordings.”).
194
Id.
195
See U.S. GOVT ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, GAO-10-862, TELECOMMUNICATIONS: THE PROPOSED
PERFORMANCE RIGHTS ACT WOULD RESULT IN ADDITIONAL COSTS FOR BROADCAST RADIO STATIONS
AND
ADDITIONAL REVENUE FOR RECORD COMPANIES, MUSICIANS, AND PERFORMERS 13-21 (2010),
available at http://www.gao.gov/assets/310/308569.pdf (GAO
REPORT”).
196
Zach O’Malley, Truth in Numbers: Six Music Industry Takeaways From Year-End Data, FORBES
(Jan. 22, 2015), available at http://www.forbes.com/sites/zackomalleygreenburg/2015/01/22/truth-
44
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Internationally, the United States is an outlier. Virtually all industrialized nations
recognize a more complete public performance right for sound recordings than does the
United States.
197
The failure of U.S. law to do the same causes U.S. record companies
and artists to forgo an estimated $70-100 million in royalties for foreign exploitations of
their works due to the lack of reciprocity.
198
Significantly, however, in recent years, the nation’s largest broadcast company,
iHeartMedia (formerly Clear Channel), has entered into licensing agreements with
WMG and a number of independent record labels (including Big Machine Records, the
record label of Taylor Swift, Rascal Flatts, and Tim McGraw) covering both terrestrial
and internet radio.
199
While the current CRB rate for streamed radio is a per-play rate,
these arrangements apparently feature a percentage-based or other alternative rate
structure for both digital and terrestrial uses.
200
Although the terms of these deals
remain private, reports indicate that iHeartMedia agreed to pay the smaller labels based
on an industry rate of 1% of advertising revenues for terrestrial uses, and perhaps a
larger sum to WMG.
201
In recent years there have also been various legislative efforts to provide for a more
complete public performance right,
202
as well as numerous congressional hearings
focused on expanding the right to cover traditional broadcast transmissions.
203
The
in-numbers-six-music-industry-takeaways-from-year-end-data/ (noting live music comprises 26%
and satellite radio subscription 10%).
197
Only a handful of countriesincluding Iran and North Korealack such a right, in addition to
the United States. See, e.g., A2IM First Notice Comments at 8; SoundExchange First Notice
Comments at 17.
198
GAO REPORT at 30 (estimates based on language of the Performance Rights Act, S. 379, 111th
Cong. (2009)). The NAB disputes these figures. NAB First Notice Comments at 29-30 & n.15.
199
See Ed Christman, Here’s Why Warner Music’s Deal with Clear Channel Could be Groundbreaking
for the Future of the U.S. Music Biz (Analysis), B
ILLBOARD (Sept. 12, 2013), http://
www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/5694973/heres-why-warner-musics-deal-with-clear-
channel-could-be-groundbreaking.
200
Id.
201
Id.; see also Ben Sisario, Clear Channel-Warner Music Deal Rewrites the Rules on Royalties, N.Y.
TIMES (Sept. 12, 2013), http://www.nytimes.com/2013/09/13/business/media/clear-channel-
warner-music-deal-rewrites-the-rules-on-royalties.html.
202
See, e.g., Performance Rights Act, H.R. 848, S. 379, 111th Cong. (2009); Performance Rights Act,
H.R. 4789, S. 2500, 110th Cong. (2010); Free Market Royalty Act, H.R. 3219, 113th Cong. (2013).
203
See, e.g., Internet Streaming of Radio Broadcasts: Balancing the Interests of Sound Recording Copyright
Owners with Those of Broadcasters: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Courts, the Internet, and Intell.
Prop. of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 108th Cong. (2004) (“Internet Streaming of Radio Hearing”);
Music Licensing Hearings.
45
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Copyright Office has long supported, and continues to support, the creation of a more
complete sound recording performance right.
204
b. Section 112 and 114 Licenses
The section 114 statutory license allows different types of noninteractive digital music
servicesfree and paid internet radio services,
205
“preexisting” satellite radio services,
206
and “preexisting” music subscription services
207
to perform sound recordings upon
compliance with the statutory license requirements, including the payment of royalties
as determined by the CRB.
208
In addition, recognizing that such digital services must
make server reproductions of sound recordingssometimes called “ephemeral”
copies—to facilitate their digital transmissions, Congress established a related statutory
license under section 112 to authorize the creation of these copies.
209
Rates and terms for
the section 112 license are also established by the CRB.
The section 112 and 114 licenses for sound recordings are subject to a number of
technical limitations. For instance, services relying on the section 114 statutory license
are prohibited from publishing an advance program schedule or otherwise announcing
204
See, e.g., The Performance Rights Act and Parity Among Music Delivery Platforms: Hearing Before the
S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 111th Cong. 117-18 (2009) (”Performance Rights Act Hearing”) (statement
of Marybeth Peters, Register of Copyrights); Ensuring Artists Fair Compensation: Updating the
Performance Right and Platform Parity for the 21st Century: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Courts, the
Internet, & Intellectual Prop. of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 111th Cong. 13-30 (2007) (Ensuring
Artists Fair Compensation Hearing) (statement of Marybeth Peters, Register of Copyrights);
Internet Streaming of Radio Hearing at 8-22 (statement of David O. Carson, General Counsel, U.S.
Copyright Office); U.S.
COPYRIGHT OFFICE, PERFORMANCE RIGHTS IN SOUND RECORDINGS (Comm.
Print 1978), available at http://copyright.gov/reports/performance-rights-sound-recordings.pdf
(“P
ERFORMANCE RIGHTS REPORT”).
205
Free noninteractive internet radio services not exempt under 17 U.S.C. § 114(d)(1) qualify as
“eligible nonsubscription services,” and paid noninteractive internet radio services qualify as
“new subscription services” in the parlance of sections 112 and 114. See 17 U.S.C. § 114(j)(6), (8).
206
A preexisting satellite digital audio radio service is a subscription satellite audio radio service
provided pursuant to a satellite digital audio radio service license issued by the FCC on or before
July 31, 1998. Id. § 114(j)(10). Currently, there is only one satellite service, Sirius XM. See
Determination of Rates and Terms for Preexisting Subscription Services and Satellite Digital
Audio Radio Services, 78 Fed. Reg. 23,054, 23,055 (Apr. 17, 2013) (“PSS/Satellite II”).
207
A preexisting subscription service is a noninteractive audio-only service that was in existence
on or before July 31, 1998. 17 U.S.C. § 114(j)(11). Music Choicewhich transmits music via cable
and satellite television and the internetis an example of a pre-existing subscription service.
PSS/Satellite II, 78 Fed. Reg. at 23,055 n.5.
208
17 U.S.C. § 114(d)(2).
209
DMCA § 402; 17 U.S.C. § 112(e)(1); H.R. REP. NO. 105-796, at 89 (1998) (Conf. Rep.).
46
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
or identifying in advance when a specific song, album or artist will be played.
210
Another example is the “sound recording performance complement,” which limits the
number tracks from a single album or by a particular artist that may be played during a
3-hour period.
211
Payment and reporting of royalties under the section 112 and 114 licenses are made to a
single non-profit agent: SoundExchange.
212
SoundExchange was established by the
RIAA in 2000 and in 2003 was spun off as an independent entity.
213
The Copyright Act
specifies how royalties collected under section 114 are to be distributed: 50% go to the
copyright owner of the sound recording, typically a record label; 45% go to the featured
recording artist or artists; 2½% go to an agent representing nonfeatured musicians who
perform on sound recordings; and 2½% to an agent representing nonfeatured vocalists
who perform on sound recordings.
214
Section 112 fees are paid by SoundExchange
directly to the sound recording owner.
215
Prior to distributing royalty payments,
SoundExchange deducts the reasonable costs incurred in carrying out its
responsibilities.
216
Notably, the Act does not include record producers in the statutorily defined royalty
split. As a result, record producers must rely on contracts with one of the parties
specified in the statute, often the featured recording artist, in order to receive royalties
from digital performances.
217
To help facilitate these contracts, SoundExchange has
210
See 17 U.S.C. § 114(d)(2)(B)-(C).
211
Id. § 114(d)(2)(B)(i), (d)(2)(C)(i), (j)(13).
212
37 C.F.R. § 380.11 (“Collective is the collection and distribution organization that is designated
by the Copyright Royalty Judges. For the 2011-2015 license period, the Collective is
SoundExchange, Inc.”); see also Intercollegiate Broad. Sys., Inc. v. Copyright Royalty Bd., 571 F.3d 69,
91 (D.C. Cir. 2009).
213
Technology Briefing: Internet; Online Royalty Pool Created, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 29, 2000, at C4; Global
Business Briefs, W
ALL ST. J., Oct. 2, 2003, at B5.
214
17 U.S.C. § 114(g)(2); see About Digital Royalties, SOUNDEXCHANGE,
http://www.soundexchange.com/artist-copyright-owner/digital-royalties/ (last visited Jan. 26,
2015). Royalties collected pursuant to section 112 are not distributed according to this split, and
instead are paid entirely to the record labels. Review of Copyright Royalty Judges
Determination, 73 Fed. Reg. 9143, 9146 (Feb. 19, 2008).
215
17 U.S.C. § 112(e); see also Review of Copyright Royalty Judges Determination, 73 Fed. Reg. at
9146 (explaining that “[r]oyalties collected under section 114 are paid to the performers and the
copyright owners of the sound recordings . . . whereas, the royalties collected pursuant to the
section 112 license are not paid to performers).
216
17 U.S.C. § 114(g)(3).
217
See id. § 114(g)(2); About Digital Royalties, SOUNDEXCHANGE; see also Music Licensing Hearings at
14 (statement of Neil Portnow, President/CEO of The Recording Academy).
47
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
begun processing direct payments to producers based upon written direction from the
featured artist.
218
Since SoundExchange became an independent entity in 2003, it has distributed over $2
billion to artists and labels.
219
The collective engages in outreach to identify and locate
artists and labels who may be due royalties from the funds that is has collected.
220
Nonetheless, significant amounts of unclaimed funds have accumulated over time.
221
Press accounts indicate that SoundExchange had unclaimed royalties of approximately
$96 million as of the end of 2013.
222
Under the applicable regulations, SoundExchange
retains all undistributed royalties for not less than three years, and thereafter may
release them to offset its administrative costs and/or to engage in ratesetting and
enforcement activities.
223
Interactive/Noninteractive Distinction
The statutory licensing framework applies only to noninteractive (i.e., radio-style)
services; interactive or on-demand services are not covered.
224
The distinction between
interactive and noninteractive services has been the matter of some debate. The statute
provides that an interactive service is one that enables a member of the public to receive
either “a transmission of a program specially created for the recipient,“ or “on request, a
transmission of a particular sound recording, whether or not as part of a program, which
is selected by or on behalf of the recipient.”
225
The statutory definition leads to the question of whether so-called “personalized” or
“custom” music streaming services—services that tailor the music they play to
individual user preferences—transmit programs that are “specially created for the
218
NARAS First Notice Comments at 5.
219
Our Work, SOUNDEXCHANGE, http://www.soundexchange.com/about/our-work/ (last visited
Jan. 26, 2015).
220
SoundExchange Outreach Efforts, SOUNDEXCHANGE, http://www.soundexchange.com/wp-
content/uploads/2014/11/Outreach-Fact-Sheet_11.5.14.pdf (last visited Jan. 26, 2015).
221
See Glenn Peoples, SoundExchange Financials Show Fewer Unclaimed Royalties, Persistent Data
Problems, B
ILLBOARD (Dec. 24, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/articles/business/6415147/
soundexchange-fewer-unclaimed-royalties-data-problems.
222
Id.
223
See, e.g., 37 C.F.R. §§ 380.8, 380.17, 380.27.
224
See 17 U.S.C. §§ 112(e), 114(d)(2)-(3), 114(f). The distinction between interactive and
noninteractive services has been the matter of some debate, and is addressed infra.
225
Id. § 114(j)(7).
48
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
recipient.” In Arista Records LLC v. Launch Media, Inc. (“Launch Media”), the Second
Circuit held that one such service that played songs for users based on users’ individual
ratings was not interactive because the service did not displace music sales.
226
Following
the Launch Media decision, personalized music streaming services such as Pandora and
Rdio have obtained statutory licenses as noninteractive services for their public
performance of sound recordings. The CRB-established rates do not currently
distinguish between such customized services and other services that simply transmit
undifferentiated, radio-style programming over the internet.
Ratesetting Standards
Notably, under section 114, the rate standard applicable to “preexisting” satellite radio
and music subscription services (i.e., those services that existed as of July 31, 1998)
differs from that for other services such as internet radio and newer subscription
services.
227
This distinction is a legislative artifact. The section 114 statutory license was
first created with the enactment of the DPRSRA in 1995, and at the time it applied only
to satellite radio and subscription music services. Royalty rates and terms under the
more limited 1995 license were governed by the four-factor policy-oriented standard in
section 801(b)(1) of the Actthat is, the same standard that had long applied to the
section 115 license for musical works.
228
With the enactment of the DMCA in 1998,
Congress expanded the section 114 license to include internet radio, created a new
statutory license for associated ephemeral recordings in section 112, and created a new
ratesetting standardthe “willing buyer/willing seller”—standard. Congress, however,
grandfathered preexisting services (i.e., those that existed before the DMCA’s enactment)
under the old royalty ratesetting standard.
Accordingly, because of the staggered enactment of the section 112 and 114 licenses,
royalty rates for a limited set of older services—Sirius XM, as the only preexisting
satellite service, and Music Choice and Muzak, as the only preexisting subscription
servicesare governed by the four-factor standard in section 801(b) of the Act.
229
Meanwhile, for all internet radio and other newer digital music services, and for all
ephemeral recordings regardless of the service, the CRB is to establish rates and terms
“that most clearly represent the rates and terms that would have been negotiated in the
marketplace between a willing buyer and a willing seller.
230
As explained in Section III,
the continuing propriety of that disparity is a matter of dispute among stakeholders.
226
Launch Media, 578 F.3d 148, 161, 163-64 (2d Cir. 2009).
227
17 U.S.C. § 114(j)(10), (11); see PSS/Satellite II, 78 Fed. Reg. at 23,055.
228
See 17 U.S.C. §§ 114(f)(1), 115(c)(3), 801(b)(1).
229
See id. §§ 114(f)(1), 801(b)(1); PSS/Satellite II, 78 Fed. Reg. at 23,055 & n.5.
230
17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(2)(B). The provision further requires the CRB to consider “whether use of
the service may substitute for or may promote the sales of phonorecords or otherwise may
49
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
CRB Ratesetting Proceedings
The statutory rates that apply under the section 112, 114 and 115 licenses are established
by the CRB.
231
CRB ratesetting proceedings for the section 112, 114, and 115 licenses take
place at five-year intervals, and the timing of these proceedings is set by statute.
232
The CRB is composed of three judges, and Congress imposed strict qualifications for
these positions. Each CRB judge is required to have at least seven years of legal
experience.
233
The chief copyright royalty judge must have a minimum of five years of
experience in adjudications, arbitrations, or court trials. As for the other two judges, one
must have significant knowledge of copyright law, and the other must have significant
knowledge of economics.
234
The Register of Copyrights also plays a role in ratesetting,
in that she is responsible for reviewing the CRB’s determinations to ensure they are free
from material legal error, and may also be called upon to address material questions of
substantive law that impact the proceedings.
235
Final ratesetting determinations are
appealable to the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit.
236
Congress intended the ratesetting process to permit voluntary industry agreements
when possible.
237
For example, Congress provided antitrust exemptions to statutory
licensees and copyright owners of sound recordings, so that they could designate
common agents to collectively negotiate and agree upon royalty rates.
238
The statute also
allows for settlement of ratesetting disputes, and mandates a three-month “voluntary
negotiation period” at the start of each proceeding before the parties submit their
cases.
239
If a settlement is reached among some or all of the participating parties, the Act
interfere with or may enhance the sound recording copyright owner’s other streams of revenue
from its sound recordings,” and “the relative roles of the copyright owner and the transmitting
entity in the copyrighted work and the service made available to the public with respect to
relative creative contribution, technological contribution, capital investment, cost, and risk.” Id.
231
Id. § 801(b)(1).
232
Id. § 804(b).
233
Id. § 802(a).
234
Id.
235
H.R. REP. NO. 108-408, at 26 (2004), reprinted in 2004 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2,332, 2,341; 17 U.S.C.
§ 802(f)(1).
236
17 U.S.C. § 803(d)(1).
237
H.R. REP. NO. 108-408, at 24.
238
17 U.S.C. §§ 112(e)(2), 114(e)(1), 115(c)(3)(B) (These antitrust exemptions are limited to
negotiations addressing rights within the scope of the statutory licenses in sections 112, 114, and
115).
239
See id. § 803(b)(1)-(3).
50
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
empowers the CRB to adopt that settlement “as a basis for statutory terms and rates”
that will apply to all parties under the statutory license.
240
Notably, however, the Act
does not require the CRB to immediately act on such settlements. In the past, the CRB
has deferred the adoption of partial settlements until the end of the full ratesetting
proceeding.
241
Absent a settlement, the CRB must proceed to determine the rates and terms of the
statutory license. Although the CRB has some flexibility in organizing its procedures,
many aspects of its proceedings are dictated by the statute.
242
In many instances, these
procedures depart from practices used in ordinary civil litigation. For instance,
participating parties must file their written direct cases in support of their requested
ratesincluding witness testimony and supporting exhibitsbefore any discovery has
been taken.
243
Additionally, the statute requires separate direct and rebuttal phases of
ratesetting hearings, effectively resulting in two trials.
244
These procedures cannot be
altered by the CRB even upon stipulation of the parties.
Royalty Rates
In general, the CRB (like the CARP before it) has adopted “per-performance” rates for
internet radio, rather than the percentage-of-revenue rates that are typical in PRO
licenses.
245
That per-stream approach has proven controversial. After the CRB’s
“Webcasting II” decision in 2007, a number of internet radio services and broadcasters
complained that the per-performance rates were unsustainable. These concerns led
Congress to pass legislation giving SoundExchange the authority to negotiate and agree
to alternative royalty schemes that could be binding on all copyright owners and others
240
Id. § 801(b)(7).
241
See SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 8-9; see also Digital Performance Right in Sound
Recordings and Ephemeral Recordings, 76 Fed. Reg. 13,026, 13,027 (Mar. 9, 2011) (adopting
partial settlement entered into in June 2009 as basis for final rates and terms for commercial
webcasters).
242
See 17 U.S.C. § 803(b)(6).
243
Id.
244
Id. § 803(b)(6)(C).
245
See, e.g., 37 C.F.R. § 380.3(a)(1); see also Determination of Reasonable Rates and Terms for the
Digital Performance of Sound Recordings and Ephemeral Recordings, 67 Fed. Reg. 45,240, 45,272
(July 8, 2002). Section 112 rates have been a relatively insignificant part of the CRB’s ratesetting
proceedings, and have been established as a modest percentage of the 114 rate. See e.g., 37 C.F.R.
§ 385.3(c) (establishing ephemeral recording rate to be 5% of the total royalties paid under the
section 112 and 114 licenses).
51
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
entitled to royalty payments in lieu of the CRB-set rates.
246
Similar complaints after a
webcasting rate decision under the CARP system had earlier led Congress to enact
analogous legislation in 2002.
247
In the wake of Congress’ actions, SoundExchange reached agreement with a number of
internet radio services, in general adopting royalty rates that were more closely aligned
with the services’ revenues. For example, in 2009, SoundExchange negotiated rates with
large commercial “pureplay” internet radio services (i.e., services like Pandora that only
transmit over the internet).
248
Under that agreement, those services agreed to pay the
greater of 25% of gross revenues or specified per-performance rates.
249
c. Privately Negotiated Licenses
A streaming service that does not fall under the section 112 and 114 licensesi.e., an
interactive service—must negotiate a license with a record company in order to use the
label’s sound recordings.
250
Since direct licenses are agreed upon at the discretion of the
copyright owner and the potential licensee, the license terms can be vastly different from
those that apply under the statutory regime. It is common for a music service seeking a
sound recording license from a label to pay a substantial advance against future
royalties, and sometimes an administrative fee.
251
Other types of consideration may also
be involved. For example, the major labels acquired a reported combined 18% equity
stake in the on-demand streaming service Spotify allegedly based, at least in part, on
their willingness to grant Spotify rights to use their sound recordings on its service.
252
246
See Webcaster Settlement Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-435, 122 Stat. 4974. Congress later
extended the timeframe for negotiations. See Webcaster Settlement Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111-
36, 123 Stat. 1926; see also Terry Hart, A Brief History of Webcaster Royalties, C
OPYHYPE (Nov. 29,
2012), http://www.copyhype.com/2012/11/a-brief-history-of-webcaster-royalties.
247
Small Webcaster Settlement Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-321, 116 Stat. 2780.
248
Notification of Agreements Under the Webcaster Settlement Act of 2009, 74 Fed. Reg. 34,796,
34,797 (July 17, 2009); Brian T. Yeh, Statutory Royalty Rates for Digital Performance of Sound
Recordings: Decision of the Copyright Royalty Board, in M
USIC LICENSING RIGHTS AND ROYALTY ISSUES
35, 49 (Thomas O. Tremblay ed., 2011).
249
Notification of Agreements Under the Webcaster Settlement Act of 2009, 74 Fed. Reg. at 34,799-
800; K
OHN at 1498.
250
17 U.S.C. § 114(d)(3)(C).
251
A2IM Second Notice Comments at 5-6; Resnick Second Notice Comments at 2-3; see also
Hannah Karp, Artists Press for Their Share, W
ALL ST. J. (July 21, 2014), http://online.wsj.com
/news/articles/SB20001424052702303833804580023700490515416 (reporting that WMG received an
advance from Google of over $400 million).
252
See Helienne Lindvall, Behind the Music: The Real Reason Why the Major Labels Love Spotify,
G
UARDIAN (Aug. 17, 2009), http://www.theguardian.com/music/musicblog/2009/aug/17/major-
labels-spotify.
52
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
4. Pre-1972 Sound Recordings
When Congress acted in 1971 to grant federal copyright protection to sound recordings,
it extended federal protection prospectively, to recordings created on or after February
15, 1972.
253
Sound recordings fixed before February 15, 1972 are protected by a
patchwork of differing state laws.
254
The disparate treatment of pre-1972 sound recordings under federal versus state law has
given rise to a number of significant policy concerns, including issues about the
preservation and use of older recordings without the benefit of federally recognized
limitations on copyright owners’ exclusive rights.
255
These issues were extensively
addressed in a 2011 Copyright Office report on potential federalization of copyright for
pre-1972 recordings.
256
In its report, the Office surveyed state laws and determined that “the protections that
state law provides for pre-1972 sound recordings are inconsistent and sometimes vague
and difficult to discern.”
257
In addition, the Office’s report concluded that state law did
not provide adequate protection for uses that would be considered fair uses under
federal law.
258
The Office therefore recommended that pre-1972 recordings be brought
within the federal copyright system, which would offer uniform protection to their
owners as well as appropriate exceptions and limitations for the benefit of users.
Since the Office’s report was released, there have been some notable developments in
this area. A significant question has arisen concerning whether state law protection
extends to the public performance of pre-1972 recordings.
259
In the context of their
negotiated deals with record labels, some major services, including YouTube and
Spotify, obtain licenses that cover the useincluding the performanceof pre-1972
253
Sound Recording Act of 1971, 85 Stat. at 392.
254
The Copyright Act expressly permits states to continue state law protection for pre-1972 sound
recordings until February 15, 2067, at which time all state protection will be preempted by federal
law and pre-1972 sound recordings will enter the public domain. 17 U.S.C. § 301(c). There is,
however, a significant class of pre-1972 sound recordings that do enjoy federal copyright
protectionsound recordings of foreign origin for which copyright protection was “restored” as
part of the Uruguay Round Agreements Act in 1994. See P
RE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT
at 17-20.
255
See PRE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT at 64-70.
256
See generally id.
257
Id. at 48.
258
Id. at 86-87.
259
In a 1977 report on public performance rights in sound recordings, the Copyright Office
recognized that Congress had left the decision whether or not to recognize a performance right
for pre-1972 sound recordings to the states. P
ERFORMANCE RIGHTS REPORT at 18.
53
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
sound recordings.
260
Some services that use the section 112 and 114 statutory licenses,
such as Music Choice,
261
make payments to SoundExchange for use of pre-1972 works
pursuant to the same statutory rates and terms applicable under sections 112 and 114.
262
Others, including Sirius XM and Spotify, do not pay royalties either to copyright owners
directly or to SoundExchange for performances of pre-1972 sound recordings.
263
Recently, three courtstwo in California and one in New York—have held that the
unauthorized public performance of pre-1972 sound recordings violates applicable state
law. In the initial case, a California federal district court ruled that Sirius XM infringed
rights guaranteed to plaintiffs by state statute.
264
A state court in California
subsequently adopted the federal court’s reading of the California statute in a second
action against Sirius XM.
265
Following these decisions, in a third case against Sirius XM,
a federal district court in New York has indicated that the public performance of pre-
1972 sound recordings constitutes common law copyright infringement and unfair
competition under New York law.
266
Notably, the reasoning employed in these
decisions is not expressly limited to digital performances (i.e., internet streaming and
satellite radio); they thus could have potentially broad implications for terrestrial radio
(currently exempt under federal law for the public performance of sound recordings) as
well. In the meantime, similar lawsuits have been filed against other digital providers,
260
Tr. at 161:18-21 (June 5, 2014) (Scott Sellwood, Google/YouTube); Tr. at 152:04-09 (June 5, 2014)
(Steven Marks, RIAA).
261
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 15; Tr. at 190:08-18 (June 24, 2014) (Paul Fakler, Music
Choice).
262
PRE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT at 45 n.196; but see PSS/Satellite II, 78 Fed. Reg. at 23,073
(indicating pre-1972 sound recordings are not covered by section 112 and 114 licenses).
263
See Hannah Karp, Turtles and Sirius XM: Not Happy Together, WALL ST. J. (Aug. 3, 2013),
http://blogs.wsj.com/speakeasy/2013/08/03/turtles-and-sirius-xm-not-happy-together. Previously,
Sirius XM did include pre-1972 recordings in its royalty accounting logs to SoundExchange,
which were non-itemized, but stopped in 2011 after SoundExchange asked Sirius XM to start
reporting exactly what it was paying for. See Hannah Karp, Sirius Is Sued Over Music Royalties for
Pre-1972 Recordings, W
ALL ST. J. (Aug. 26, 2013), http://www.wsj.com/articles/
SB10001424127887324591204579037260890310376.
264
See Flo & Eddie Inc. v. Sirius XM (“Flo & Eddie v. Sirius XM CA”), No. 13-cv-5693, 2014 U.S. Dist.
LEXIS 139053, at *22-23 (C.D. Cal. Sept. 22, 2014).
265
Capitol Records, LLC v. Sirius XM, No. BC520981 (Cal. Super. Ct. Oct. 14, 2014) (order regarding
jury instructions), available at http://www.project-72.org/documents/Sirius-XM-Order-Granting-
Jury-Mot.pdf.
266
See Flo & Eddie Inc. v. Sirius XM (“Flo & Eddie v. Sirius XM NY”), No. 13-cv-5784, 2014 U.S. Dist.
LEXIS 166492, at *40-44, *50-52 (S.D.N.Y. Nov. 14, 2014) (denying Sirius XM’s motion for
summary judgment, and asking Sirius XM to show cause why judgment should not be entered
on behalf of plaintiffs), reconsideration denied, 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 174907 (Dec. 12, 2014).
54
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
including Pandora, Google, Apple’s Beats service, and Rdio, alleging the unauthorized
use of pre-1972 recordings.
267
Another issue that has been the subject of recent litigation is whether the DMCA safe-
harbor provisions extend to pre-1972 sound recordings.
268
Under section 512(c), an
internet service provider is not liable for “infringement of copyright by reason of the
storage at the direction of a user of” infringing material, provided that the service meets
certain statutory conditions, including take-down requirements.
269
Meanwhile, a
separate provision of the Act, section 301(c), preserves state law protection for pre-1972
sound recordings, stating that “any rights or remedies under the common law or statute
of any state shall not be annulled or limited by this title until February 15, 2067.”
270
In its
2011 report, the Office examined the interplay between these two provisions, and
concluded that the DMCA safe harbors did not apply to pre-1972 sound recordings.
271
Although one decision predating the Office’s report found that the DMCA safe harbors
do apply to pre-1972 sound recordings,
272
more recent decisions have agreed with the
Copyright Office that the safe harbors are a creature of federal law and do not limit state
law protections.
273
D. Synchronization Rights
To incorporate music into an audiovisual work—such as a film, video television
program, or video game—the creator of that work must obtain synchronization licenses
from both the owner of the musical work and the owner of the sound recording.
Synchronization (often shortened to “synch”) refers to the use of music in “timed
relation” to visual content.
274
Although the Copyright Act does not refer explicitly to a
267
See Flo & Eddie, Inc. v. Pandora Media, Inc., No. 14-cv-07648 (C.D. Cal. Oct. 2, 2014); Complaint,
Capitol Records, LLC v. Pandora Media, Inc., No. 651195/2014 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. Apr. 17, 2014); see also
Eriq Gardner, Sony, Google, Apple Hit With Lawsuits Over Pre-1972 Music, H
OLLYWOOD REPORTER
(Jan. 23, 2015), http://www.hollywoodreporter.com/thr-esq/sony-google-apple-hit-lawsuits-
766187.
268
See 17 U.S.C. § 512(a)-(d).
269
Id. § 512(c).
270
Id. § 301(c).
271
PRE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT at 130-32.
272
Capitol Records, Inc. v. MP3tunes, LLC, 821 F. Supp. 2d 627, 64042 (S.D.N.Y. 2011). But see
Capitol Records, Inc. v. MP3tunes, LLC, No. 07-cv-9931, 2012 WL 242827, at *1*2 (S.D.N.Y. Jan. 9,
2012) (citing Copyright Office report and acknowledging that its earlier decision “may involve a
‘substantial ground for difference of opinion’”).
273
Capitol Records, LLC v. Vimeo, LLC, 972 F. Supp. 2d 500, 536-37 (S.D.N.Y. 2013); see also Capitol
Records, LLC v. Vimeo, LLC, 972 F. Supp. 2d 537, 552 (S.D.N.Y. 2013) (denying motion for
reconsideration); Capitol Records, Inc. v. Naxos of America, Inc., 830 N.E.2d 250 (N.Y. 2005).
274
See Steele v. Turner Broad. Sys., Inc., 646 F. Supp. 2d 185, 193 (D. Mass. 2009).
55
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
synchronization right, it is generally understood to be an aspect of music owners
reproduction and/or derivative work rights.
275
The licensing of music for inclusion in audiovisual works, unlike that for other uses,
occurs in the free market for both musical works and sound recordings. The synch
market thus stands as a useful counterpoint to the regulated licensing markets discussed
above. A notable feature of the synch market is the relatively even balance between
royalties paid for the musical works rights and those paid for the sound recording
rights. Musical work and sound recording owners are generally paid equally—50/50—
under individually negotiated synch licenses.
276
The synchronization market for uses in commercial works such as film, television
programs, and video games appears reasonably efficient and flexible. In addition to in-
house resources, a number of intermediaries help handle licensing for those who wish to
use music in a new creative work. Music supervisors working for production
companies facilitate selection, negotiation, and delivery of music for use in audiovisual
productions.
277
Companies such as Greenlight, Dashbox, Cue Songs, and Rumblefish
provide online services that offer different songs for synchronization purposes.
278
An evolving aspect in the music licensing marketplace is the exploitation of music
videos that record labels produce to accompany new releases. Traditionally, any
royalties for these videos were nominal, as they were created largely to promote sales of
275
See, e.g., Buffalo Broad. v. ASCAP, 744 F.2d at 920; Agee, 59 F.3d at 321.
276
See NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 16; Tr. at 60:20-22 (June 4, 2014) (Brittany Schaffer,
NMPA/Loeb & Loeb LLP) (“[S]ynchronization licenses are generally divided in terms of income
50/50 between sound recording and the musical composition.”). While parity may be
commonplace for individually negotiated deals, the same does not seem to hold true for broader
licenses with consumer-facing video services such as YouTube. Under an HFA-administered
YouTube license, for example, publishers are paid 15% of YouTube’s net revenue from uploaded
videos that incorporate HFA-controlled publishing rights and embody a commercially released
or distributed sound recording (e.g., a lip sync video), and 50% of revenue from videos that
incorporate HFA-controlled publishing rights but embody a user-created recording (i.e., a cover
recording). NMPA/HFA/YOUTUBE,
LICENSING OFFER, Licensing Offer Overview,
http://www.youtubelicenseoffer.com/docs/notice.pdf (last visited Jan. 29, 2015). YouTube’s
standard contract for independent record labels reportedly allocates 45% of YouTube subscription
music video revenue to labels, as compared to 10% to publishers. Ed Christman, Inside YouTube’s
Controversial Contract with Indies, B
ILLBOARD (June 20, 2014), http://www. billboard.com/
biz/articles/news/digital-and-mobile/6128540/analysis-youtube-indie-labels-contract-
subscription-service?mobile_redirection=false.
277
NMPA & HFA Second Notice Comments at 10-13.
278
Id. at 14-15.
56
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
records through music video channels such as MTV.
279
But more recently, as videos
have become among the most common ways in which consumers wish to enjoy music,
280
there is strong interest in developing this market. Record labels seek to license these
professionally created videoswhich incorporate musical worksto online providers
such as YouTube and Vevo.
281
In the early 2000s, major record labels and publishers entered into “New Digital Media
Agreements” (“NDMAs”) to allow labels efficiently to obtain licenses from their major
publisher counterparts so they could pursue new digital products and exploit music
videos in online markets.
282
These licensing arrangements, in turn, became a model for a
more recent 2012 agreement between UMG and NMPA that allowed UMG to seek
similar rights from smaller independent publishers on an “opt-in” basis. The licensing
arrangement includes rights for the use of musical works in “MTV-style” videos, live
concert footage, and similar exploitations.
283
Like the major record labels, larger music publishers have entered into direct licensing
relationships with the on-demand video provider YouTube that allow them some
amount of control over the use of user-uploaded videos incorporating their music and
provide for payment of royalties.
284
Following the settlement of infringement litigation
279
See PASSMAN at 177-78 (reflecting the decline of the traditional market for music videos on
platforms such as the MTV television network); K
OHN at 1119 (noting that promotional music
videos have synchronization fees that are “quite nominal, set at an amount intended merely to
cover the administrative costs of preparing the paperwork for the license grant. This is because
the copyright owner stands to substantially benefit from . . . performance royalties resulting from
the exhibition of the music video.”).
280
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 14.
281
Vevo is a joint venture between UMG, SME, the Abu-Dhabi Media Company, and YouTube.
See Alex Pham, YouTube Confirms Vevo Deal, B
ILLBOARD (July 2, 2013), http://www.billboard.com
/biz/articles/news/digital-and-mobile/1568816/youtube-confirms-vevo-deal; see also P
ASSMAN at
259 (for record company-produced videos streamed, “the record labels get about 70% of ad
revenues and/or subscription monies,” and generally pay publishers “in the range of 10% of the
ad revenues (a little under 15% of the 70% that the company gets)”).
282
See RIAA First Notice Comments at 14 n.28; NMPA Second Notice Comments at 33.
283
See NMPA Second Notice Comments at 33; Susan Butler, UMG/NMPA Broker Model License
Agreement, M
USIC CONFIDENTIAL, June 21, 2012; Ed Christman, NMPA Inks Deal With Universal
Music Group Over VEVO, YouTube Videos, B
ILLBOARD (June 19, 2012), http://www.billboard.com
/biz/articles/news/publishing/1093134/nmpa-inks-deal-with-universal-music-group-over-vevo-
youtube. The licensing arrangement excludes rights for synch uses in motion pictures, television,
advertising, video games and other products that are typically individually negotiated by
publishers. Butler, UMG/NMPA Broker Model License Agreement.
284
See YouTube Licensing Offer Overview, YOUTUBE LICENSING OFFER, http://www.youtubelicense
offer.com/notice (last visited Jan. 26, 2015).
57
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
by a class of independent music publishers against YouTube in 2011,
285
NMPA and its
licensing subsidiary HFA announced an agreement with YouTube under which smaller
publishers could choose to license their musical works to YouTube by opting in to
prescribed licensing terms. Those who choose to participate in the arrangement grant
YouTube the right to “reproduce, distribute and to prepare derivative works (including
synchronization rights)” for videos posted by YouTube’s users.
286
The license does not,
however, cover the public performance right. Music publishers who opt into the
YouTube deal receive royalties from YouTube and have some ability to manage the use
of their music through HFA, which administers the relationship and can access
YouTube’s content identification tools on behalf of individual publishers.
287
Over 3,000
music publishers have entered into this licensing arrangement with YouTube.
288
Another developing area is the market for so-called micro-licenses” for music that is
used in videos of modest economic value, such as wedding videos and corporate
presentations. In the past, income received by rightsholders from licensing such uses
might not overcome administrative or other costs. But the market is moving to take
advantage of technological developments—especially online applications—that make
micro-licensing more viable. This includes the aforementioned services like Rumblefish,
but also efforts by NMPA, HFA, and RIAA to license more synchronization rights
through programs that allow individual copyright owners to effectuate small licensing
transactions.
289
E. Licensing Efficiency and Transparency
New digital services face a formidable challenge when attempting to license music. One
study showed that acquiring the necessary rights to offer a marketable digital music
offering
290
requires roughly eighteen months of effort, with some entities never able to
285
See The Football Ass’n Premier League Ltd. v. YouTube, Inc., 633 F. Supp. 2d 159 (S.D.N.Y. 2009).
286
YouTube License Agreement, YOUTUBE LICENSING OFFER, http://www.youtubelicenseoffer.com
/docs/license.pdf (last visited Jan. 26, 2015); see also Susan Butler, Anatomy of a Trade Group License,
M
USIC CONFIDENTIAL, Sept. 9, 2011.
287
See YouTube Licensing Offer Overview, YOUTUBE LICENSING OFFER, http://www.youtubelicense
offer.com/notice (last visited Jan. 26, 2015).
288
Susan Butler, U.S. Music Licensing: The Rights Holders (Part Two, Conclusion), MUSIC
CONFIDENTIAL, June 5, 2014.
289
Ed Christman, RIAA & NMPA Eyeing Simplified Music Licensing System, Could Unlock ‘Millions’
in New Revenue, B
ILLBOARD (June 13, 2013), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/record-
labels/1566550/riaa-nmpa-eyeing-simplified-music-licensing-system-could.
290
See RIAA First Notice Comments at 8 (“To be competitive, today’s streaming, cloud and
subscription music services require licenses to the full catalog of songs (and shares thereof)
owned by virtually every music publisher.”); DiMA Second Notice Comments at 16 (“Digital
service providers and record companies do, in fact, need to obtain licenses for millions of songs
58
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
successfully negotiate the licenses needed to launch their services.
291
One of the key
reasons for this complexity is the lack of an “authoritative list of rights holders and the
recordings/works they represent.”
292
As discussed in detail in Section III, it is widely acknowledged that reliable, up-to-date
information about copyrighted works is a critical prerequisite for efficient licensing in
the modern music marketplace. Both copyright owners and music services must be able
to uniquely identify particular sound recordings and underlying musical works, along
with the dynamic and often fractured ownership status of these distinct works. In
addition, they need to be able to pair sound recordings with the musical works they
embody. While the industry has made some progress on this front, much remains to be
done.
1. Data Standards
One of the initial considerations regarding management of reliable and up-to-date
copyright information for musical works and sound recording copyrights is the use of
standard identifiers. Fortunately, the music industry already employs a variety of
identifiers recognized by the International Organization for Standardization (“ISO), the
international standard-setting body. The ISO has established two key standards for the
identification of works themselves—the International Standard Music Work Code
(“ISWC”) for musical works, and the International Standard Recording Code (ISRC)
for sound recordings.
293
The ISWC represents a unique, permanent, and internationally recognized reference
number for the identification of musical works. The standard was developed by the
International Confederation of Societies of Authors and Composers (“CISAC”). In the
U.S. and Canada, ASCAP is the appointed agency that assigns ISWCs, and works with
in order to meet consumer expectations and be commercially viable.”). Notably, the recently
launched streaming service “The Overflow” offers a limited catalog of “Christian music” and
related genres. Glenn Peoples, David Beside Goliath: New Christian Music Streaming Service The
Overflow Points to a New Strategy, B
ILLBOARD (Jan. 5, 2015), http://www.billboard.com/articles/
business/6429451/overflow-christian-subscription-streaming-music-service; T
HE OVERFLOW,
http://theoverflow.com (last visited Jan. 20, 2015).
291
DAVID TOUVE, MUSIC BUSINESS ASSOCIATION, THE INNOVATION PARADOX: HOW LICENSING
AND
COPYRIGHT IMPACTS DIGITAL MUSIC STARTUPS 6-7 (2012) (“TOUVE”); see also John Seabrook,
Revenue Streams: Is Spotify the Music Industry’s Friend or Its Foe?, N
EW YORKER (Nov. 24, 2014),
available at http://www.newyorker.com/magazine/2014/11/24/revenue-streams (reporting that
Spotify’s U.S. licensing efforts took two years).
292
TOUVE at 5.
293
See Jessop First Notice Comments at 4.
59
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
other representatives of songwriters and publishers to assign ISWCs. As relevant here,
to obtain an ISWC, a publisher must provide the following at a minimum: at least one
original title for the work; all songwriters of the work identified by their Interested
Parties Information (“IPI”) code (discussed below); and whether the work is derived
from an existing work.
294
One significant issue with ISWCs, then, is that they cannot be
assigned until all the songwriters on a musical work are identified. This has the benefit
of assuring that data are complete before an identifier is attached. But it also leads to a
substantial lag time before the ISWC for a particular musical work can be assigned
unfortunately, this can occur well after a record is released, so that digital files
embodying the individual tracks often will not include ISWCs identifying the
underlying musical works.
295
ASCAP and BMIwhich also use proprietary numbering
systems to track works internally—add ISWCs to their databases as those codes are
assigned.
296
The ISRC was created as a unique, permanent, and internationally recognized reference
number for the identification of sound and music video recordings. ISRCs are assigned
at the track—rather than albumlevel. The ISO has appointed IFPI as the international
ISRC agency. IFPI in turn designates national or regional agencies to manage the
issuance of ISRCs within a specific country or region. The U.S. ISRC agency is RIAA.
RIAA authorizes individual record labels to assign ISRCs to their own recordings.
297
ISRCs are required to be included on digital files provided for the iTunes store and by
many other digital platforms.
There are some shortcomings with the ISRC system. First, there is no single definitive
U.S. database for ISRCs. Instead, each sound recording owner must maintain its own
ISRC records and metadata.
298
Notably, however, SoundExchange is currently
compiling a database of sound recordings performed under the section 112 and 114
294
What is an ISWC, ISWC INTERNATIONAL AGENCY, http://www.iswc.org/en/iswc.html (last
visited Jan. 9, 2015).
295
Tr. at 334:13-337:20 (June 23, 2014) (Andrea Finkelstein, SME; Jacqueline Charlesworth &
Sarang Damle, U.S. Copyright Office); Tr. at 343:2-344:16, 346:17-21 (June 23, 2014) (Lynn
Lummel, ASCAP).
296
ASCAP Second Notice Comments at 11 (“It should be underscored that each work will have
two identifiersthe ISWC as well as the PRO’s own internal Work ID number.”).
297
Obtaining Code, USISRC, http://www.usisrc.org/about/obtaining_code.html (last visited Jan. 25,
2015). RIAA also authorizes “ISRC managers” to assign ISRCs to sound recordings produced by
artists and labels that do not wish to manage their own ISRC assignments. Id.; see also Registration
Fees, USISRC, http://www.usisrc.org/faqs/registration_fees.html (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
298
Pipeline Project 2014, Belmont University’s Mike Curb College of Music Business and
Entertainment (“Pipeline Project”) Second Notice Comments at 7; see also Types, USISRC,
https://www.usisrc.org/applications/types.html (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
60
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
licenses, and expects to have good identification and ownership information, including
ISRCs, for approximately 14 million recordings in the relatively near term.
299
In addition, in the case of multiple owners, ISRCs do not require a complete list of
owners before assignment of ISRCs. Instead, the ISRC website recommends that
multiple owners simply designate one of the owners to assign the ISRC.
300
The ISO has adopted two other codes to identify the individuals or entities associated
with particular works. The IPI code allows a musical work to be associated with the
various parties that are involved in its creation, marketing, and administration. IPI
codes apply to composers, authors, composer/authors, arrangers, publishers,
administrators, and sub-publishers. The codes are assigned by CISAC and are necessary
to obtain an ISWC.
301
The International Standard Name Identifier (“ISNI”) is akin to the IPI, but while the IPI
scheme is limited to musical works, ISNI is designed to be a global identification system
for creators of all types of copyrighted works, including authors, songwriters, recording
artists, and publishers. The ISNI International Agency was founded in 2010 to develop
the standard, with the goal of eventually replacing existing, disparate identification
standards, including the IPI.
302
ISNIs are assigned by an international network of
registration agencies which rely upon a centralized database to assign and track ISNI
identifiers.
303
Over 8 million identities have been registered so far across multiple classes
of creators and works.
304
At the moment, however, it appears that most ISNIs are being
assigned to literary authors in Europe. It also seems that the number of registration
agencies globally remains limited, with only one agency so far in the United States.
305
299
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 4-5.
300
Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 7.
301
The IPI System, IPISYSTEM.ORG, http://www.ipisystem.org/SUISASITES/IPI/ipipublic.nsf/
pages/index1 (last visited Jan. 9, 2015).
302
See Jennifer Gatenby & Andrew MacEwan, ISNI: A New System For Name Identification,
I
NFORMATION STANDARDS QUARTERLY, Summer 2011, at 4-5, available at http://www.niso.org/
publications/isq/2011/v23no3/gatenby; Jennifer Gatenby & Joep Kil, ISNI From Development to
Operations, ISNI, www.isni.org/filedepot_download/58/95.
303
See Gatenby & MacEwan, ISNI: A New System For Name Identification at 4-5.
304
ISNI, http://www.isni.org (last visited Jan. 9, 2015).
305
Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 5. Bowker, an affiliate of ProQuest, assigns ISNIs
and tracks the assignment and usage of them. See Bowker Becomes First ISNI Registration Agency in
the U.S., B
OWKER (June 21, 2012), http://www.bowker.com/en-US/aboutus/press_room/2012/
pr_06212012a.shtml; Bowker, Use of ISNI Is Growing Fast Among Authors, Says New Bowker
Analysis, Y
AHOO FINANCE (May 7, 2014), http://finance.yahoo.com/news/isni-growing-fast-
among-authors-144800650.html.
61
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The music industry also employs identifiers not associated with ISO, including
Universal Product Codes (UPC”). In the music context, a UPC is a set of numbers,
along with a corresponding barcode, that identify a finished music product. A different
UPC is usually necessary for each product or version of a product to distinguish among,
for example, albums, digital singles, or remixed versions of sound recordings. UPCs are
generally required by most major physical retailers, and are now required by the iTunes
store and other digital platforms. Record labels generally acquire UPCs from GS1 US, a
nonprofit group that sets standards for international commerce. UPCs can also be
obtained for free or at a nominal cost from a music distributor such as CD Baby or
TuneCore.
306
In addition to standards that have been or are being developed by international
standard-setting entities, there are also private initiatives for identifying music and its
owners, for example, through the use of digital acoustic fingerprinting and similar
technologies. Examples include Gracenote, Shazam, and The Echo Nest—and perhaps
most notably, YouTube. An acoustic fingerprint is a digital rendering of the acoustical
properties of a particular sound recording, typically one embodied in a digital file such
as an mp3 file. That fingerprint can be stored and searched for matches to other digital
music files.
307
An acoustic fingerprint does not, on its own, provide ownership or
authorship information, but it can be associated with metadatasuch as the
standardized identifiers discussed above—that does. One advantage of using digital
fingerprints is that while it is relatively trivial to strip metadata such as ISRCs and
ISWCs from individual music files, it is arguably more difficult to alter a file’s acoustic
fingerprint without changing the quality of the audio.
308
2. Public Data
The U.S. Copyright Office operates a public registration system, which maintains
information that can help to identify musical works, sound recordings, and their
owners. The registration database, however, is not a comprehensive resource for this
purpose. Copyright registration is not mandatory, and so registration records are far
306
How to Get UPC Barcodes for Your Products, WALL ST. J., http://guides.wsj.com/small-
business/starting-a-business/how-to-get-upc-codes-for-your-products-2 (last visited Jan. 9, 2015);
Kristin Thomson, Metadata for Musicians, F
UTURE OF MUSIC COALITION (Nov. 4, 2014),
https://futureofmusic.org/article/article/metadata-musicians.
307
Michael Brown, White Paper: Audio Fingerprinting, MAXIMUM PC (Apr. 3, 2009), http://
www.maximumpc.com/article/features/white_paper_audio_fingerprinting.
308
See Ciumac Sergiu, Duplicate Songs Detector Via Audio Fingerprinting, CODE PROJECT (June 20,
2013), http://www.codeproject.com/Articles/206507/Duplicates-detector-via-audio-fingerprinting.
62
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
from complete. In addition, even when a work has been registered, the registration
record is static and thus will not reflect a change in ownership.
309
The database that houses the Office’s registration records is not currently designed to
identify or locate works through the use of standard identifiers, such as those described
above, and such identifiers are not required in the registration process.
310
As a result, a
relatively small number of registration records for musical works and sound recordings
reflect these standard identifiers.
311
Apart from the original registration, some, but not all, copyright owners choose to
record assignments and transfers of ownership through the Copyright Office’s
recordation process. Again, however, such records are far from complete.
312
Nor, due to
the historical separation of the registration and recordation systems, is information
about recorded documents reliably linked to registration records.
313
3. Non-Government Databases
Several entities actively develop and maintain their own discrete databases, many of
which include standard identifiers and other metadata used by the music industry to
track sound recordings and musical works.
As noted above, the RIAA does not keep a central database of sound recordings
associated with ISRCs, and so the most comprehensive U.S. sound recording database is
likely that of SoundExchange. SoundExchange maintains a database of sound
recordings whose uses have been reported to it under the section 112 and 114 licenses,
together with information regarding the associated recording artists and labels. This
309
ROBERT BRAUNEIS, ABRAHAM L. KAMINSTEIN SCHOLAR IN RESIDENCE, U.S. COPYRIGHT
OFFICE, TRANSFORMING RECORDATION AND REENGINEERING AT THE UNITED STATES COPYRIGHT
OFFICE 127-29 (2015) (“BRAUNEIS”), available at http://www.copyright.gov/docs/recordation/.
310
Technological Upgrades to Registration and Recordation Functions, 78 Fed. Reg. 17,722 (Mar.
22, 2013); B
RAUNEIS at 120-21.
311
As of March 2013, for example, ISRCs were associated with only 5,510 (0.03%) of registration
records in the Copyright Office Catalog. B
RAUNEIS at 121.
312
Id. at 110-11.
313
Id. The Office has recently embarked upon public processes to consider possible upgrades to
its systems that could improve the searchability and usability of its records. Such changes might
include, for example, a more robust registration database and a shift to a more user-friendly and
accessible electronic recordation system. See Strategic Plan for Recordation of Documents, 79 Fed.
Reg. 2696 (Jan. 15, 2014); Technological Upgrades to Registration and Recordation Functions, 78
Fed. Reg. 17,722 (Mar. 22, 2013).
63
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
database is not currently publicly accessible or available to be used for licensing
purposes.
314
In the realm of musical works, HFA maintains an extensive database of ownership
information and provides an online tool enabling the public to search for songwriter and
publisher data for all songs that have been registered by its member publishers.
315
ASCAP, BMI, and SESAC each also have databases covering the compositions in their
repertoires that are available to the public through their respective websites.
316
In
addition, ASCAP and BMIalong with the Society of Composers, Authors and Music
Publishers of Canada (“SOCAN”)—are currently collaborating to create a common,
authoritative resource for the musical works represented by the several organizations.
The joint initiative, called MusicMark, will enable publishers to submit a single file for
registration of a song and revise ownership data across the PROs simultaneously, even if
the work was co-written by members of different societies. Each PRO will then integrate
the registration data into its own repertoire database. By enabling PRO members to
more efficiently register musical works through a single interfaceincluding works co-
written by songwriters who are members of different PROs—MusicMark should
provide a more accurate and synchronized view of copyright information for works in
the repertoires of the participating PROs.
317
While each of these databases represents an important and valuable component of the
U.S. music marketplace, because they are separate and separately controlled, they do not
offer a comprehensive licensing resource. The HFA and PRO databases are currently
searchable by the public only manually, on an individual song basis.
318
In addition,
these organizations do not warrant the accuracy or completeness of the information they
provide (perhaps because they are relying upon representations by third parties
concerning authorship and ownership).
319
Finally, it is unclear what effect publisher
314
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 5.
315
SONGFILE, http://www.songfile.com (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
316
ASCAP’s database is called ACE, and BMI’s database is called the BMI Repertoire. See Ace Title
Search, ASCAP, https://www.ascap.com/Home/ace-title-search/index.aspx (last visited Jan. 29,
2015); BMI Repertoire, BMI, http://repertoire.bmi.com/startpage.asp (last visited Jan. 29, 2015).
SESAC also has a database called SESAC Repertory. SESAC Repertory, SESAC,
http://www.sesac.com/Repertory/RepertorySearch.aspx?x=39&y=19 (last visited Jan. 29, 2015).
317
MUSICMARK, http://www.musicmark.com (last visited Jan. 9, 2015).
318
See SONGFILE, http://www.songfile.com (last visited Jan. 25, 2015); Ace Title Search, ASCAP,
https://www.ascap.com/Home/ace-title-search/index.aspx (last visited Jan. 29, 2015); BMI
Repertoire, BMI, http://repertoire.bmi.com/startpage.asp (last visited Jan. 29, 2015); SESAC
Repertory, SESAC, http://www.sesac.com/Repertory/RepertorySearch.aspx?x=39&y=19 (last
visited Jan. 29, 2015).
319
Terms of Use Agreement, ASCAP, http://www.ascap.com/about/legal-terms/terms-of-use.aspx
(last visited Jan. 16, 2015); Terms and Conditions of Use, BMI, http://www.bmi.com/legal/entry/
64
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
withdrawal from the PROs in favor of direct administration of the relevant rights—
should it come to pass—might have on the efficacy of the PRO databases.
320
4. International Efforts
One example of international efforts to address data information deficiencies is (or was)
the planned Global Repertoire Database (“GRD) for musical works, to be developed by
a working group spearheaded and funded by music publishers and collective
management organizations in the EU with the support of the World Intellectual
Property Organization (“WIPO”). The GRD was intended to provide a comprehensive
and authoritative source of data about the ownership and administration of musical
works throughout the world. Its supporters anticipated enabling registrations directly
from publishers, composers and collective management organizations, and maintaining
a database of those registrations, with procedures to resolve ownership disputes.
Unfortunately, despite the acknowledged need for solutions in data sharing, support for
the project has waned, and the GRD effort has been put on hold (at least for the time
being).
321
A similar effort remains underway with respect to sound recordings. Phonographic
Performance Ltd (“PPL”), the U.K. collective rights organization, is building a Global
Recordings Database and has so far compiled ownership data on over 5.6 million
recordings released in the United Kingdom. PPL intends to expand its efforts by
terms_and_conditions_of_use (last visited Jan. 25, 2015); SESAC Repertory Terms and Conditions,
SESAC, http://www.sesac.com/Repertory/Terms.aspx (last visited Jan. 25, 2015); Songfile Terms of
Use, S
ONGFILE, http://www.songfile.com/termsofuse.html (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
320
Notably, in the wake of the Pandora decisionwhich criticized UMPG’s and Sony/ATVs
failure to provide catalog data to Pandorathese publishers have recently posted their U.S.
catalogs online. See Press Release, UMPG, Universal Music Publishing Group To Offer Expanded
Access To Song Catalog Data Through Company’s Website (June 27, 2014), available at
http://www.umusicpub.com/#contentRequest=newsdetail&contentLocation=sub&
contentOptions=%26articleID%3D6437%26from%3Dpressreleases; Sony/ATV Makes Entire
Catalogue Available Online, M
USIC BUSINESS WORLDWIDE (JU LY 16, 2014), http://
www.musicbusinessworldwide.com/sonyatv-makes-entire-catalogue-available-online/.
321
PRS ‘disappointed’ at Global Repertoire Database collapse, MUSIC ALLY (June 11, 2014),
http://musically.com/2014/07/11/prs-disappointed-at-global-repertoire-database-collapse; Paul
Resnikoff, Repertoire Database Declared a Global Failure. . . , D
IGITAL MUSIC NEWS (July 10, 2014),
http://www.digitalmusicnews.com/permalink/2014/07/10/global-repertoire-database-declared-
global-failure.
65
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
working with major record companies and a range of overseas music licensing
companies to include worldwide data.
322
Another initiative is the U.K.’s Copyright Hub, a web portal connected to a network of
rightsholders that aims to make it easier for people to track down and license
copyrighted works.
323
At present, the Copyright Hub’s functionality is fairly basic,
offering helpful information about copyright law and website links to licensing
organizations. The plan is to change from a signposting tool into an inquiry router that
sends queries to rights managers’ databases, and returns results to Hub users.
324
In
addition, further development may enable creators to register rights information with
third-party registries linked to the Hub.
325
5. Data Sharing Initiatives
As explained above, data regarding the creation, ownership, and administration of
sound recordings and musical works are currently maintained in discrete and
independently administered databases. A number of initiatives have attempted to
overcome this situation by developing standards related to the communication of
information about works among disparate sources. In particular, these initiatives are
aimed at allowing relevant information and metadata to be efficiently communicated in
a common format so that each party requiring access to the data can understand and
automatically process that data without excessive administrative costs.
One such initiative is Digital Data Exchange (“DDEX”), an industry consortium
consisting of media companies, music licensing entities, digital service providers and
others.
326
DDEX has developed standardized formats in which rights and licensing
information is represented and communicated.
327
For example, DDEX offers digital sales
report standards that are being used in the U.K. to facilitate standardized reporting
322
RICHARD HOOPER & ROS LYNCH, COPYRIGHT WORKS: STREAMLINING COPYRIGHT LICENSING
FOR THE
DIGITAL AGE 3 (2012), available at http://www.copyrighthub.co.uk/Documents/dce-
report-phase2.aspx.
323
THE COPYRIGHT HUB, http://www.copyrighthub.co.uk (last visited Jan. 25, 2015).
324
Id.
325
Id.; Tom Cox, Copyright Hub Pilot Introduced in the UK, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY BLAWG (Aug.
8, 2013), http://www.intellectualpropertyblawg.com/copyright-law/copyright-hub-pilot-
introduced-in-the-uk; Welcome to the Copyright Hub, W
ORLD INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY REVIEW
(Jan. 9, 2013), http://www.worldipreview.com/article/welcome-to-the-copyright-hub.
326
See DDEX First Notice Comments at 1.
327
See, e.g., MUSIC BUSINESS ASSOCIATION, MUSIC METADATA STYLE GUIDE V2, at 35-38, available
at http://musicbiz.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/08/MusicMetadataStyleGuide-MusicBiz-
FINAL.pdf (last modified Aug. 14, 2014).
66
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
between digital music services and the U.K. PRO, PRS for Music.
328
By employing
DDEX messaging standards, entities wishing to transact with multiple companies can
avoid handling multiple formats and delivery methods.
329
A similar initiative is WIPO’s proposed International Music Registry (IMR”), which
seeks to provide a single access point to the different rights management systems used
around the world. WIPO is currently conducting a series of stakeholder discussions on
the IMR’s scope and structure.
330
328
Press Release, RightsFlow, PRS For Music And Rightsflow Partner On DDEX Standardized
Reporting Initiative (Dec. 13, 2010), http://mi2n.com/print.php3?id=136849.
329
See DDEX First Notice Comments at 1-2.
330
What Copyright Infrastructure is needed to facilitate the Licensing of Copyrighted Works in the Digital
Age: the International Music Registry?, WIPO, http://www.wipo.int/edocs/mdocs/mdocs/en/
wipo_ip_aut_ge_11/wipo_ip_aut_ge_11_t12.doc; The International Music Registry, WIPO,
http://www.wipo.int/imr/en (last visited Jan. 27, 2015).
67
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
III. Challenges of the Current System
Perhaps not surprisingly in light of its bewildering array of rights and practices, those
who participated in the study identified many significant obstacles in the current music
licensing marketplace. As detailed below, stakeholders have a wide range of opinions
concerning how best to address them.
Despite the areas of controversy, however, on a somewhat brighter note, study
participants were able to articulate some broad areas of consensus as to the overarching
principles that should guide any revision of our licensing system, as follows: First,
music creators need to be fairly compensated for their efforts.
331
Second, the licensing
process needs to be more efficient, including through bundling of necessary rights.
332
Third, market participants need access to authoritative data to identify and license the
music they use.
333
And fourth, usage and payment information should be transparent
331
See, e.g., Copyright Alliance First Notice Comments at 6 (“We believe all authors and creators
are entitled to fair compensation for their creative work.”); DiMA First Notice Comments at 1
(“DiMA members share the belief that rights owners should be appropriately compensated for
the use of copyrighted works.”); NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 31 (noting that “[f]or
music publishers and songwriters, music licensing is only effective if it provides a fair market
royalty for the use of their songs”); SGA First Notice Comments at 3 (identifying “fair market
value compensation for the use of musical works” as an “indispensable need”).
332
See, e.g., Public Knowledge & CFA First Notice Comments at 5 (“Copyright law’s music
licensing provisions can help alleviate . . . bottlenecks and make music licensing more efficient
and fair for all.”); NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments (“Music publishers and songwriters seek
an efficient digital music marketplace. . . .”); RIAA Second Notice Comments at 13 (“Commenters
desire a more efficient licensing process, and focused on blanket licensing as one way to achieve
such efficiency.”); NARAS First Notice Comments at 2 (“The Recording Academy supports a
structure that is fair, simple and efficient for both the licensor and licensee.”); GIPC Second
Notice Comments at 7 (urging the Office to “keep in mind issues of efficiency in the marketplace
so as to facilitate new, licensed services”).
333
See, e.g., Modern Works Music Publishing First Notice Comments at 10 (“Congress should
encourage cooperation among licensors to create technologies that enable licensees to easily
search rights databases.”); Pilot Music Business Services Second Notice Comments at 3 (“[O]ne
centralized database is needed.”); Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 18 (“It seems to us
that the statutory license was the twenty-century’s solution to efficiency; however, as we progress
further into the digital age, and as data becomes more useful, we no longer see a great need for a
compulsory license.”); Tr. at 381:04-11 (June 23, 2014) (Waleed Diab, Google/YouTube) (“[T]he
ability to match the information on the sound recording side and the composition side is
absolutely necessary. . . . I think what you are hearing is, there is absolutely a need for a
centralized, standardized, data base, somewhere that services can go and pull that information.”).
68
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
and accessible to rights owners.
334
Many of the stakeholders’ comments reflect these
important goals.
A. Compensation and Licensing Disparities
1. Effect of Market Trends on Creator Income
According to the Supreme Court, copyright is intended to increase the “harvest of
knowledge” by assuring creators “a fair return for their labors.”
335
And, as noted above,
industry participants are in general agreement that a well-functioning music licensing
system should adequately compensate those who create and record songs.
336
There is,
however, substantial debate as to whether the current music licensing system is
achieving this goal and, if it is not, the reasons why it is failing creators.
In recent years, many music creators have decried what they see as a precipitous decline
in their income.
337
Understanding the reasons for this apparent decrease requires
knowledge of creators’ various income streams. Songwriters have three primary sources
of income, which they generally share with music publishers: mechanical royalties,
synchronization royalties, and performance royalties. Recording artists receive a share
of revenues from their record labels for the sale of physical and digital albums and
singles, sound recording synchronization royalties, and digital performance royalties. In
334
See, e.g., NSAI Second Notice Comments at 2-3 (expressing concern about advances and
bonuses that “are never paid to the songwriter or composer” and proposing requiring that “such
payments be disclosed by record labels and music publishers”); SGA First Notice Comments at 3
(calling for “complete transparency throughout the licensing, use and payment process”); Kohn
First Notice Comments at 11 (proposing that service providers “be required to provide
transparent access to transaction data in real-time to an independent validation service”); RIAA
Second Notice Comments at 19 (“The major record companies . . . support the idea that where
there is direct licensing, publishers/writers should have a direct audit right with respect to third
parties that use their works.”).
335
Harper & Row Publishers, Inc. v. Nation Enters., 471 U.S. 539, 545-46 (1985).
336
See RIAA Second Notice Comments at 8 (“[N]obody seems to question the basic premise that
royalty rates should reflect fair market value.”).
337
See, e.g., SGA First Notice Comments at 10 (“[T]he income of the music and recording
industries (and especially of individual music creators and recording artists) have been
diminished, according to reliable estimates, by as much as two-thirds.”); A2IM First Notice
Comments at 10 (noting that “the decline in sound recording revenues” has “had a dramatic
effect on the income of both music labels . . . and their recording artists”); see also Nate Rau,
Nashville’s Musical Middle Class Collapses, T
ENNESSEAN (Jan. 28, 2015), http://
www.tennessean.com/story/entertainment/music/2015/01/04/nashville-musical-middle-class-
collapses-new-dylans/21236245 (observing that industry trends have led to “the collapse of
Nashville’s music middle class”).
69
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
addition, recording artists may derive income from live performances, the sale of
merchandise, and other sources.
338
From Physical Formats to Downloads to Streaming a.
In recent years there has been a profound shift in the way music is consumedfrom
purchases of physical albums, to downloads of digital singles, to on-demand access
through digital streaming services. These shifts in music consumption patterns have led
to corresponding changes in the relative mix of income streams to copyright ownersin
particular, an increased reliance on performance royalties as compared to reproduction
and distribution royalties.
339
For example, the below charts from the RIAA illustrate the shift from U.S. physical sales
to digital downloads and other sources of revenue from 2004 to 2013. They reflect
remarkable change in less than a decade:
340
338
Under so-called “360” record deals, artists may be required to share a portion of these
additional revenues with their label. See Doug Bouton, Note, The Music Industry in Flux: Are 360
Record Deals the Saving Grace or the Coup de Grace?, 9 V
A. SPORTS & ENT. L.J. 312, 318 (2010).
339
See, e.g., IPAC First Notice Comments at 13 (observing that “the decline in revenue from
physical album sales, to downloads, and ultimately streaming, has drastically reduced the
income opportunities for songwriters and composers”); RIAA Second Notice Comments at 38
(“Songwriters and recording artists have become more dependent on performance revenue, but
that revenue is not sufficient on its own to sustain a livelihood.”).
340
See RIAA, A Fruitful Anniversary for iTunes, MUSIC NOTES BLOG (Apr. 25, 2013),
http://www.riaa.com/blog.php?content_selector=riaa-news-blog&blog_selector=A-Fruitful-
Anniversary-&blog_type=&news_month_filter=4&news_year_filter=2013 (providing 2004 chart);
RIAA First Notice Comments at 51 (providing 2013 chart). Charts reproduced with the
permission of RIAA.
70
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Other data from the RIAA show how streaming, in particular, has boomed in recent
years:
341
NMPA submitted data showing a similar shift.
342
In 2012, NMPA reported that 30% of
U.S. music publisher revenues came from performance royalties, 36% from mechanical
royalties, 28% from synch royalties, and 6% from other sources.
343
Two years later,
NMPA reported that 52% of music publisher revenues came from public performance
royalties, while only 23% came from mechanical royalties, 20% from synch licenses, and
5% from other sources.
344
Other recent sales data show that streaming is continuing its
surgeaccording to Nielsen, the number of on-demand streams in the United States
grew 54% from 2013 to 2014, with “over 164 billion songs streamed on-demand through
audio and video platforms.”
345
The meteoric rise of streaming has corresponded with a sharp decline in physical and
digital download sales. In 2014, according to Nielsen data, total U.S. album sales (in
both physical and digital formats) fell by 11.2%, and digital download sales decreased
341
RIAA First Notice Comments at 50. Chart reproduced with the permission of RIAA.
342
NMPA Second Notice Comments at 8 (citing sources).
343
Ed Christman, NMPA’s David Israelite to Congress: A More Efficient Mechanical Licensing System,
B
ILLBOARD (June 13, 2012), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/publishing/1093490/
nmpasdavid-israelite-to-congress-a-more-efficient-mechanical.
344
Press Release, NMPA, U.S. Music Publishing Industry Valued at $2.2 Billion (June 11, 2014),
available at https://www.nmpa.org/media/showrelease.asp?id=233.
345
NIELSEN, 2014 NIELSEN MUSIC U.S. REPORT, http://www.nielsen.com/content/dam/corporate/
us/en/public%20factsheets/Soundscan/2014-year-end-music-report.pdf.
71
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
12.5%, from the year before.
346
Of course, this has been accompanied by a
commensurate drop in mechanical revenues for music publishers and songwriters.
According to NSAI, “[m]any songwriters report a reduction of 60 to 70% or more” in
mechanical royalties, and those royalties “continue to decrease by an alarming rate.
347
Many believe that in the not-too-distant future, interactive streaming will eclipse digital
downloads to become the dominant means by which consumers access music.
348
Meanwhile, since the late 1990s, there has been a marked decline in industry revenues
overall.
349
RIAA observes that, since 1999, total U.S. recorded music retail revenues have
dropped about 53%.
350
As relative newcomer Spotify summed up the situation, “the
majority of revenue in the industry has evaporated.”
351
What is a matter of some debate among stakeholders, however, is the actual cause of this
striking decline. Some commenters view the reduction in overall revenue and creator
income as the result of ordinary market forces. For example, NAB suggested that
general market factorsincluding an extended recession, a decline in consumer
discretionary spending, and increased competition for consumers’ shrinking
entertainment budgets—have all contributed to reduced creator income.
352
Other
346
Id.; see also BMI Second Notice Comments at 16 (“[T]he instant availability to the public of the
widest possible choice of recorded music by means of streaming technology has come at the
expense of an accelerating drop-off in the sale of recordings (hard copies and downloads).”).
347
NSAI Second Notice Comments at 6.
348
See IFPI, DIGITAL MUSIC REPORT 2014, at 5, http://www.ifpi.org/downloads/Digital-Music-
Report-2014.pdf (“It is now clear that music streaming and subscription is a mainstream model
for our business.”); ASCAP First Notice Comments at 5-6 (stating that “digital music streaming
services account for an increasingly large portion of music revenues in the U.S.”);
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 22 (“The music marketplace changed rapidly from one
long dominated by the sale of physical products, to one in which digital downloads are the
primary means of acquiring ownership of copies. Now, it is changing again, and obtaining access
to music through streaming services is ascendant.”).
349
See Michael DeGusta, The REAL Death of the Music Industry, BUSINESS INSIDER (Feb. 18, 2011),
http://www.businessinsider.com/these-charts-explain-the-real-death-of-the-music-industry-2011-
2.
350
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 38.
351
How is Spotify contributing to the music business?, SPOTIFY, http://www.spotifyartists.com/
spotify-explained/#how-is-spotify-contributing-to-the-music-business (last visited Jan. 30, 2015)
(citing global data).
352
NAB First Notice Comments at 9-10.
72
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
stakeholders identified industry-specific market trends as a reason for the decline, such
as increased competition driving down the value of synch licenses.
353
Still others attribute at least a good portion of the decrease to the shift from album sales
to individual song purchases.
354
IPAC explained this dynamic in the context of
mechanical royalties:
Dramatically lower album sales is the primary market development that
has led to songwriters reporting significant income declines in recent
years. During the heyday of the CD, album cuts made almost as much
money in mechanical royalties as the most popular single on the CD.
Today’s music industry is seeing significantly fewer full album purchases
and significantly more individual song purchases. As a result,
mechanical royalty income generated from the songs on an album has
declined dramatically, leading to the decline in songwriter income.
355
But IPAC also observed that this trend has been exacerbated by the shift to streaming,
which it claims generates lower royalties for copyright owners,
356
a topic that is
addressed next.
Impact of Music Streaming Models b.
A major area of debate is whether digital music streaming services fairly compensate
rightsholders, particularly music publishers and songwriters. Digital streaming
providers assert that they provide copyright owners with entirely new revenue streams
by paying performance royalties to both sound recording and musical work owners for
353
LaPolt Second Notice Comments at 3 (“[W]hile synchronization licenses are more plentiful
than ever, these licenses are paying lower and lower rates per individual agreement for the
average songwriter.”); NMPA & HFA Second Notice Comments at 8 (noting that “increased
competition has driven down synch fees”); NSAI Second Notice Comments at 6 (“With hundreds
of television networks and online content providers compared to just a few years ago, more
synch licenses are issued, but for a much lower amount per use.”).
354
See CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at 60-62 (“The leading edge of the shift
was driven by unbundling of albums and the sale of singles. Consumers were no longer forced
to buy songs they did not want in order to get the ones they desired.”); Tr. at 274:01-12 (June 23,
2014) (Paul Fakler, NAB/Music Choice) (“Consumers no longer are forced to buy a bundled
album containing recordings that they don’t want to buy. So there are a lot of factors that have
gone into declines of record sales.”).
355
IPAC Second Notice Comments at 8; see also NSAI Second Notice Comments at 6 (“One major
reason is dramatically less income from album cuts not released as singles. A few years ago a
non-single cut on an album with high sales volume produced greater income for many
songwriters. Today album cuts, with a few rare exceptions, produce very little income.”).
356
IPAC Second Notice Comments at 8-9.
73
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
interactive and noninteractive services.
357
With respect to sound recording royalties
specifically, DiMA noted that “[d]igital radio alone paid out $590.4 million in royalties to
artists and rightsholders last year.”
358
Copyright owners, as well as the RIAA, acknowledge the increase in performance
royalties.
359
ASCAP and BMI in recent years have both announced record-high
collections and royalty distributions.
360
But notwithstanding the overall increase in
performance royalties, many copyright owners believe that “the downward spiral of
record sales and therefore artist and mechanical royalties has not yet been compensated
by the increase in streaming revenue.”
361
In other words, increases in performance
revenues have not made up for the dramatic decrease in sales.
Significantly, the leading interactive streaming audio service, Spotify, believes that the
rapid decline [in industry revenue] is not due to a fall in music consumption but to a
shift in music listening behavior towards formats that do not generate significant income
for artists.”
362
ASCAP observed that “technological developments have significantly
increased the use of musical works, yet significantly decreased the income earned by
songwriters.”
363
Songwriters increasingly worry about their income (or lack thereof)
357
DiMA First Notice Comments at 45 (“The substantial royalties paid by digital music services
constitute new revenue streams that were unimagined just a few decades ago.”).
358
Id.
359
RIAA First Notice Comments Ex. A at 1 (“In 2013, strong growth in streaming revenues
contributed to a US music industry that was stable overall at $7 billion for the fourth consecutive
year.”); see also IFPI, D
IGITAL MUSIC REPORT 2014, at 5 (“The US music market continued to
stabilize, growing slightly in trade revenue terms, helped by rising consumer demand for music
streaming services.”).
360
Ben Sisario, Collectors of Royalties for Music Publishers May See Better Results, N.Y. TIMES (Sept.
23, 2013), http://www.nytimes.com/2013/09/23/business/media/collectors-of-royalties-for-music-
publishers-may-see-better-results.html; Press Release, ASCAP Reports Strong Revenues in 2013,
ASCAP (Feb. 12, 2014), http://www.ascap.com/press/2014/0213-2013-financials.aspx.
361
ABKCO First Notice Comments at 5; see also, e.g., NMPA Second Notice Comments at 7 (noting
that “performance royalties are increasing in importance while mechanical income has
diminished. Almost all musical work owners are in agreement that this is the most challenging
aspect of the new digital marketplace”); RIAA Second Notice Comments at 38; ASCAP Second
Notice Comments at 23 (finding that “overall songwriter income has declined because
mechanical right income has dropped by a large margin”).
362
How is Spotify contributing to the music business?, SPOTIFY, http://www.spotifyartists.com/
spotify-explained/#how-is-spotify-contributing-to-the-music-business (last visited Jan. 30, 2015).
Spotify states, however, that its subscription service “aims to regenerate this lost value by
converting music fans from these poorly monetized formats to our paid streaming format, which
produces far more value per listener.” Id.
363
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 39.
74
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
from digital streaming services, especially those that they regard as poorly
monetized”—i.e., ad-supported services that do not require a subscription fee or
generate a large amount of advertising revenue.
A growing number of high-profile songwriter/artistsincluding Taylor Swift and Thom
Yorkeare leveraging their sound recording rights to remove their music from Spotify,
principally out of concern that Spotify’s free ad-supported tier of service does not fairly
compensate them for their songs.
364
As Swift put it succinctly: “I think that people
should feel that there is a value to what musicians have created, and that’s that.”
365
Songwriter concerns are vividly illustrated by the following tweet by Bette Midler:
Other songwriters have made similarly bleak claims.
366
For instance, the songwriter
Aloe Blacc recently reported:
364
Seabrook, Revenue Streams: Is Spotify the Music Industry’s Friend or Its Foe?; Stuart Dredge, Thom
Yorke Explains Why He Hates Spotify, B
USINESS INSIDER (Oct. 7, 2013), http://www.
businessinsider.com/thom-yorke-explains-why-he-hates-spotify-2013-10; Sasha Bogursky, Taylor
Swift, Garth Brooks and other artists lead the fight against Spotify, F
OX NEWS (Nov. 19, 2014),
http://www.foxnews.com/entertainment/2014/11/19/taylor-swift-garth-brooks-artists-lead-fight-
against-spotify/.
365
Jack Dickey, Taylor Swift on 1989, Spotify, Her Next Tour and Female Role Models, TIME (Nov. 13,
2014), http://time.com/3578249/taylor-swift-interview. In a similar move, GMR recently
demanded that YouTube remove videos from its service containing approximately 20,000 songs
that GMR represents, including the Eagles and Pharrell Williams. Eriq Gardner, Pharrell Williams’
Lawyer to YouTube: Remove Our Songs or Face $1 Billion Lawsuit, H
OLLYWOOD REPORTER (Dec. 22,
2014), http://www.hollywoodreporter.com/thr-esq/pharrell-williams-lawyer-youtube-remove-
759877.
366
See, e.g., Maya Kosoff, Pharell Made Only $2,700 In Songwriter Royalties From 43 Million Plays of
‘Happy’ On Pandora, B
USINESS INSIDER (Dec. 23, 2014), http://www.businessinsider.com/pharrell-
made-only-2700-in-songwriter-royalties-from-43-million-plays-of-happy-on-pandora-2014-12;
David Lowery, My Song Got Played On Pandora 1 Million Times and All I Got Was $16.89, Less Than
75
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Avicii’s release “Wake Me Up!” that I co-wrote and sing, for example, was
the most streamed song in Spotify history and the 13th most played song
on Pandora since its release in 2013, with more than 168 million streams
in the US. And yet, that yielded only $12,359 in Pandora domestic
royaltieswhich were then split among three songwriters and our
publishers. In return for co-writing a major hit song, I’ve earned less than
$4,000 domestically from the largest digital music service.
367
Notably, songwriters who are not also recording artists with some measure of control
over their recordings typically do not have the option to withdraw their works from
low-paying services, because—due to the combination of the section 115 compulsory
license and the ASCAP and BMI consent decreesthey have no choice other than to
permit the exploitation of their musical works by such providers. And even recording
artists cannot remove their music from noninteractive digital services like Pandora that
qualify for the section 112 and 114 compulsory licenses.
For their part, the digital music services deny that they are the cause of the decline in
songwriter income. These services note that they pay royalties for the public
performance of sound recordings, while terrestrial radio does not, and so the total
royalties they pay to both sound recording and musical work owners must be
considered.
368
Accordingly, Pandora challenged the numbers cited by Midler and Blacc
by publicizing the total amounts paid for all rights to perform the songs, including
sound recording rights—stating that they paid $6,400 in royalties in Midler’s case and
over $250,000 for the plays of “Wake Me Up!”.
369
Digital music services emphasize that they “pay the lion’s share of their revenues over to
rights owners,”
370
and suggest that the songwriter concerns are more accurately traced to
What I Make From a Single T-Shirt Sale!, TRICHORDIST (June 24, 2013), http://thetrichordist. com/
2013/06/24; Doug Gross, Songwriters: Spotify doesn’t pay off . . . unless you’re a Taylor Swift, CNN
(Nov. 13, 2014), http://www.cnn.com/2014/11/12/tech/web/spotify-pay-musicians (noting that the
songwriters of the Bon Jovi hit “Livin’ on a Prayer” split $110 in royalties from Pandora for 6.5
million plays of that song).
367
Aloe Blacc, Streaming Services Need to Pay Songwriters Fairly, WIRED (Nov. 5, 2014),
http://www.wired.com/2014/11/aloe-blacc-pay-songwriters.
368
DiMA First Notice Comments at 46.
369
Andy Gensler, Bette Midler Disparages Pandora, Spotify Over Artist Compensation, BILLBOARD
(Apr. 6, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/digital-and-mobile/6039697/bette-
midler-disparages-pandora-spotify-over-artist; Alison Kosik, The puzzling and ‘antiquated’ world of
music royalties, CNN
MONEY (Nov. 17, 2014), http://money.cnn.com/2014/11/17/media/aloe-blacc-
music-royalties.
370
DiMA First Notice Comments at 46; see also Glenn Peoples, Pandora Revenue Up 40 Percent,
Listening Growth Softens, B
ILLBOARD (Oct. 23, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/
76
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
the division of total royalties between sound recording owners and musical work
owners.
371
From the servicesperspective, total content costs are the relevant
consideration. They assert that they are “agnostic” as to how that total is divided among
various rightsholders.
372
Digital music services and broadcasters also contend that, to the extent individual
creators believe they are not receiving adequate income, the blame might lie with
intermediaries. DiMA stated that “there is little transparency about what happens to the
significant royalties generated from digital music services after they are paid to record
labels, music publishers, and PROs, and processed under the financial terms of
recording artists’ and songwriters’ own private arrangements with rightsowners.”
373
DiMA thus alleged that, rather than being paid out to individual creators, “a significant
portion of the royalties received are retained by [intermediaries] for their own account,
or applied toward the recoupment of advances paid to recording artists and
songwriters.”
374
SAG-AFTRA and AFM, which represent individual artists, expressed a
similar worry that direct licensing deals “can create uncertainty regarding which
benefits of the deal are subject to being shared with Artists at all.” They noted in
particular that “[d]irect license deals increasingly have been reported to include
‘breakage’—advance payments or guaranteed payments in excess of the per-
performance royalty earned under the licenseequity shares, promotion or other non-
usage based elements” and that even if such amounts are shared with artists, they “may
digital-and-mobile/6296383/pandora-revenue-up-40-percent-listening-growth-softens (noting
Pandora pays 46.5% of its revenues in royalties to copyright owners).
371
See DiMA First Notice Comments at 11 (“[M]uch of the current debate over rates stems from
disagreement among the labels, publishers and PROs about how to allocate the content owners’
fixed share of the pie, rather than from a notion that service providers are not paying enough, in the
aggregate, for content.”).
372
See Tr. at 193:13-18 (June 4, 2014) (Scott Sellwood, Google/YouTube) (“[I]f there could be some
agreement between publishers and labels as to total content cost, we don’twe’re very agnostic,
we don’t care whether it’s a performance or a reproduction, tell us how much it costs.”); accord Tr.
at 112:02-113:08 (June 17, 2014) (Vickie Nauman, CrossBorderWorks) (“[Third-party technology
developers’] incentives are not to solve the problems between the publishers and the labels and
the PROs . . . [T]hey want to know that they can come to a simple source and pay for the rights.”).
373
DiMA First Notice Comments at 47.
374
Id.; see also NAB First Notice Comments at 10-12 (“To the extent recording artists have not been
adequately sharing in the new revenue streams from on-demand streaming services . . . it is likely
due to these same creative accounting schemes that the record companies have employed for
decades to underpay artists.”).
77
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
be subject to recoupment and less transparent than payments under the compulsory
license.”
375
Non-Performing Songwriters c.
While all creators have been affected by the shift from full-album sales to digital
streaming models, songwriters who are not also performing artists appear to have been
especially hard hit. Unlike songwriter-artists, “pure” songwriters who write works for
others to perform do not have the potential to make up for lost income through touring
or merchandise sales.
According to NSAI, since 2000, the number of full-time songwriters in Nashville has
fallen by 80%.
376
NSAI further observes that two decades ago, there were some 3,000 to
4,000 publishing deals available for songwriters in Nashville; that number has since
dropped to 300 to 400.
377
A publishing deal is crucial, as it “essentially pays a songwriter
an annual salary to write songs.”
378
Without such a deal, it may be impossible for a
songwriter to finance his or her creative efforts. A recent article in The Tennessean
concludes that the result of the shift away from album sales to streaming “has been the
collapse of Nashville’s musical middle class.”
379
Additional Considerations d.
Piracy
In addition, a broad range of stakeholders—with the exception of the CFA and Public
Knowledge
380
—pointed to piracy as a continuing challenge that depresses revenues for
both legal music providers and rightsholders. But piracy was not a significant focus of
discussion. Unlike in the Napster era, stakeholders now seem resigned to this
marketplace condition and the perhaps irreversible impact it has had on the industry.
RIAA—which abandoned its lawsuits against individual file-sharers several years
ago
381
observed that piracy “certainly is in the background when you talk about
whether digital music services are earning enough money or paying enough money,
375
SAG-AFTRA & AFM Second Notice Comments at 2.
376
Rau, Nashville’s musical middle class collapses.
377
NSAI Second Notice Comments at 6.
378
Rau, Nashville’s musical middle class collapses.
379
Id.
380
CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at 70 (“In today’s music market, the claim
that piracy is still a problem is contradicted by a great deal of evidence on actual consumer
behavior.”).
381
David Kravets, Copyright Lawsuits Plummet in Aftermath of RIAA Campaign, WIRED (May 18,
2010), http://www.wired.com/2010/05/riaa-bump/.
78
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
[and] competing against free remains a problem.”
382
DiMA agreed that “the truth is that
any legitimate digital service right now competes with free.”
383
This sentiment was
echoed by Spotify as well: “We are competing with piracy. It’s a reality that we all face
on every level of the ecosystem. We are all competing with free.”
384
Impact of DMCA Safe Harbors
While piracy may now be considered as an accepted background fact, the same cannot
be said of the DMCA safe harbors, codified in section 512 of the Copyright Act, which
remain highly controversial. Section 512 curtails liability for online providers for
infringing user-posted content provided that they remove such content expeditiously in
response to a copyright owner’s takedown notice.
385
Although the operation of the
DMCA safe harbors is beyond the scope of this study, the Office briefly notes these
DMCA concerns since they were so frequently expressed.
386
Many copyright owners blame the DMCA’s safe harbor regime for allowing digital
providers the opportunity to profit from the unauthorized use of copyrighted music
without paying licensing fees.
387
One composer, Hélène Muddiman, likened the
situation to a company giving away someone else’s CDs at a fairground and making
money by advertising to the people in line.
388
Music publisher Jason Rys contended that
382
Tr. at 98:02-04 (June 24, 2014) (Susan Chertkoff, RIAA); see also RIAA Second Notice Comments
at 6 (It remains a problem that the legitimate market for licensed musical works must operate in
an environment in which there is also a huge amount of infringing use.”).
383
Tr. at 111:09-11 (June 24, 2014) (Lee Knife, DiMA).
384
Id. at 122:01-04 (James Duffett-Smith, Spotify).
385
17 U.S.C. § 512(c); DMCA § 202(a).
386
In a separate public process, the Department of Commerce’s Internet Policy Task Forceled
by the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (“USPTO”) and the National Telecommunications and
Information Administration (“NTIA”)has, in keeping with its July 2013 Green Paper,
established a “multi-stakeholder” dialogue on “improving the operation of the notice and
takedown system for removing infringing content from the Internet under the DMCA.” See
Request for Comments on Department of Commerce Green Paper, Copyright Policy, Creativity,
and Innovation in the Digital Economy, 78 Fed. Reg. 61,337, 61,338 (Oct. 3, 2013); see also
D
EPARTMENT OF COMMERCE INTERNET POLICY TASK FORCE, COPYRIGHT POLICY, CREATIVITY, AND
INNOVATION IN THE DIGITAL ECONOMY 54 (2013) (“GREEN PAPER”), available at http://www.uspto.
gov/news/publications/copyrightgreenpaper.pdf. The Office will be interested to see the results
of that process.
387
See Lincoff First Notice Comments at 9.
388
Tr. at 136:10-139:05 (June 17, 2014) (Hélène Muddiman, Hollywood Elite Composers); see also
Zoë Keating, What should I do about Youtube?,
ZOEKEATING.TUMBLER.COM (Jan. 22, 2015)
http://zoekeating.tumblr.com/post/108898194009/what-should-i-do-about-youtube (describing
YouTube’s negotiating tactics for licenses covering its new subscription service, which include
79
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
“due to the DMCA there’s nothing you can realistically do to stop your songs from
appearing on YouTube.”
389
In addition to complaining that the notice and takedown regime created under the
DMCA results in an impossible game of “whack-a-mole”since removed content is
frequently reposted, requiring the owner to serve another takedown notice
390
some
stakeholders also point out that the digital companies’ ability to exploit infringing
content unless and until a notice is sent affords these providers significant added
leverage in licensing negotiations, since content owners must either agree to a license or
devote significant resources to an unending takedown process. This dynamic, in turn, is
thought to have a “depressive effect” on royalty rates.
391
For their part, digital services stress the considerable effort that is required to respond to
copyright owners slew of takedown notices. The number of takedown requests
submitted to Google, for example, continues to climb and suggests a staggering amount
of online infringement. In 2010, Google received approximately 3 million DMCA
takedown requests; in 2014, that number was 345 million—over 940,000 takedown
requests every day.
392
excluding artists from YouTube’s revenue-sharing program if the artist declines to license their
works for the subscription service).
389
Tr. at 228:08-10 (June 16, 2014) (Jason Rys, Wixen Music Publishing); see also Tr. at 119:10-21
(June 24, 2014) (Dick Huey, Toolshed Inc.) (The DMCA is “a defense that’s used by the largest
tech companies in some cases to avoid direct licensing.”).
390
Audiosocket First Notice Comments at 1; Buckley Second Notice Comments at 4; DotMusic
First Notice Comments at 8.
391
BMI First Notice Comments at 28-29 (“Another explanation [for reduced songwriter, composer
and recording artist income] is the depressive effect of the [DMCA] safe harbors, which shield
Internet service providers . . . from liability for certain user activities.”). To cite a recent example,
Irving Azoff of GMR recently threatened litigation against YouTube for the unauthorized
performances of his clients’ music, explaining that “they are the ones that have been least
cooperative and the company our clients feel are the worst offenders.” Gardner, Pharrell
Williams’ Lawyer to YouTube: Remove Our Songs or Face $1 Billion Lawsuit. GMR’s apparent position
is that if YouTube is able to identify music for the purpose of monetizing it through its Content
ID system, it should also be able to take it down without the service of individual takedown
notices. Id.
392
Joe Mullin, Google Handled 345 Million Copyright Takedowns in 2014, ARSTECHNICA (Jan. 6,
2015), http://arstechnica.com/tech-policy/2015/01/google-handled-345-million-copyright-
takedowns-in-2014; Section 512 of Title 17: Hearing Before the Subcomm. On Courts, Intell. Prop., and
the Internet of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 113th Cong. 47 (2014) (Statement of Katherine Oyama,
Sr. Policy Counsel, Google Inc.).
80
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
2. Disparate Treatment of Analogous Rights and Uses
Closely tied to the issue of fair compensation is the disparate legal treatment of sound
recordings and musical works, both vis-à-vis each other and across different delivery
platforms. Many participants regard these disparities as unwarranted, and blame them
for the unfairness and inefficiency in the music licensing system.
Inconsistent Ratesetting Standards a.
As explained above, ratesetting standards under the statutory licenses and consent
decrees differ based on the right and use at issue. The CRB establishes rates for
mechanical reproductions of musical works under section 115 under the four-factor,
public policy-oriented standard in section 801(b)(1) of the Copyright Act.
393
Under the
ASCAP and BMI consent decrees, the rate courts establish rates for the public
performance of musical works under a “fair market value” analysis which attempts to
determine the price that a willing buyer and willing seller would agree to in an arm’s
length transaction, but gives substantial weight to antitrust concerns.
394
As also described above, rates for the digital performance of sound recordings under
section 114 are set under different standards, depending on the type of use. Royalty
rates for a limited set of older servicesSirius XM, as the only preexisting satellite
service, and Music Choice and Muzak, as the only preexisting subscription services—are
governed by the same four-factor standard in section 801(b)(1) as mechanical
reproductions of musical works subject to compulsory licensing under section 115.
395
Meanwhile, royalty rates for all internet radio and newer noninteractive subscription
services, and for all ephemeral recordings under section 112 regardless of the type of
service, are established under the so-called “willing buyer/willing seller” standard,
which many believe yields more market-oriented rates than those established under
section 801(b)(1).
396
Most stakeholders seem to acknowledge that it is problematic for the law to impose
differing ratesetting standards, especially for businesses that provide similar services.
397
393
17 U.S.C. § 801(b)(1).
394
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 25 (quoting United States v. BMI (Music Choice II), 316 F.3d
189, 194 (2d Cir. 2003)); ASCAP v. MobiTV, Inc., 681 F.3d 76, 82 (2d Cir. 2012) (stating that “the
rate-setting court must take into account the fact that ASCAP, as a monopolist, exercises market-
distorting power in negotiations for the use of its music”).
395
See 17 U.S.C. §§ 114(f)(1), 801(b)(1).
396
See id. §§ 112(e)(4), 114(f)(2)(B).
397
See, e.g., SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 6-8, 14-16; DiMA First Notice Comments at
40; RIAA First Notice Comments at 30-32; CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at
23-26; Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 3; NARAS First Notice Comments at 8-9.
81
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
As DiMA noted, “[t]he ‘playing field’ regarding ratesetting standards is not level, and
the result is fundamental inequity.”
398
Depending upon whether they wish to see higher
or lower royalty rates, however, these same stakeholders disagree as to which ratesetting
standard should apply.
Music services and public interest groups support adoption of the 801(b)(1) standard for
all statutory licenses, as the standard more likely to produce lower rates. Public
Knowledge and CFA, for example, opined that the 801(b)(1) standards balancing of
policy considerations and focus on “creating economic incentives with the ultimate
purpose of encouraging artists and platforms to create new works and bring those
works to market” better aligns with the constitutional purpose of copyright law.
399
Similarly, Sirius XM pointed out that the 801(b)(1) standard provided more “latitude to
consider the enumerated policy factors, including recognizing the ‘relative
contributions’ of technological pioneers, and ensuring that both copyright owners and
users are treated fairly.”
400
It also noted that rates set under this standard have proven
less susceptible to legal challenge or congressional modification.
401
Taking a somewhat different tack, DiMA criticized the willing buyer/willing seller
standard forrequir[ing] judges to set a rate based solely on marketplace benchmarks,”
wherethere is very little record evidence of market rates for directly licensed internet
radio services that are not tied to a separate rights grant for additional service types and
functionalities (such as direct licenses for interactive services).”
402
In a related vein,
Spotify noted that under the willing buyer/willing seller standard, benchmark rates
proffered by licensees “are often premised on the agreements entered into by only the
largest of licensors . . . [who] demand ‘Most Favored Nations’ provisions to ensure that
only the highest rates are utilized in the market as opposed to rates that would arise
from true free market negotiations.”
403
In contrast, copyright owners and their representatives support the adoption of the
willing buyer/willing seller standard for all rates across the board. They posit that the
willing buyer/willing seller standard is fairer to music owners and creators, who cannot
opt out of compulsory licenses.
404
BMI stated that it is “simple and self-evident” that
398
DiMA First Notice Comments at 40.
399
CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at 24-25.
400
Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 13.
401
Id. at 14-15.
402
DiMA First Notice Comments at 36 (emphasis in original).
403
Spotify First Notice Comments at 7.
404
See, e.g., NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 8, 15-16; Wixen First Notice Comments at 2;
BMI First Notice Comments at 3; IPAC First Notice Comments at 6; NARAS First Notice
Comments at 1; Tr. at 292:17-20 (June 24, 2014) (Peter Brodsky, Sony/ATV).
82
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
creators should be paid at a fair market value rate.
405
Sony/ATV argued that the
801(b)(1) standard “creates artificially deflated rights,” whereas a willing buyer/willing
seller standard “will create fair market value” for copyright owners.
406
In sum,
copyright owners strongly object to a ratesetting standard that does not aspire to free-
market rates.
In this regard, a number of copyright owners, including NMPA, ASCAP, BMI, SESAC,
and NARAS, expressed support for the Songwriter Equity Act (“SEA”), proposed
legislation that would change the ratesetting criteria applicable to section 115 from the
801(b)(1) formula to the willing buyer/willing seller standard.
407
Different Ratesetting Bodies b.
Another disparity in the ratesetting process involves the bodies that oversee the
ratesetting proceedings. As discussed above, antitrust consent decrees entered into with
the DOJ by ASCAP and BMI dictate that rates for the public performance of musical
works administered by those PROs be overseen by two judges of the U.S. District Court
for the Southern District of New York that sit as rate courts for the respective consent
decrees. Antitrust concerns play a dominant role in the setting of these rates.
408
In
contrast, the CRB, which sets rates for the statutory licenses in sections 112, 114, and 115,
does not set rates with antitrust concerns specifically in mind.
409
Instead, the CRB is
designed to be an expert ratesetting body, and to bring to bear “a significant mastery of
economics and marketplace factors as well as considerable knowledge of copyright
law.”
410
A number of stakeholders criticized this divided ratesetting regime. Licensees pointed
out that similar services must petition different bodies to obtain the rights necessary to
engage in a single activity—for example, interactive streaming—leading to increased
costs. When rates are set by different bodies at different times, there is a question as to
405
BMI First Notice Comments at 3.
406
Tr. at 291:04-07 (June 24, 2014) (Peter Brodsky, Sony/ATV).
407
SEA, H.R. 4079, 113th Cong. (2014); see also Songwriter Equity Act Gains Support in Congress,
BMI, http://www.bmi.com/news/entry/songwriter_equity_act_gains_support_in_congress (last
visited Jan. 30, 2015). The SEA would also eliminate the current prohibition in section 114(i) that
prohibits the PRO rate courts from considering sound recording performance rates in
establishing the performance royalties due for musical works.
408
BMI v. DMX, 683 F.3d at 49.
409
Indeed, as noted, Congress provided copyright owners and users with an antitrust exemption
to allow those groups to engage in collective negotiation of rates under the statutory licenses. See
17 U.S.C. §§ 112(e)(2); 114(e)(1), 115(c)(3)(B).
410
H.R. REP. NO. 108-408, at 25; see generally 17 U.S.C. § 802(a).
83
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
how to adjust and harmonize the different rates.
411
Others raised fundamental structural
and procedural concerns, such as the propriety of a single district court being tasked
with an ongoing economic responsibility it is not specifically designed to handle, in
comparison to a dedicated tribunal such as the CRB. Bob Kohn, author of a well-known
treatise on music licensing, noted that “rate court proceedings have morphed from the
nature of a fairness hearing for proposed rates to an actual rate setting process—
something which the courts are not equipped to do, especially without jurisdiction over
rate setting for mechanical reproductions of musical works and transmissions of sound
recordings.”
412
Music services fear that fragmented consideration of royalty rates across different
ratesetting bodies can lead to unsustainable results.
413
On this point, a representative
from Spotify stated:
One thing that is absolutely essential, though, is that any rate setting
standard is not looked at in a vacuum. . . . If we have an increase in
publishing rates, for example, that go up beyond, much higher than they
are at the moment, then we could be in a situation where we pay out
more than one hundred percent of our revenue, which is unsustainable.
414
Adding to general concerns about disparate ratesetting processes is the fact that section
114(i) of the Copyright Act prevents the PRO rate courts from considering fees set by the
CRB for digital performance of sound recordings, thus further encouraging
balkanization.
415
Recognizing the shortcomings inherent in the current divided approach, some
participants proposed unifying ratesetting proceedings for music licensing in a single
body, observing that this could also lead to cost savings through the elimination of
duplicative proceedings.
416
411
Tr. at 237:08-21 (June 16, 2014) (Gary R. Greenstein, Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati).
412
Kohn First Notice Comments at 12.
413
Tr. at 194:05-18 (June 4, 2014) (Scott Sellwood, Google/YouTube) (“[T]he main concern for us
that comes from fragmentation is an incremental creep in total content cost from which we can’t
really sustain the business.”). RIAA, however, likened this concern to “saying if Dunkin’ Donuts
finds out that the price of coffee is going up that now they are going to tell their flour supplier
that they are going to pay less.” Tr. at 98:12-19 (June 24, 2014) (Susan Chertkoff, RIAA).
414
Tr. at 258:01-14 (June 23, 2014) (James Duffett-Smith, Spotify).
415
See NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 21-22; BMI First Notice Comments at 12; SESAC
First Notice Comments at 3-5; NARAS First Notice Comments at 4; CTIA First Notice Comments
at 11-12; Tr. at 268:11-269:14 (June 16, 2014) (Timothy A. Cohan, PeerMusic).
416
See FMC First Notice Comments at 4 (suggesting that “it may be more useful to have
arbitration and dispute resolution mechanisms take place under the same court, perhaps the
84
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Pre-1972 Sound Recordings c.
As explained above, legal uncertainties surround state law protection for pre-1972 sound
recordings. This has led digital music providers to take different approaches as to the
payment of royalties for the streaming of pre-1972 sound recordingssome pay, and
some do not. In recent months, questions of whether and how to pay for such uses have
become more immediate due to judicial decisions in California and New York upholding
the right of pre-1972 sound recording owners to collect for performances of their
works—and additional lawsuits are pending.
417
As a general matter, some stakeholders support the full federalization of sound
recordingsi.e., the total inclusion of pre-1972 sound recordings within the federal
Copyright Act, subject to existing exceptions and limitations—while others have favored
a more limited solution that would, for example, provide a payment mechanism under
the section 112 and 114 licenses for noninteractive digital services with a safe harbor
from state liability. In addition, it seems that some parties, particularly digital music
services, might be content to operate without a federal statutory obligation to
compensate pre-1972 sound recording owners. But these stakeholders at least
acknowledge that a federal licensing scheme would be preferable to obtaining direct
licenses under scattered state laws for each sound recording performed, which is no
longer merely a hypothetical scenario.
418
Full Federalization Considerations
Full federalizationmeans that the rights and limitations in the Copyright Act
applicable to post-1972 sound recordings, including fair use and the DMCA safe harbors,
would also apply to pre-1972 sound recordings.
419
The Copyright Office’s 2011 report on
the treatment of pre-1972 recordings recommends full federalization (though with
termination rights limited to post-federalization grants). Specifically, the Office
concluded that this approach would “improve the certainty and consistency of copyright
law, will likely encourage more preservation and access activities, and should not result
in any appreciable harm to the economic interests of right holders.
420
Copyright Royalty Board”); Lincoff First Notice Comments at 4-11 (proposing a unified “digital
transmission right” encompassing rights of musical works and sound recording owners with
rates set by the CRB).
417
The decisions came down shortly after the close of the record in this study, so it is possible that
stakeholders’ positions as to how our licensing system should handle pre-1972 recordings have
evolved somewhat from their earlier expressed views.
418
See, e.g., DiMA First Notice Comments at 39; Music Choice First Notice Comments at 13-16.
419
See PRE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT at ix.
420
Id.
85
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
A range of study participants agree with the Office’s view.
421
The prospect of receiving
federally required compensation for pre-1972 exploitations is a driver for some; NARAS,
which largely agreed with the Office’s findings, observed that “older artists, who
contributed greatly to our nation’s cultural legacy, often rely on their recordings as their
sole source of income.”
422
Others consider access to the full spectrum of the Copyright
Act’s rights and limitations to be an important element of any solution. Some creators of
pre-1972 sound recordings, for instance, believe they should have access to federal
termination rights.
423
The Library of Congress (which submitted comments as an
interested party) worried that preserving “millions of historic music and sound
recordings” will be impossible under the current regime, where “pre-1972 recordings
are subject to a variety of disparate state laws and state common law that . . . lack
statutory language to exempt archival copying for preservation purposes.”
424
Others,
including digital music services, feel strongly that the fair use doctrine and DMCA safe
harbor provisions should apply to pre-1972 recordings.
425
Partial Federalization Alternative
Supporters of partial federalization, while open to consideration of a broader solution,
believe that a measure requiring compensation for use of pre-1972 sound recordings
421
See, e.g., Kernochan Center Second Notice Comments at passim; Brigham Young University
Copyright Licensing Office (“BYU”) First Notice Comments at 3; FMC First Notice Comments at
8-10; Kohn First Notice Comments at 14-15; Library of Congress First Notice Comments at 2-4;
Public Knowledge Second Notice Comments at 3-5; Tr. at 164:22-165:02 (June 17, 2014) (Eric
Harbeson, Music Library Association).
422
NARAS First Notice Comments at 6.
423
See, e.g., id. at 7-8; Tr. at 154:11-21 (June 5, 2014) (Robert Meitus, Meitus Gelbert Rose LLP); see
also P
RE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT at 148-49 (recommending against federal termination
rights to existing grants, but supporting such rights for grants made after effective date of
federalization legislation). With respect to older recordings that fall within the scope of federal
protection, one participant suggested providing authors of sound recordings with the
opportunity to recapture their creations if the record labels stop exploiting the works
commercially. Rinkerman Second Notice Comments at 2. According to the proposal, these rights
would incentivize the continued availability of works and prevent works from languishing in
limbo based on perceptions of marketability. Id. RIAA responded that, since digital music
platforms make it easier to re-issue obscure recordings without the costs associated with physical
distribution, owners do not need additional incentive to exploit commercially viable works under
their control. Tr. at 211:16-212:09 (June 24, 2014) (Susan Chertkof, RIAA).
424
Library of Congress First Notice Comments at 2-3.
425
DiMA First Notice Comments at 39; BYU First Notice Comments at 3. Though DiMA “takes
no view” on the federalization issue, it claims that, to the extent Congress considers incorporating
pre-1972 sound recordings into federal copyright law, such a change should be “absolute and
full.” Tr. at 157:05-18 (June 5, 2014) (Lee Knife, DiMA).
86
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
should be enacted in the near term.
426
SoundExchange explained that full federalization
“would raise a number of complicated issues,” but resolving those issues should not
delay providing legacy artists with fair compensation for the use of their works.
427
SoundExchange noted in particular that “the artists who created pre-1972 recordings are
especially dependent on digital revenue streams, because they are often less likely than
more current artists to be able to generate significant income from touring, product sales
and other sources.”
428
For those who support such an approach, obtaining royalties
from digital performance services is of primary importance and partial federalization
should be implemented as a short-term solution while issues of full federalization
continue to be debated.
429
Accordingly, some stakeholders advocated for Congress to simply expand the section
112 and 114 statutory licensing scheme to encompass pre-1972 sound recordings.
According to these parties, bringing pre-1972 sound recordings within the scope of
federal copyright protection in this manner would supply digital music services with an
easy means to offer lawful public performances of those recordings while generating
new sources of revenue for copyright owners.
430
Proponents of partial federalization
have supported Congress’ adoption of the Respecting Senior Performers as Essential
Cultural Treasures Act (otherwise known as the “RESPECT Act), legislation introduced
in 2014 that would extend the section 112 and 114 licenses to cover pre-1972 recordings
but at the same time provide protection from state law liability for such uses.
431
Terrestrial Radio Exemption d.
As explained above, current law does not require traditional terrestrialor “over-the-
air”—radio broadcasters to compensate sound recording owners for the public
performance of their recordings.
432
Digital music services, by contrast, must pay both
sound recording owners and musical work owners for performances. The Copyright
Office has long supported a full public performance right for sound recordings.
Recording artists and record labels argue that they are entitled to compensation from
terrestrial radio stations in the same way that songwriters and publishers receive
426
See, e.g., A2IM First Notice Comments at 7-8; ABKCO First Notice Comments at 3; RIAA First
Notice Comments at 32-33; see also NARAS First Notice Comments at 6-8 (supporting partial
federalization as a “stop gap”).
427
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 11-13.
428
Id. at 11-12.
429
Tr. at 180:11-14 (June 24, 2014) (Casey Rae, FMC).
430
See LaPolt First Notice Comments at 10 (“Recording artists with pre-1972 recordings were
denied an estimated $60 million in royalties in 2013 alone.”).
431
RESPECT Act, H.R. 4772, 113th Cong. (2014).
432
17 U.S.C. §§ 106(4), 106(6), 114(a).
87
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
compensation when their songs are played on the radio.
433
They characterize the
terrestrial broadcast exemption as an antiquated “loophole” that causes “glaring
inequity.”
434
They believe that the terrestrial radio industry does not adequately
compensate sound recording owners for helping to generate billions of dollars in annual
advertising revenues for radio services.
435
In this regard, they assert that the
promotional effect of radio airplay on record sales claimed by broadcasters is overstated,
and that sound recording owners should not be forced to forgo compensation in
exchange for the suggestion of promotional value.
436
In addition, copyright owners and digital streaming services together urge that current
law gives terrestrial radio unwarranted competitive advantage over new, innovative
entrants.
437
They note that wireless communications technologies have improved to the
point where digital services are competing directly with traditional terrestrial radio, and
consumers are using the same devices to receive digital and analog transmissions of the
same recordings.
438
As one participant put it, “[t]o me it seems obvious that having an
individual song play or performance on terrestrial radio in your car is fundamentally the
same as a satellite radio Sirius XM play in your car as is a Pandora stream via a wireless
cellphone tower through your car radio.
439
433
See SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 16 (“The rationale for requiring terrestrial radio
services to pay royalties to artists and copyright owners is the same as for all other platforms.”);
see also, e.g., A2IM First Notice Comments at 8; RIAA First Notice Comments at 30-31; SAG-
AFTRA & AFM First Notice Comments at 6.
434
See, e.g., SAG-AFTRA & AFM First Notice Comments at 6; SoundExchange First Notice
Comments at 16.
435
See A2IM First Notice Comments at 8 (AM/FM broadcasters make billions selling ads to folks
who tune in for our music while our sound recording creators get nothing.”); NARAS First
Notice Comments at 9 (Broadcast radio is the only industry in America that bases its business on
using the intellectual property of another without permission or compensation.”); SAG-AFTRA &
AFM First Notice Comments at 6 (“Radio has built a $15 billion industry based primarily on the
exploitation of the creative work of Artists, and should finally be required to fairly compensate
those Artists.”).
436
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 16; LaPolt First Notice Comments at 6.
437
DiMA First Notice Comments at 40-41; FMC First Notice Comments at 15; RIAA First Notice
Comments at 30-31; Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 2-4; see also Copyright Alliance First
Notice Comments at 2.
438
Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 3-4; see also DiMA First Notice Comments at 40-41 (noting
that “platform distinctions do not make sense in the digital environment where the very same
consumer electronics devicessuch as automobile in-dash receiversare capable of receiving
digital and/or analog transmissions of the same sound recording”).
439
Geo Music Group & George Johnson Music Publ’g at 13.
88
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Predictably, terrestrial broadcasters opposed a new requirement to pay performance
royalties for sound recordings, likening such payments to a “tariff” aimed at subsidizing
the recording industry.
440
They state that the terrestrial broadcast exemption represents
a “reciprocal dynamicby which “record labels and performing artists profit from the
free exposure and promotion provided by radio airplay, while local radio stations
receive revenues from advertisers that purchase airtime to sell their products and
services.”
441
As evidence of the high promotional value of broadcast radio, they point
out that record companies spend millions of dollars annually trying to persuade radio
stations to play or promote their recordings.
442
Foreign performance royalties are an important consideration in this debate. Virtually
all industrialized nations recognize a more robust sound recording performance right
than the United States; according to proponents of the right, the United States stands out
on the list of countries (among them Iran and North Korea) that do not.
443
Proponents
further point out that the terrestrial radio exemption prevents U.S. sound recording
owners and performers from collecting royalties for foreign radio broadcasts, as most
countries do not require payment of performance royalties to American sound recording
owners due to the lack of reciprocity.
444
According to one estimate, in addition to
forgone domestic royalties, U.S. sound recording owners are deprived of between $70
and $100 million in foreign royalties each year.
445
440
See NAB First Notice Comments at 29.
441
Id. at 28 (citing research indicating the promotional benefit provided to the recording industry
from free radio airplay ranges from $1.5 to $2.4 billion annually).
442
Id.; see also GAO REPORT at 50 (explaining that it is common for record companies to employ
independent promoters to encourage the broadcast industry to perform their songs).
443
See Tr. at 287:11-17 (June 23, 2014) (Blake Morgan, ECR Music Group and #IRespectMusic); The
Register’s Call for Updates to U.S. Copyright Law: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Courts, Intell. Prop.
and the Internet of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 113th Cong. 3 (2013) (“The Register’s Call for Updates
Hearing”) (statement of Rep. Melvin L. Watt) (“I think it is time, and the time is long overdue, for
Congress to recognize a performance right in sound recordings . . . . To not do so just prolongs
this longstanding inequity and keeps us out of pace with the international community.”);
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 16-17 (“The free ride given to terrestrial radio also
makes the U.S. an outlier internationally. At least 75 nations recognize some form of performance
right for terrestrial radio, and the U.S. is the only western industrialized nation that does not.”).
444
See, e.g., RIAA First Notice Comments at 30-31; FMC First Notice Comments at 14-15;
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 17.
445
See GAO REPORT at 30; see also Mary LaFrance, From Whether to How: The Challenge of
Implementing a Full Public Performance Right in Sound Recordings, 2 H
ARV. J. OF SPORTS & ENT. L.
221, 226 (2011).
89
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
For their part, broadcast industry representatives dispute the amount of foreign royalties
sound recording owners are unable to collect due to the lack of a terrestrial performance
right.
446
They posit that U.S. expansion of the performance right would be insufficient to
compel reciprocity, claiming that many foreign nations would continue to balk at paying
royalties unless the U.S. made other conforming changes to its law as well.
447
They also
maintain that many U.S. sound recording owners are already paid when their works are
performed abroad, as foreign collection societies are sometimes willing (or even
compelled) to pay for these uses.
448
B. Government’s Role in Music Licensing
1. PRO Consent Decrees
PROs, publishers, songwriters, and others criticized the ASCAP and BMI consent
decrees on many fronts, arguing that the 75-year-old regime is outdated,
449
that PROs
“can no longer meet the evolving needs of writers, publishers, music licensees and
446
NAB claims that proponents of reconciling international performance right laws have “failed
to substantiate the actual amount of revenue at issue.” NAB Second Notice Comments at 3. It
further asserts that, even if substantiated, “[t]he estimated . . . $70 million dollars in foreign
performance tariffs essentially constitute a rounding error to the major record companies.” NAB
First Notice Comments at 29 n.15.
447
NAB Second Notice Comments at 3 ([Proponents] also ignore the fact that many of these
foreign regimes are distinctly less generous to sound recordings in other respects. If the U.S. is to
adopt their regimes in one respect, presumably it should do so in others such as a much shorter
term of protection, no protections against anti-circumvention devices, and cultural and other
playlist quotas.”).
448
NAB alleges that “the U.K. adheres to ‘simultaneous publication rules, which grant U.S.
sound recordings the same rights as U.K. sound recordings when they are released in both
countries simultaneously,” though no evidence documenting that point was submitted during
the course of this study. NAB Second Notice Comments at 3-4; see also LaFrance, From Whether to
How: The Challenge of Implementing a Full Public Performance Right in Sound Recordings at 225
(explaining that “[i]n practice, many foreign collecting societies . . . have been willing to
reciprocate even before being legally required to do so,” but noting that laws and collecting
society practices are not identical and reciprocal arrangements are generally negotiated on a case-
by-case basis).
449
SGA First Notice Comments at 4; see also BMI First Notice Comments at 3 (noting that “the
decrees must be reviewed with an eye towards modernization”); LaPolt Second Notice
Comments at 15 (explaining that the consent decrees are “restrictive and outdated”); NSAI
Second Notice Comments at 6 (“Non-performing songwriters are threatened with extinction
under . . . the outdated ASCAP and BMI Consent Decree models.”); Wixen First Notice
Comments at 3 (ASCAP and BMI “cannot sufficiently represent songwriters’ interests while
operating under the outdated consent decrees.”).
90
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
ultimately the consumers,
450
and that while the “consent decrees were imposed to
protect against anticompetitive behavior, they are now used to distort and manipulate
the market for the benefit of a handful of powerful digital distribution companies that
are the gatekeepers between musics creators and those who want to enjoy that
music.”
451
Licensees and others, however, believe that the consent decrees are vital to
preventing anticompetitive conduct by the PROs and major publishers.
452
Some believe
that direct antitrust regulation should be extended even further, to encompass all
licensing of public performances of musical works.
453
As noted above, the DOJ is undertaking a review of the consent decrees to examine their
continued operation and effectiveness, and has solicited public comments, which reflect
many of the same concerns that the Office heard during this study.
454
While the DOJ is
focused on whether the consent decrees can or should be modified as a matter of
antitrust policy, this study examines the impact of the decrees on the music licensing
marketplace in general.
Royalty Rates a.
Under the consent decrees, any party may obtain permission from ASCAP or BMI to
perform musical works upon the submission of an application. If, after the application
450
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 3.
451
NMPA, Comments Submitted in Response to the DOJ’s Antitrust Consent Decree Review at 5
(Aug. 6, 2014), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/ascapbmi/comments/307900.pdf.
452
See, e.g., CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at 6 (“[T]he court’s ruling in [In re
Petition of Pandora Media] should put an end to the claims that these antitrust decrees are
‘obsolete’ or ‘outdated.’”); CTIA First Notice Comments at 6 (“[T]he decrees remain essential to
foster competitive market pricing for music performance rights.”); DiMA Second Notice
Comments at 16 (“[The PRO] collectives require government oversight . . . . [T]he natural
behavior for collectives and monopolies is to instinctively leverage their position and attempt to
extract supra-competitive rates and terms.”); FMC First Notice Comments at 6 (Even if the
consent decrees are examined regarding changes in the marketplace, “there would be no
compelling reason to completely eliminate the consent decrees and the important limitations they
place on PROs and publishers from engaging in anticompetitive behavior.”); RMLC First Notice
Comments at 5 (“[T]he pattern of price corrections and other decree enforcement measures
implemented by the federal judiciary following vigorously contested trials and appeals is
testimony to the continuing need for judicial supervision of ASCAP and BMI.”); TMLC First
Notice Comments at 5 (“[The] status quo requires, at the very least, maintaining constraints
protecting music users such as those provided for in the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees.”).
453
See, e.g., CTIA First Notice Comments at 6 (“Due to the nature of the markets, SESAC and the
major publishers also exercise substantial supra-competitive market power. That market power
should also be controlled.”).
454
Antitrust Consent Decree Review, U.S. DOJ, http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/ascap-bmi-decree-
review.html (last visited Jan. 30, 2015).
91
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
is received, the PRO and user cannot agree to the licensing fee, either may apply to the
applicable rate court for a determination of the rate.
In general, licensees expressed more confidence in the rate court process than did the
PROs and copyright owners. For instance, DiMA opined that the “time-tested”
ratesetting standards under the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees haveconsistently
established royalty rates that appropriately approximate the ‘fair market value’ of
particular licenses in different contexts.”
455
CTIA observed that the rate courts are
“essential to foster competitive market pricing for music performance rights.”
456
In contrast, PROs and copyright owners stated that the rate courts deflate public
performance royalties below their true market value.
457
Songwriters and publishers
believe that the rate court rates are inequitable to copyright owners, asserting that the
rates they set are “below-market,”
458
“unfair and unrealistic[],”
459
and “artificially
low.”
460
In support of these claims, several stakeholders pointed to the 12 to 1 (some say
14 to 1) discrepancy between the rates set by the CRB for the public performance of
sound recordings and rates set by rate courts for the public performance of musical
works.
461
Copyright owners complained that the “fair market value” standard employed by the
rate courts is inadequate, with a “lack of clarity regarding what factors the rate court
455
DiMA First Notice Comments at 30.
456
CTIA First Notice Comments at 6.
457
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 26 (Royalty rates are “set at rates below what the evidence
indicates are market levels.”); LaPolt First Notice Comments at 11 (“The compulsory rates set by
the rate courts for licenses are severely lower than their true market value.”); NARAS Second
Notice Comments at 2 (explaining that “recent rate court decisions made pursuant to the Consent
Decrees have resulted in royalty rates for digital music services that are below fair market
value).
458
BMI First Notice Comments at 9.
459
Council of Music Creators First Notice Comments at 5.
460
SCL First Notice Comments at 12.
461
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 29 n.45, 44 (“This almost 12-to-1 disparity in SoundExchange
and PRO payments is unprecedented in the global music marketplace.” ASCAP elsewhere notes
the ratio may be higher, citing a rate of “12 to 14 times greater.”) (citation omitted); BMI First
Notice Comments at 2 (finding that “recording artists are paid as much as . . . twelve times [what
songwriters and publishers are paid] for the public performance right.”); Music Managers’
Forum (“MMF”) & Featured Artists’ Coalition (“FAC”) Second Notice Comments at 10 (noting
“the price for musical compositions is disadvantaged by a factor of 10 or 12 to 1”); SESAC First
Notice Comments at 4 (referencing a ratio of 13:1); Tr. at 58:19-21 (June 17, 2014) (Gary R.
Greenstein, Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati) (referencing “14-to-1 fees to the sound recording
copyright owner versus the musical work copyright owner”).
92
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
should consider . . . and the weight given to those factors.”
462
A number of copyright
owners highlighted section 114(i), which precludes rate court consideration of rates set
for sound recording performances by the CRB, as one reason for below-value PRO
performance rates.
463
In addition, ASCAP objected thatneither ASCAP nor BMI are
free to refuse to license their repertories,” leading to a lack of “competitive market
transactions involving non-compelled sellers” to use as benchmarks for the government-
regulated rate.
464
Rate Court Proceedings b.
A common complaint about the rate court process is that it is expensive and time-
consuming.
465
Netflix observed that “both the substantial costs of litigation and the
business uncertainties inherent in court-determined approximations of what is a
competitive rate impose unnecessary risks and costs on all parties.”
466
Music Choice
complained that “costs are disproportionately burdensome on individual licensees,”
whereas a PRO can spread its costs across copyright owners.
467
But ASCAP observed,
ASCAP and applicants have collectively expended well in excess of one hundred
million dollars on litigation expenses related to rate court proceedings, much of that
incurred since only 2009.”
468
And attorney Christian Castle objected that “songwriters
did not ask for [the process], cannot escape it, and are forced to participate.”
469
462
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 24; see also SESAC First Notice Comments at 6 (“The consent
decrees . . . offer no definition or guidelines as to what constitutes ‘reasonable.’”).
463
See BMI First Notice Comments at 10 (“We believe that the prohibition against the PRO rate
courts considering the rates set for sound recordings provides in part an explanation for this
unintended disparity.”); see also ABKCO First Notice Comments at 2; ASCAP First Notice
Comments at 29-30.
464
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 25.
465
Id. at 3 (“Rate court proceedings have become extremely time and labor-intensive, costing the
parties millions in litigation expenses.”); BMI First Notice Comments at 8-9 (“Federal rate court
litigation is an exceptionally slow process to set prices to keep up with the rapidly-evolving
digital marketplace, and it is exceedingly expensive for all participants . . . .”); SESAC First Notice
Comments at 7 (“[T]he consent decrees . . . hold[] songwriters and music publisher royalties’
hostage to systematically protracted rate negotiations and expensive, time-consuming rate court
proceedings.”).
466
Netflix First Notice Comments at 6.
467
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 5.
468
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 23.
469
Castle First Notice Comments at 8.
93
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Federal copyright litigation is not only expensive but often lengthy,
470
and the rate courts
are no exception. According to BMI, “a typical rate court case can take many years to be
resolved, which includes the inevitable, potentially multi-year, appeal of the trial court’s
decision.”
471
ASCAP noted that although the consent decree “mandates that
proceedings must be trial-ready within one year of the filing of the initial petition, that
deadline is rarely met.”
472
As music attorney Dina LaPolt commented, the drawn-out
proceedings create the perception that rate courts “cannot keep up with the pace set by
the new digital marketplace.”
473
Interim Fees c.
Other concerns revolve around the fact that the rate for a particular license may not be
established until long after the licensee begins using musical works. The ASCAP and
BMI consent decrees allow music users to perform the PROs repertoire upon the mere
filing of an application for a license, without payment of any license fee.
474
As a general
matter, songwriters, publishers, and PROs found it unfair that “the current rate court
system . . . does not provide for an inexpensive, effective way to set interim fees to
compensate creators while the long rate-setting process plays out.”
475
This feature potentially exposes the PROs to gamesmanship by applicants, as “the
burden is on the PRO to make a motion for the imposition of an interim feea motion
that is, like the rate court proceeding itself, expensive and time-consuming.
476
As
ASCAP elaborated: “Even when an interim fee is paid, it is often at less than full value,”
leading many licensees to make “strategic choices to stay on interim terms until ASCAP
determines it must commence an expensive rate court proceeding.”
477
BMI observed
that “it is not unheard of for an applicant to go out of business before a fee is ever set; as
a result, the PROs (and, of course, in turn, our writers, composers and publishers) are
never compensated for the use of their valuable repertoires.
478
470
See U. S. COPYRIGHT OFFICE, COPYRIGHT SMALL CLAIMS 24-26 (2013), available at http://copyright.
gov/docs/smallclaims/usco-smallcopyrightclaims.pdf.
471
BMI First Notice Comments at 9.
472
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 22.
473
LaPolt Second Notice Comments at app. 4.
474
ASCAP First Notice Comment at 15; BMI First Notice Comment at 16.
475
BMI First Notice Comments at 3; see also LaPolt Second Notice Comments at app. 4 (noting that
“some licensees employ the rate court as a dilatory tactic to use performance licenses for a time
without having to compensate the PROs.”).
476
BMI First Notice Comments at 16.
477
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 16 & n.22.
478
BMI First Notice Comments at 17; see also ASCAP First Notice Comments at 15-16.
94
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Inconsistent Regulation of PROs d.
Yet another concern is the disparate treatment of entities that license performance rights.
The largest PROs, ASCAP and BMI, are subject to direct government oversight and
regulated pricing under the consent decrees. Other entities that represent significant
catalogs of works, however, such as SESAC and GMR—and major publishers, who may
withdraw from the PROs to license public performance rights directly—are not. Some
contend that the application of different rules to these different players creates an
unwarranted competitive imbalance and opportunities for regulatory arbitrage.
479
Licensees argued that SESAC, for example, has taken advantage of this discrepancy by
engaging in anticompetitive behavior that is prohibited under the consent decrees.
480
As
noted above, in 2014, RMLC and local television stations each separately sued SESAC
seeking antitrust relief.
481
RMLC argued that SESAC’s practices created “significant
overcharges to radio stations for their uses of SESAC music,”
482
while the local television
stations criticized SESAC for offering only a blanket license and refusing to provide
licensees with repertoire information.
483
These suits were both allowed to proceed after
479
SCL First Notice Comments at 12 (“Commercial entities like SESAC, startups like Azoff MSG
Entertainment [GMR] and a variety of foreign PROs are all competing for the opportunity to the
collect revenues of the music creators but unlike ASCAP and BMI, are not constrained by
antiquated regulations in their efforts to do so.”); Sarah Skates, Global Music Rights Has Growing
Roster, Negotiating Power, M
USIC ROW (Oct. 30, 2014), http://www.musicrow.com/2014/10/global-
music-rights-has-growing-roster-negotiating-power/ (opining that GMR “would likely have more
power than other PROs ASCAP and BMI when negotiating licenses on behalf of its members, due
to the fact that it would not be subject to the same regulatory agreements that govern the more
established organizations”).
480
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 10 (“Given the current state of SESAC’s repertory, the
same facts supporting the continued need for rate court regulation of ASCAP and BMI apply
equally to SESAC, and SESAC should be subject to the same regulation and rate court
supervision as the other PROs.”).
481
See RMLC v. SESAC, 29 F. Supp. 3d 487; Meredith Corp., 1 F. Supp. 3d 180.
482
RMLC First Notice Comments at 2.
483
TMLC First Notice Comments at 14; see also Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 6 (“[SESAC’s]
combination of concentrated ownership and either an unwillingness or inability to be transparent
as to what works are actually in the repertory creates a completely untenable situation.”).
95
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
the respective courts denied SESAC’s motions to dismiss.
484
(The parties to the New
York case brought by Meredith Corporation have since agreed to a settlement.
485
)
SESAC disagreed that it has a competitive advantage, instead contending that because
the industry . . . arose in a culture that assumes that the rates set by the rate courts are
accurate . . . SESAC must also accept those rates.”
486
And copyright owners suggested
that the rates obtained by SESAC and GMR outside of the consent decrees might be
useful as market benchmarks in rate court proceedings.
487
Even within the consent decree framework, there are regulatory discrepancies. The
ASCAP and BMI decrees are administered by different district court judges, and in the
past, there have been periods of time during which the ASCAP and BMI decrees
included significantly different terms.
488
The decrees are still not entirely aligned. For
example, the ASCAP consent decree expressly prohibits ASCAP from licensing any
rights other than public performance rights, while the BMI consent decree contains no
such provision. BMI has expressed the view that it may license other rights under its
consent decreebut has yet to do so.
489
In short, “[n]othing obligates the rate courts to
reach similar results on rate-setting or other issues.”
490
Parties’ Proposals e.
Stakeholders suggested a broad range of solutions to the perceived shortcomings of the
consent decrees governing ASCAP and BMI. The most salient proposals are discussed
below.
484
RMLC v. SESAC, 29 F. Supp. 3d at 500-03 (dismissing price fixing allegation, but allowing
monopoly claim to proceed); Meredith Corp. v. SESAC LLC, No. 09-cv-9177, 2011 WL 856266, at *1
(S.D.N.Y. Mar. 9, 2011) (denying motion to dismiss).
485
Memorandum of Law in Support of Plaintiffs’ Unopposed Motion for Preliminary Approval of
Settlement at 1-2, 5, Meredith Corp., 1 F. Supp. 3d 180 (No. 09-cv-9177). TMLC, which was not a
party to the litigation, was also a signatory to the settlement. Id. at 1 n.2.
486
Tr. at 61:04-11 (June 5, 2014) (Reid Alan Waltz, SESAC); see also Tr. at 58:20-59:03 (June 23, 2014)
(Bill Lee, SESAC) (“Although SESAC is not under a rate court, many rate court decisions do have
a negative impact on SESAC’s ability to modify license agreements. And ultimately it is the
creator, the songwriter, who suffers because of that lack of modernization.”).
487
Production Music Association Second Notice Comments at 5.
488
See generally RICHARD A. EPSTEIN, ANTITRUST CONSENT DECREES: IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
30-39 (2007) (“E
PSTEIN”) (describing differences between the decrees and concluding that the
consent decrees “did not keep ASCAP and BMI in parity at all times, so that differential
regulations governed key portions of their business”).
489
See BMI, Comments on Department of Commerce Green Paper at 4-5.
490
LaPolt First Notice Comments at 12.
96
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Complete or Partial Withdrawal of Rights
As discussed above, the ASCAP and BMI rate courts recently concluded that, under the
consent decrees, music publishers could not withdraw only “new media (i.e., digital
streaming) rights from the PROs to be licensed directly. As a result, the major
publishers have petitioned the DOJ seeking modification of the consent decrees to allow
for such partial withdrawals. As an alternative plan, major publishers are also
evaluating whether to withdraw their works entirely from the PROs and directly
negotiate public performance rates outside of the consent decree framework.
491
A broad range of stakeholders expressed serious apprehension about complete
publisher withdrawal, predicting “havoc” for the music industry.
492
BMI noted that
complete withdrawal “is potentially catastrophic for smaller publishers and songwriters
who depend on BMI for their livelihood, and for BMI’s hundreds of thousands of
customers who depend on BMI to fulfill their copyright obligations.
493
Significantly,
Martin Bandier, chairman and CEO of Sony/ATV—one of the major publishers
considering full withdrawalsimilarly predicted that if Sony/ATV found it necessary to
withdraw, such an outcome could be “catastrophic” for ASCAP and BMI.
494
Part of the concern is that many administrative costs of running a PRO, such as
negotiating licenses or monitoring radio stations, do not scale downward with a
reduction in revenues; a royalty check costs the same amount to process whether it is
large or small. ASCAP and BMI offset their administrative costs by charging a
commission (roughly 13% of royalties paid in both cases
495
). If major publishers were to
wholly withdraw, the commissions collected by the PROs from the substantial royalties
generated by those catalogs would no longer be available to defray fixed overhead
expenses. As a result, the remaining smaller members of these organizations would
have to shoulder the full administrative costs, likely through significantly higher
commissions.
496
Some commenters questioned whether the PROs would be able to
491
BMI First Notice Comments at 9 (“[M]any knowledgeable publishers . . . have lost confidence
in the efficacy of the rate court process to yield fair market-value. That loss of confidence is
driving publishers to move away from the PROs to avoid this perceived inadequacy.”).
492
See, e.g., Tr. at 23:17-20 (June 17, 2014) (Timothy Cohan, PeerMusic) (“[T]here seems to be
consensus that there would be universal havocI think that’s an apt termif total withdrawals
were to happen.”); Tr. at 30:05-06 (June 17, 2014) (Ashley Irwin, SCL) (stating that publisher
withdrawals would result in “total havoc”).
493
BMI Second Notice Comments at 12.
494
Sisario, Pandora Suit May Upend Century-Old Royalty Plan.
495
A2IM First Notice Comments at 6.
496
See, e.g., ASCAP Second Notice Comments at 3-4 (predicting that “withdrawing publishers will
result in a loss of revenue but without an attendant drop in expenses, which will have to be
97
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
continue in operation in such a circumstance.
497
A related concern is that smaller
publishers might face unsustainable increases in licensing and transaction costs as
independent entities,
which could lead to greater consolidation in the music publishing
market.
498
Nonetheless, based on their public statements and comments during this study, at least
two major publishersUMPG and Sony/ATVappear poised to withdraw.
499
In
contrast to Sony/ATV, a representative from UMPG suggested that such an action would
not be the end of the PROs:
We could withdraw tomorrow, and it would be seamless. The landscape
would not change that much. Youre talking about introducing maybe a
few additional players to the licensing process, Universal being one of
them. The societies don’t go away. The societies continue to exist for
those writers and publishers who don’t have the resources that were
fortunate enough to have to create infrastructures to deal with licensing
and data management, but there are several solutions, they are all
workable, and they don’t impact the industry or the writer community
negatively.
500
unfairly borne by the remaining ASCAP members”); see also LaPolt First Notice Comments at 12-
13; NARAS Second Notice Comments at 2.
497
Tr. at 9:09-15 (June 5, 2014) (Sam Mosenkis, ASCAP) (“[I]f the revenues . . . decrease[] by 60
percent, clearly operating ratios are going to increase, possibly to a point where we can’t operate
efficiently enough and the whole concept of efficient licensing really drops down the drain.”); see
also NSAI Second Notice Comments at 3 (“If major music publishers directly license and collect
the digital performance royalties easiest to accomplish, it is unlikely that ASCAP and BMI could
continue to exist on what is left, at least with the same efficiency and cost.”).
498
See, e.g., RIAA First Notice Comments at 39 (“[O]utright withdrawal is a possibility that
imperils the whole musical work performance licensing system, and creates a risk that there will
be no practical way to access works, and shares of works, owned by smaller publishers.”).
499
See ASCAP First Notice Comments at 36; Tr. at 37:02-39:08 (June 17, 2014) (David Kokakis,
UMPG); see also Ed Christman, Sony/ATV’s Martin Bandier Repeats Warning to ASCAP, BMI,
B
ILLBOARD (July 11, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/publishing
/6157469/sonyatvs-martin-bandier-repeats-warning-to-ascap-bmi (reporting the details of a letter
sent by Sony/ATV chairman and CEO, Martin Bandier, to Sony/ATV songwriters explaining that
Sony/ATV “may have no alternative but to take all of our rights out of ASCAP and BMI”).
Warner/Chappell did not participate in the study, but previously announced “their intentions to
withdraw their New Media licensing rights from ASCAP” along with other large publishers,
following completion of the June 2012 deal between Pandora and Sony/EMI. In re Pandora, 2013
WL 5211927, at *3.
500
Tr. at 34:18-35:09 (June 17, 2014) (David Kokakis, UMPG).
98
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
As an alternative to full withdrawal, partial withdrawal of only new media rights
remains a possibility if the rate courts’ “all in or all out” interpretations of the consent
decrees are reversed on appeal, or the DOJ concludes that it should support a
modification of the decrees to permit it. The PROs and major publishers have advanced
several arguments in favor of partial withdrawal, including their view that it would
allow for fairer, market-based rates for new media uses, that it would allow for greater
flexibility in licensing terms, and that directly negotiated licenses with digital services
would provide a competitive benchmark in ratesetting proceedings governing non-
withdrawing publishers.
501
Licensees, however, stated that even partial withdrawal would undermine the
protection of the consent decrees, and allow the withdrawing publishers to raise rates
through the exercise of unfettered market power.
502
Music Choice claimed that for the
brief period before the ASCAP rate court banned publishers’ partial withdrawal,
“negotiations with Sony and UMPG were oppressive, and resulted in substantially
higher royalty rates.”
503
Others echoed the concern that publishers would engage in
anticompetitive behavior.
504
Songwriters also have significant concerns about publisher withdrawals, specifically as
to how the writer’s share of performance royalties would be administered and paid.
Songwriter contracts typically provide that the writers share will be collected and paid
through a PRO,
505
but many of these contracts likely do not contemplate publisher
withdrawal from the PRO.
506
Songwriters fear that, if they instead receive payment
through the publisher, they will be vulnerable to the publishers less transparent
501
See, e.g., ASCAP First Notice Comments at 34-35.
502
DiMA First Notice Comments at 32 (“[I]f the antitrust consent decrees were to be modified by
the Department of Justice to accommodate ‘limited’ withdrawals . . . the marketplace for musical
work public performance rights would be significantly compromised.”).
503
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 6.
504
CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at 5 (“When ASCAP allowed the largest
music publishers to remove their digital rights from the existing contracts, [the publishers]
immediately returned to the abusive practices that had made the consent decree necessary in the
first place.”); Tr. at 52:07-20 (June 24, 2014) (Paul Fakler, Music Choice) (“[After publishers did
partially withdraw] there was evidence from the record, of collusion, strong arm tactics to inflate
the rates, sharing confidential information about negotiations.”).
505
Tr. at 12:07-09 (June 17, 2014) (Garry Schyman, SCL) (“We only receive the writer’s share, and
that’s contractual.”); id. at 24:13-16 (Timothy Cohan, PeerMusic) (“Contracts have mentioned the
writer’s share for a long, long time. They are not consistent. It is often negotiated from contract
to contract.”).
506
Id. at 12:10-14 (Garry Schyman, SCL) (“[V]ery often the contracts do not specify what would
happen if the music is withdrawn from a PRO. It merely says if money is collected through your
society, that you are entitled to receive your share.”).
99
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
accounting.
507
FMC suggested that “[a]ny further amendments to the consent decrees
must be done with complete transparency and with a thoughtful consideration of the
impact on songwriters’ leverage and compensation.”
508
The SCL voiced concerns that withdrawal of publishers from U.S. PROs would cause
problems for foreign songwriters, who enter into exclusive arrangements with their local
performing rights society, which in turn authorize U.S. PROs to collect royalties on their
behalf through reciprocal relationships. According to SCL, a U.S. publisher representing
a foreign author’s works under a sub-publishing agreement lacks the authority to
withdraw that writers’ rights from the U.S. PRO.
509
Questioned about this, David
Kokakis of UMPG responded that his company has “considered the international
implications” of withdrawal and does not “currently intend to disrupt that [reciprocity]
model.”
510
Kokakis maintained that “exploitation of foreign works in the United States .
. . would continue to run through the [U.S.] societies.”
511
A number of study participants proposed continued reliance upon the PROs to collect
and administer royalties from licensees even under directly negotiated deals.
512
According to ASCAP, when the major publishers sought to withdraw their new media
rights, ASCAP entered into administration arrangements with the withdrawing
publishers “that enabled the publishers to negotiate directly their digital rights in the
free market, but leave the administration of such deals—receiving fees, processing music
use information data, matching works to interested parties and paying all interested
parties—to ASCAP” for a fee.
513
Such an arrangement might also address the concern
that the withdrawing publishers would lack the infrastructure to license and collect
performance royalties from bars, restaurants or live performance venues.”
514
507
NARAS Second Notice Comments at 2 (noting that “the rest of the music ecosystem would
lose the efficiency, transparency and stability provided by the PROs.”); CFA & Public Knowledge
First Notice Comments at 18; Tr. at 33:22-34:06 (June 24, 2014) (Rick Carnes, SGA).
508
FMC First Notice Comments at 6-7.
509
Tr. at 31:16-32:04 (June 17, 2014) (Ashley Irwin, SCL) (“[M]y deal with [a foreign PRO] does not
allow a sub-publisher to pull out of an American society. It contravenes my agreement with my
local society. So I don’t know if anybody has considered what the foreign societies will do if the
publishers pull out here that are representing, once again, a reciprocity thing.”).
510
Id. at 34:11-13, 43:09-10 (David Kokakis, UPMG).
511
Id. at 43:17-19.
512
Id. at 38:06-08; BMI Second Notice Comments at 14; see also Tr. at 45:05-10 (June 16, 2014)
(Ashley Irwin, SCL) (proposing bifurcation of public performance right between publishers and
songwriters, so that songwriters could continue to utilize the PROs).
513
ASCAP Second Notice Comment at 6.
514
NSAI Second Notice Comments at 3; see also NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 20
(“[Withdrawal] presents a Hobson’s choice for music publisherseither pull out of ASCAP
100
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Elimination Versus Expansion of Consent Decrees
During the course of this study, PROs, publishers, and songwriters have advocated for
the sunset of the consent decrees that govern ASCAP and BMI.
515
ASCAP noted the
anomaly that the decrees “continue[] into perpetuity regardless of the increased
competition in the marketplace for licensing the public performance of musical
works.”
516
ASCAP thus views the decrees as “particularly punitive in nature when
viewed in light of current DOJ policy,” which mandates the inclusion of sunset
provisions in standard consent decrees, and under which the DOJ “does not currently
enter into consent decrees with terms longer than ten years.
517
ASCAP observed that
the marketplace has undergone massive changes since its decree was first adopted in
1941, in that “ASCAP now faces vibrant competition, not only from BMI, but also from
unregulated competitors such as SESAC, foreign PROs, and new market entrants, as
well as from ASCAP’s own publisher and writer members.
518
BMI similarly points out
that “outmoded views of the purported monopoly power of regulated collectives such
as BMI and ASCAP need to be discarded” as “digital technology has made it easier for
creators and distributors, including unregulated competitors to PROs, to identify
performances and their owners.”
519
In contrast, licensees fear that sunset of the consent decrees would lead not just to
higher, but “supracompetitive,” rates,
520
all the more problematic when licensees have to
pay performance royalties for both sound recordings and musical works. A wide range
of licensees accordingly support the continuation of the consent decrees in essentially
unchanged form.
521
Some participants went further by suggesting that the restrictions imposed by the
consent decrees should be extended to the smaller PROs not currently subject to direct
completely (and take on the difficult burdens of general licensing, e.g., licensing to small music
users such as bars and clubs), or forfeit the right to negotiate agreements at market rates with
digital service providers.”).
515
BMI First Notice Comments at 20; ASCAP First Notice Comments at 4.
516
Id. at 37-38.
517
Id. at 38; see also BMI First Notice Comments at 13 (“In 1979, the [DOJ] determined that
entering into perpetual consent decrees was not in the public interest.”).
518
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 38.
519
BMI First Notice Comments at 25.
520
See, e.g., Music Choice First Notice Comments at 8.
521
See, e.g., DiMA First Notice Comments at 15 (“The processes and protections assured by these
consent decrees serve several important roles that are critical to an efficient, properly functioning
marketplace for these rights . . . .”).
101
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
supervision. For example, Netflix suggested that all PROs should be subject to the same
ratesetting authority and that PROs could divide the shares of the royalty pools among
themselves.
522
Participants also suggested that withdrawing major publishers should be
subject to oversight and possibly a consent decree to protect against a concentration of
market power.
523
Rate Court Changes
The costs and length of rate court proceeding are frustrating for many. Some
including ASCAP and BMIhave suggested replacing the rate courts with an
alternative dispute resolution process such as arbitration.
524
IPAC advocated for private
negotiation followed by expedited mediation within prescribed time limits.
525
Licensees, however, were skeptical. NAB stated that “[t]here is no reason to believe that,
without drastic elimination of appropriate and essential discovery and appellate review,
private arbitration will be any more efficient, speedy, or cost-effective than the rate
courts.”
526
FMC voiced a concern that sealed arbitration proceedings would threaten
transparency.
527
Even while acknowledging the rate courts flaws, a number of licensees
supported the continuation of that regime, in part due to its procedural safeguards,
including use of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure and Evidence.
528
As one licensee
opined,the process of rate-setting under the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees—and the
522
Netflix First Notice Comments at 7.
523
See, e.g., Tr. at 44:22-45:05 (June 5, 2014) (Lee Knife, DiMA) (“I think whenever you have that
type of concentration of market power, that kind of demands some type of oversight, again,
whether or not that’s in the form of a compulsory license, a statutory license, a consent decree, or
something like that.”); Tr. at 52:07-20 (June 24, 2014) (Paul Fakler, Music Choice).
524
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 23-24 (explaining that arbitration would offer a more
definite timeline and would discourage applicants from relying on the license application or
interim licenses); Music Licensing Hearings at 52 (statement of Michael O’Neill, CEO, BMI) (“We
believe that replacing the current rate court with arbitration in New York under the American
Arbitration Association rules would be a faster, less expensive, and a more market-responsive
mechanism for all parties to obtain fair, market-value rate decisions.”); Content Creators
Coalition Second Notice Comments at 2-3.
525
IPAC First Notice Comments at 9.
526
NAB Second Notice Comments at 2; see also Music Choice Second Notice Comments at 8; Tr. at
55:14-16 (June 24, 2014) (Willard Hoyt, TMLC) (“It has been our experience that arbitration is not,
necessarily, less expensive than the rate court.”).
527
Tr. at 88:21-89:05 (June 23, 2014) (Casey Rae, FMC).
528
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 29.
102
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
hypothetical competitive market standard for rate-setting applied in Rate Court cases—
has worked reasonably well.”
529
PROs and publishers also seek to encourage interim payment of royalties pending the
determination of a final rate. MMF and FAC suggested that “[a]t the very least US
licensees should be required to make an interim payment pending the issuing of a final
license with an agreed tariff.”
530
BMI suggested that rather than invoking the
burdensome rate court process to set an interim rate, the fee could be set at the rate the
licensee paid under its last license or, for new users, the “going industry rate.
531
Bundled Licensing
There appears to be broad agreement among stakeholders that PROs and other licensing
entities should be able to bundle performance rights with reproduction and distribution
rights, and potentially other rights, to meet the needs of modern music services.
532
NSAI, for example, opined that “[t]he most efficient path to digital service providers
obtaining necessary licenses would be to allow the PRO’s to license and collect
mechanical royalties.”
533
Stakeholders offered conflicting methods by which bundled rights could be made
available. For instance, NMPA suggested that bundled rights could be sought directly
from the music publishers that own and administer the song in question.
534
But the
PROs suggested that their existing structures could be leveraged to facilitate bundled
529
Netflix First Notice Comments at 7-8 (emphasis in original); see also Sirius XM First Notice
Comments at 4 (“In our experience, the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees and the licensing
process that they mandate work relatively well.”); Spotify First Notice Comments at 10
(explaining that “the current system where the PROs are subject to regulation via the consent
decrees is working well”).
530
MMF & FAC Second Notice Comments at 10.
531
BMI First Notice Comments at 17.
532
See ASCAP First Notice Comments at 30; DiMA First Notice Comments at 25 (“A mechanism
should be put in place that enables the collective administration of an ‘all-in,’ combined
mechanical and performance royalty.”); IPAC First Notice Comments at 8 (“A unified licensing
scheme for uses that require both public performance and mechanical licenses could benefit both
licensees and copyright owners.”); RIAA First Notice Comments at 6 (“[T]he marketplace needs
bundles of rights.”); CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at 28; SCL First Notice
Comments at 12.
533
NSAI Second Notice Comments at 8.
534
NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 18; Tr. at 239:15-18 (June 24, 2014) (Jay Rosenthal,
NMPA).
103
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
licensing on a blanket basis, if only the consent decrees were amended.
535
Several parties
also observed that allowing bundling of rights would align U.S. music licensing with
collective practices in Europe.
536
Elimination of Section 114(i) Prohibition
Songwriters and publishers expressed support for the SEA, which, in addition to
addressing the ratesetting standard under section 115, would amend section 114(i) of the
Copyright Act to remove language prohibiting the rate courts and other bodies from
considering the license fees payable for the public performance of sound recordings
when determining rates to be paid for musical works.
537
Proponents of the SEA stated
that rate courts should be able to consider all relevant evidence
538
and predicted that the
courts, after considering the CRB-established sound recording rates, would increase
performance rates for musical works so that they were more commensurate with rates
paid for sound recordings.
539
Music services opposed amending section 114(i) on the ground that eliminating the
evidentiary exclusion of the CRB-set rate for sound recordings would increase rates for
musical works without a proportional decrease of rates for sound recordings, leading to
an overall escalation of total content costs to potentially unsustainable levels.
540
Some
noted that those who now support the elimination of that provision are the same parties
who sought it in the first place, as the provision was enacted out of copyright owners’
535
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 30-34; BMI First Notice Comments at 15-16; Tr. at 273:13-15
(June 24, 2014) (Richard Reimer, ASCAP); Tr. at 38:03-04 (June 24, 2014) (Stuart Rosen, BMI).
536
BMI First Notice Comments at 6; Tr. at 32:20-33:01 (June 4, 2014) (Dan Coleman, Modern Music
Works Publishing); Tr. at 273:07-12 (June 24, 2014) (Richard Reimer, ASCAP).
537
SEA, H.R. 4079 § 2.
538
See, e.g., NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 21-22; BMI First Notice Comments at 18-19;
SESAC First Notice Comments at 3-4; NARAS First Notice Comments at 4; Geo Music Group &
George Johnson Music Publ’g First Notice Comments at 16; Tr. at 198:09-17 (June 5, 2014) (Daniel
Gervais, Vanderbilt University Law School) (noting “when you read in the Copyright Royalty
Board determination that the value of a sound recording is unrelated to the value of the song . . .
[t]o me, that complete disconnect is not warranted”).
539
See, e.g., BMI First Notice Comments at 18; ASCAP First Notice Comments at 27-30; SESAC
First Notice Comments at 5; NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 26-28; NARAS First Notice
Comments at 4; LaPolt First Notice Comments at 12.
540
See e.g., CTIA First Notice Comments at 12 (noting that “publishers want it both waysthey
want the higher sound recording fees to be relevant in setting their fees, but they want to protect
their affiliate record companies and ensure that sound recording fees are not dragged down by
much lower musical works fees”); Music Choice First Notice Comments at 34 (“The simple fact is
that the disparity in rates between the Section 114 license and the PRO licenses does not prove
that the PRO rates are too low; it proves that the Section 114 rates are too high.”).
104
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
concern that consideration of sound recording license fees might depress musical work
rates.
541
Opponents further observed that music publishers themselves previously
testified before the CRB that it was economically logical and necessary to maintain a
distinction between musical work and sound recording rates, and are now simply
questioning their prior judgment in light of the higher sound recording rates set by the
CRB.
542
2. Mechanical Rights Licensing
Many parties have called for either the complete elimination or modernization of section
115, citing issues such as the administrative challenges of the license, the inaccuracy and
slowness of the ratesetting process, and frustration with government-mandated rates.
Royalty Rates and Standard a.
A broad range of parties expressed dissatisfaction with royalty rates established by the
CRB. Music publishers and songwriters argue that the rates determined under the
section 801(b)(1) standard applicable to section 115 are depressed as a result of the
government ratesetting process and do not reflect the fair market value of musical
works. While advocating for the elimination of the compulsory license, these parties
also assert that at the very least mechanical rates should be established under the more
market-oriented willing buyer/willing seller standard that applies under the section 112
and 114 licenses.
543
Musical work owners explain that section 115 acts as a ceiling that does not allow them
to seek higher royalties through voluntary negotiations.
544
Many point to the fact that
the current 9.1-cent rate for phonorecords has not kept pace with inflation, since the
541
CTIA First Notice Comments at 11-12.; Tr. at 254:06-19 (June 16, 2014) (Russell Hauth,
NRBMLC) (”Now that the sound recording industry has got a great rate, the musical works want
the same, and they want to not be separated any longer. You know, I’ve got to say that’s fairly
hypocritical.”).
542
See, e.g., NRBMLC First Notice Comments at 11-12; Tr. at 254:06-19 (June 16, 2014) (Russell
Hauth, NRBMLC); Tr. at 76:22-79:07 (June 24, 2014) (Bruce Rich, RMLC); Tr. at 85:13-86:07 (June
24, 2014) (Paul Fakler, NAB).
543
See ABKCO First Notice Comments at 1; BMI First Notice Comments at 5; Gear Publ’g Co. &
Lisa Thomas Music Servs., LLC First Notice Comments at 4; IPAC First Notice Comments at 7; see
also Tr. at 119:01-09 (June 17, 2014) (John Rudolph, Music Analytics); Tr. at 33:20-34:02 (June 23,
2014) (Jay Rosenthal, NMPA).
544
See Carapetyan Second Notice Comments at 1 (“The reality is it is rarely used in standard
industry practice, serving only as a framework for negotiating terms of direct licenses, but acting
as a de facto ceiling for royalty rates nonetheless.”); Geo Music Group & George Johnson Music
Publ’g First Notice Comments at 10 (opining that “the statutory rate is still a cap and as non-effective
as it gets.”) (emphasis in original); NSAI Second Notice Comments at 7.
105
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
original 2-cent rate set by statute in 1909 would be 51 cents today if adjusted for
inflation.
545
In addition, a number of participants noted a 9 to 1 inequity of rates
between sound recordings and musical works for downloads and CDs: when a song is
downloaded from iTunes for $1.29, approximately 80 cents is allocated for the sound
recording, but only 9.1 cents goes to the musical work.
546
By way of contrast, rates for
privately negotiated synchronization licenses—which are not subject to government
oversightgenerally reflect a 1 to 1 ratio between musical works and sound
recordings.
547
Digital music services, however, disagree, contending that the statutory rates set under
the section 801(b)(1) standard reflect fair market value, or higher.
548
According to them,
the statutory rates provide a “useful benchmark for direct deals” by providing a
framework by which to negotiate such deals.
549
They contend that the willing
buyer/willing seller standard is faulty at best since “the ‘market’ the standard seeks to
construct or emulate does not exist and often has never existed,”
550
whereas the section
801(b)(1) standard is “flexible” and more predictable and accounts for fairness in
compensating copyright owners.
551
Though record labels are in agreement with digital music services that the section
801(b)(1) standard does not result in rates lower than fair market value, they have also
advocated changing the section 115 rate standard to the willing buyer/willing seller
standard.
552
Record labels point to the importance of emphasizing fair market value as
“the goal of any rate-setting process” and argue that harmonizing the statutory rate
545
See LaPolt Second Notice Comments at 9; MMF & FAC Second Notice Comments at 6; Modern
Works Music Publishing First Notice Comments at 4-5; see also Tr. at 250:15-21 (June 4, 2014)
(Brittany Schaffer, NMPA/Loeb & Loeb LLP).
546
NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 16; Tr. at 266:14-267:05 (June 16, 2014) (Ilene
Goldberg); see also Kohn First Notice Comments at 19-20.
547
LaPolt First Notice Comments at 14; NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 16; see also Tr. at
60:20-22 (June 4, 2014) (Brittany Schaffer, NMPA/Loeb & Loeb LLP).
548
See DiMA First Notice Comments at 23 (“The Section 801(b) standard has been time-tested to
provide fair rates (i.e., ‘reasonable fees’) that have been accepted for more than half a century in
many different contexts, including ratesetting proceedings under Sections 114(f)(1)(B), 115, and
116.”); DiMA Second Notice Comments at 21; Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 13-14; see also
Tr. at 310:01-09 (June 23, 2014) (Lee Knife, DiMA).
549
DiMA First Notice Comments at 19.
550
DiMA Second Notice Comments at 20; see also Music Choice First Notice Comments at 37.
551
DiMA Second Notice Comments at 20-21; see also Tr. at 278:21-279:02 (June 23, 2014) (Paul
Fakler, NAB/Music Choice); Tr. at 294:02-10 (June 23, 2014) (Cynthia Greer, Sirius XM).
552
RIAA First Notice Comments at 25.
106
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
standards by bringing section 115 within the willing buyer/willing seller standard
would achieve that goal.
553
Administrative Burdens b.
Stakeholders expressed near universal concern about the inefficiencies of the mechanical
licensing process. The section 115 statutory license creates a per-work licensing model;
the same model is employed when seeking licenses through intermediaries such as
HFA.
554
Licensees seeking to release individual records typically obtain a mechanical
license for the specific product through HFA or directly from the publisher.
555
But
digital services seeking large volumessometimes millionsof licenses are more likely
to rely on the section 115 statutory license for at least some of their licensing needs.
Consequently, digital providers expressed considerable frustration with the song-by-
song licensing process.
556
Although the statutory licensing process is more commonly relied upon now than it has
been in the past, RIAA regarded this development as merely “an indication that musical
work licensing is so broken that mass use of the compulsory license process is the best of
a lot of bad options.”
557
In addition to the burden of seeking licenses for individual
works, licensees complain about the lack of readily available data concerning musical
work ownership, as described further below.
558
Digital services asserted that the
inaccessibility of ownership information leads to costly and burdensome efforts to
identify the rightsholders and potentially incomplete or incorrect licenses, exposing
them to the risk of statutory infringement damages despite diligent efforts.
559
A number of licensees also objected to the detailed accounting and payment
requirements imposed by section 115.
560
DiMA noted that for “direct license agreements
553
Id.
554
See, e.g., BMI First Notice Comments at 5; DiMA First Notice Comments at 20; Spotify First
Notice Comments at 3-5; RIAA First Notice Comments at 10-11.
555
See id. at 40 (describing the previously high volume of mechanical licenses issued through HFA
and the increasing practice of direct licensing for new songs and new albums).
556
See DiMA First Notice Comments at 20 (noting that “the costs [in filing NOIs with the
Copyright Office] can be overwhelming given the volume of works at issue”); Tr. at 172:06-13
(June 16, 2014) (Lawrence J. Blake, Concord Music).
557
RIAA First Notice Comments at 23 n.36.
558
DiMA First Notice Comments at 20.
559
Id. at 20-21.
560
CTIA First Notice Comments at 13 (explaining that “virtually all participants in the market
have recognized that the licensing regime for the reproduction and distribution rights, which
requires specific monthly reporting and payment, is complex and burdensome”); LaPolt Second
107
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
for rights otherwise covered by the section 115 statutory licenses, it is customary for
digital music services to pay rightsowners on a quarterly basis.”
561
The statute, however,
requires accounting and payment on a monthly basis, which increases administrative
burdens and out-of-pocket costs.
Perceived Unfairness c.
Many stakeholders are of the view that the section 115 license is unfair to copyright
owners. As one submission summed it up: “The notifications, statements of account,
license terms, lack of compliance, lack of audit provisions, lack of accountability, lack of
transparency, ‘one size fits all’ royalty rates and inability to effectively enforce the terms
of the license demonstrate a complete breakdown in the statutory licensing system from
start to finish.”
562
Lack of Audit Rights
Though there may be significant practical limitations on copyright owners’ ability to
exercise audit rights due to the burden and expense of examining licensees,
563
the right
to audit is nonetheless highly valued. Accordingly, there is a particular industry
concern that section 115 does not provide music publishers with the right to verify the
statements of account they receive from licensees.
Section 115 differs from other statutory licenses in the Copyright Act in providing for an
“honor system” of self-reporting without a verification procedure.
564
Owners of musical
works, therefore, have no choice other than to rely upon user-certified royalty
Notice Comments at 10; Tr. at 234:21-235:01 (June 23, 2014) (Cheryl Potts, Crystal Clear Music &
CleerKut).
561
DiMA First Notice Comments at 22 (emphasis in original). See 17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(5).
562
Gear Publ’g Co. & Lisa Thomas Music Servs., LLC First Notice Comments at 5-6; Geo Music
Group & George Johnson Music Publ’g First Notice Comments at 9.
563
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 21 (“Although many cases are filed by songwriters and
recording artists for underpayment of royalties, far more cases go unlitigated. This is because,
among other reasons, (1) the audit provisions in the authors’ contracts are often very restrictive;
(2) it is very expensive for an author to hire forensic accountants to conduct an audit; (3) once an
audit begins, the record company or publisher uses various tactics, including accounting records
that seem designed to obfuscate royalty revenues received and royalties due, to impede the audit;
and (4) even after underpayments are established, authors often must accept pennies on the
dollar for their claims because the cost of litigation against the record companies and publishers
is so high.”).
564
NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 14.
108
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
statements that they may find difficult to trust.
565
Further complicating the situation is
that a compulsory licensee may pay all royalties to one co-owner without any
notification to the others.
566
As one stakeholder put it, “[a]n audit right is particularly necessary in the music
industry which has an admittedly long and storied history of dubious accounting
practices and exploiting songwriters. Every songwriter deserves and should be entitled
to a straight count; self-certification . . . is not sufficient.”
567
Another stated, “it’s trust
but you can’t verify . . . . [W]eve got to rely on the kindness of strangers that they’re
going to report accurately.”
568
For many musical work owners, the issue is not just trust, but fairness. As musician
David Lowery explained, “I have seen instances where a supposed compulsory licensee
has failed to comply with its payment obligations for years, ignored termination notices,
and yet is still able to continue to receive the benefits of new statutory licenses for
songwriters who await the same fate.”
569
Or, as another songwriter advocate concluded:
“Having been compelled by the government to license their songs to strangers, it seems
only fair that the songwriter at least be able to confirm to their reasonable satisfaction
that they are getting a straight count.”
570
565
Castle First Notice Comments at 2. As discussed above, in lieu of requiring certifications, the
mechanical licensing agent HFA instead conducts audits of licenseesa substantial benefit for its
publisher members. See Michael Simon, The Basics of Mechanical Licensing from Harry Fox, A
RTISTS
HOUSE MUSIC (July 12, 2007), http://www.artistshousemusic.org/articles/the+basics+of+
mechanical+licensing+from+harry+fox (noting HFA’s audits of licensees). But the section 115
license does not require this.
566
IPAC First Notice Comments at 3-4 (“If the digital music service pays all royalties for the use of
a musical work to only one co-owner, then that co-owner is obligated to pay the other co-owners
of the musical work their respective share of the monies received. This practice effectively shifts
to the copyright owner the accounting and payment obligations of the user. This example also
puts co-owners of the musical work who have not received the Notice at a disadvantagethese
co-owners will likely be unaware that their musical works are being used, be unaware that
royalties are due, and be in a difficult position in terms of that co-owner’s rights to audit the
digital music service.”).
567
Rys First Notice Comments at 2.
568
Tr. at 209:17-20 (June 16, 2014) (Keith Bernstein, Crunch Digital).
569
Lowery First Notice Comments at 1; see also IPAC First Notice Comments at 3-4.
570
Castle First Notice Comments at 3.
109
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
While record companies seemed to offer some support for the ability of publishers and
songwriters to audit mechanical uses,
571
digital services objected to any sort of
verification process. In opposing an audit right, DiMA argued that the required
statements of account already provide for a method of self-auditing,” and that auditing
requirements would be burdensome and frustrate the value of the license itself.
572
In
addition, due to the challenges of accounting for digital uses under different licensing
schemes, DiMA believed auditing would cause even good-faith actors to appear
noncompliant.
573
A few parties offered specific proposals for an audit right under section 115. NMPA and
HFA suggested amending section 115 to include a duty to exchange and update usage
data on a continuous basis.
574
David Lowery suggested a system whereby the Copyright
Office could investigate licensees that were not compliant with their duties under
section 115.
575
Administrative Issues
Publishers, songwriters, and licensing administrators emphasized the problem of
noncompliant statutory licensees.
576
The required notices to obtain a statutory license
are frequently deficient,
577
and licensees regularly fail to timely and accurately pay and
report usage.
578
Due to the involuntary nature of the license, publishers and songwriters
cannot easily avoid these risks, as “[n]othing in the Section 115 license scheme requires
571
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 19 (noting that major record companies “support the idea
that where there is direct licensing, publishers/writers should have a direct audit right with
respect to third parties that use their works”).
572
See DiMA First Notice Comments at 19-20.
573
Id. at 21 (“For digital music services that rely on licenses under Section 115 as well as separate
licenses for the public performance of musical works, it is often impossible to determine the
appropriate deduction for musical work public performance royalties at the time that accountings
under the Section 115 licenses are due. This is because the calculation of ‘mechanical’ royalty
rates under Section 115 requires that public performance royalties be deducted; and public
performance rates are often not determinedwhether by ‘interim agreement,’ ‘final agreement’
or ratesetting proceedinguntil long after the close of the month during which Section 115
royalties are due.”).
574
NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 9-10; see also Kohn First Notice Comments at 11.
575
Lowery First Notice Comments at 3-4.
576
See, e.g., id. 1-4.
577
Carapetyan Second Notice Comments at 1 (noting that there is “a bevy of legally deficient
‘Notices of Intention’ that force publishers into the involuntary role of teaching the fundamentals
of copyright to the masseswhich is neither practical nor fairand often in the end the cost in
effort and man-hours far exceeds the minuscule royalties for the use”).
578
Lowery First Notice Comments at 2.
110
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
any consideration of the creditworthiness or trustworthiness of the compulsory
licensee.”
579
Many found the recourse provided by statute—termination of the license
and costly infringement lawsuits—ineffective.
580
Publishers also complained about regulatory provisions that permit payment of royalties
and service of NOIs on a single co-owner of a work, with that co-owner then under an
obligation to account to the other co-owners. As one commenter explained, “[t]his
practice effectively shifts to the copyright owner the accounting and payment
obligations of the user.”
581
At the same time, a number of parties asserted that the complex nature of the statutory
licensing scheme was unfair to licensees. Some pointed to the complexity of the section
115 royalty regulations for digital services—and the fine distinctions they draw among
different types of services—as a source of confusion as to what royalties need to be
paid.
582
Digital services also highlighted the one-sided risk of costly statutory damages
should they fail to ascertain that a first use of a work has occurred (rendering the work
eligible for statutory licensing) and timely serve an NOI on the copyright owner, even
where such determination is difficult due to lack of sufficient data.
583
Parties’ Proposals d.
Elimination of Statutory License
Songwriters and publishers appear almost universally to favor the elimination of the
section 115 statutory license, albeit with an appropriate phase-out period.
584
They assert
that the statutory regime creates an artificial status quo that precludes a private market
from developing.
585
Musical work owners predict that the elimination of a license would
allow “a functioning licensing market . . . [to] flourish.”
586
579
Id. at 2-3; see also NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 15.
580
See, e.g., Castle Second Notice Comments at 3 (“[A] defaulter under the statutory license can
lawfully continue sending NOIs for future licenses even if they have never paid a dime on past
licensesthe only recourse a songwriter has in this case is termination and if that too is ignored,
extraordinarily expensive federal copyright litigation.”).
581
IPAC First Notice Comment at 3; see also Rys First Notice Comments at 2.
582
See DiMA First Notice Comments at 22 (observing differences between the royalty rate
structures for some current rate categories).
583
Id. at 21.
584
See, e.g., NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 8; NSAI Second Notice Comments at 7; IPAC
First Notice Comments at 4.
585
See ABKCO First Notice Comments at 1 (“The free market is stifled under Section 115 licensing
requirements with government controlling rates which thereby limits and inhibits sector growth
111
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Digital music services, however, assert that the section 115 license is both important and
fair, as it “provides an essential counter-balance to the unique market power of copyright rights
owners . . . by providing a mechanism for immediate license coverage, thereby negating
the rights owner’s prerogative to withhold the grant of a license.”
587
Thus, some
licensees view section 115 as a protection against monopoly power that allows the public
to enjoy musical works while still compensating copyright owners.
588
Spotify argued
that the free market is not stifled by the statutory license, but that section 115 instead
acts as “an indispensable component to facilitating a vibrant marketplace for making
millions of sound recordings available to the public on commercially reasonable
terms.”
589
Blanket Licensing
In light of the widely perceived inefficiencies of song-by-song licensing of mechanical
rightsparticularly as compared to the collective approach of the PROsa wide range
of stakeholders suggested that a blanket system would be a superior means of licensing
mechanical rights.
590
As RIAA noted, blanket licensing avoids the administrative costs
associated with negotiating and managing large numbers of licenses of varying terms
and provides a way for legitimate services to avoid infringement risk.
591
Similarly, the
publisher ABKCO opined that blanket license agreements would facilitate the use of
music and would help licensees fulfill notification and reporting obligations.
592
IPAC
and innovation.”); MMF & FAC Second Notice Comments at 14-15; RIAA Second Notice
Comments at 4-5; Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 16.
586
NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 7; see also IPAC First Notice Comments at 6.
587
DiMA First Notice Comments at 19 (emphasis in original).
588
Modern Works Music Publishing Second Notice Comments at 3 (explaining that section 115 is
an antitrust provision that accelerates the entry of musical works into the public sphere, while
ensuring that copyright holders are paid.”) (emphasis in original).
589
Spotify First Notice Comments at 3.
590
See, e.g., NARAS First Notice Comments at 3-4; DiMA First Notice Comments at 16-17; IPAC
First Notice Comments at 6-7; BMI First Notice Comments at 5; ASCAP First Notice Comments at
30-31. In 2006, the House Subcommittee on Courts, the Internet, and Intellectual Property
considered SIRA, legislation that would have created a blanket license for digital uses under
section 115. While SIRA enjoyed support from some key stakeholders and was approved by the
subcommittee, it was not passed out of the full committee. See Reforming Section 115 Hearing at 4
(statement of Rep. Howard Coble) (detailing legislative history); Mitchell, Reforming Section 115:
Escape from the Byzantine World of Mechanical Licensing at 1277 (describing support for SIRA).
591
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 13.
592
ABKCO First Notice Comments at 1-2.
112
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
suggested that blanket licensing could be implemented through the creation of one or
more licensing agencies.
593
To highlight the complexity of licensing in the modern music marketplace, RIAA
described the experience of one of its members, which had released “a very successful
album,” and “had to obtain for that album 1481 licenses for the release of three physical
products, the 92 digital products, the 27 songs across the 51 songwriters” with a total of
“89 shares.”
594
One of those shares “represented [a] 1.5 percent interest in a song, and
there were two publishers for that.”
595
According to the RIAA, apart from multiple
songwriter interests, one of the reasons for this explosion in licensing complexity is the
increased complexity of the releases themselveswhereas in the past a record label
release consisted of “a disk and some liner notes,” today it comprises multiple digital
formats, different kinds of audiovisual presentations, and different kinds of music
services.
596
In light of its belief that these problems “cannot be solved by piecemeal efforts,” RIAA
proposed fundamentally restructuring performance and mechanical licensing for
musical works.
597
Under the RIAA proposal, record labels would receive a compulsory
blanket license covering all rights (performance, mechanical, and synch) necessary for
what RIAA calls “modern music products,” including audiovisual products like music
videos, videos with album art or liner notes, and lyric videos.
598
The rate court and CRB
would be eliminated. Instead, the record labels and publishers would agree upon splits
of revenues received by the record labels from their sale and licensing of recorded
music. The record companies would have sole responsibility to sell and license those
products; those deals would be negotiated by the labels in the marketplace (except for
uses falling under the section 112 and 114 licenses).
599
RIAA believed that its proposal
would achieve fair market rates for publishers and songwriters while retaining the
benefits of a collective licensing system, such as simplified licensing and lower
administrative costs.
600
593
IPAC First Notice Comments at 6-7.
594
Tr. 25:11-16 (June 4, 2014) (Steven Marks, RIAA).
595
Id. at 25:16-18.
596
Id. at 24:04-26:18.
597
RIAA First Notice Comments at 15-17.
598
Id. at 16. RIAA made clear that its proposed blanket license would not cover other uses of
musical works, like synch rights for movie, television, and advertising, performances within live
venue, stand-alone lyrics, and sheet music. Id. at 17.
599
Id. at 15-18.
600
Id. at 18-22.
113
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
But publishers and songwriters vigorously resisted RIAA’s proposal, arguing that it
would merely shift control over musical works from songwriters and music publishers
to record labelssince the labels would then be in charge of licensing decisions and
royalty rates.
601
They also expressed concern about bringing audiovisual works or other
rights currently outside of the compulsory system under a statutory blanket license.
602
NMPA characterized the RIAA’s proposal as “seeking to expand the scope of the Sec.
115 compulsory license to authorize almost all forms of exploitation of a sound
recording, including, among other things, record label created videos, and ‘first use’
rights.”
603
3. Sections 112 and 114
As compared to issues relating to the licensing of musical works, concerns regarding the
section 112 and 114 statutory licenses were relatively modest.
Royalty Rates a.
Sound recording owners appear generally satisfied with the section 112 and 114 rates set
under the willing buyer/willing seller standard.
604
A2IM, in particular, appreciates that
the CRB’s process treats all sound recordings the same for ratesetting purposes.
605
CFA and Public Knowledge, however, assert that section 112 and 114 royalties are
“much too high,” pointing to the fact that Pandora had “yet to demonstrate sustained
profitability.”
606
DiMA similarly contended that the willing buyer/willing seller
601
NMPA Second Notice Comments at 32-33; see also Tr. at 245:12-20 (June 24, 2014) (Peter
Brodsky, Sony/ATV).
602
LaPolt Second Notice Comments at 14; NMPA Second Notice Comments at 32-35; NSAI
Second Notice Comments at 8; see also Tr. at 214:14-20 (June 16, 2014) (John Barker, IPAC); Tr. at
246:21-247:09 (June 24, 2014) (Peter Brodsky, Sony/ATV).
603
NMPA Second Notice Comments at 32.
604
RIAA First Notice Comments at 32 (“All services operating under the statutory licenses should
pay fair market royalties set under the willing buyer/willing seller standard.”). In contrast, RIAA
criticized the “below-market royalty rates” set under the section 801(b)(1) standard for
grandfathered services. Id. at 31.
605
A2IM First Notice Comments at 3.
606
CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at 8. Pandora did report a modest profit in
Q3, 2013, but its current strategy is focused on expansion. Romain Dillet, Pandora Beats, Q3 2013
Revenue Up 60% to $120M, Net Income of $2.1M; Q4 Forecast Much Lower Than Expected,
T
ECHCRUNCH (Dec. 4, 2012), http://techcrunch.com/2012/12/04/pandoras-q3-2013/; PANDORA
MEDIA, INC., QUARTERLY REPORT (FORM 10-Q) 21 (Oct. 28, 2014), http://investor.pandora.com/
phoenix.zhtml?c=227956&p=irol-sec (click on Oct. 28, 2014 filing) (“[W]e expect to incur annual
net losses on a U.S. GAAP basis in the near term because our current strategy is to leverage any
improvements in gross profit by investing in broadening distribution channels, developing
114
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
standard yields rates that are “high and unsustainable” and that numerous services,
including those operated by AOL, Yahoo!, East Village Radio, Turntable.fm, Loudcity,
RadioParadise, and 3 Wk, have exited the business as a result.
607
DiMA also criticized the CRB’s imposition of per-performance rates for internet radio,
suggesting that such a rate structure should not be applied “in circumstances where the
higher usage does not equate to higher revenues for the digital music service
provider.
608
DiMA and others additionally observed that Congress felt compelled to
offer relief to internet radio services complaining of high rates under the willing
buyer/willing seller standard by passing the Small Webcaster Settlement Act of 2002 and
the Webcaster Settlement Acts of 2008 and 2009 to allow for negotiated alternatives to
the CRB-set rates.
609
Interactive/Noninteractive Divide b.
Stakeholders expressed a number of concerns regarding eligibility for the section 112
and 114 licenses.
As discussed above, interactive services are not eligible for the statutory licenses under
sections 112 and 114, though in the Second Circuit’s 2009 Launch Media decision, the
court concluded that a custom radio service—one that relies on user feedback to play a
personalized selection of musicis not an “interactive” service.
610
As a result, custom
radio services such as Pandora are treated as noninteractive and operate under section
112 and 114 licenses.
Copyright owners expressed concern that “customized Internet radio has approached
interactivity in every sense of the word except under the outdated requirements of the
statutory definition.”
611
RIAA similarly opined that Launch Media “all but extinguished
voluntary licensing of personalized streaming services at a premium [above] the
statutory rate.”
612
Notably, however, sound recording owners did not necessarily favor
innovative and scalable advertising products, increasing utilization of advertising inventory and
building our sales force.”).
607
DiMA First Notice Comments at 33 n.76.
608
Id. at 36.
609
Id. at 37; Educational Media Foundation (“EMF”) First Notice Comments at 7-8; Sirius XM First
Notice Comments at 14; Spotify First Notice Comments at 12.
610
See 17 U.S.C. § 114(d)(2)(A)(i); Launch Media, 578 F.3d 148.
611
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 44; see also BMI First Notice Comments at 22.
612
RIAA First Notice Comments at 34.
115
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
moving personalized services out of the statutory license.
613
Instead, they advocated for
a “middle tier” of royalty rates for personalized radio services under the statutory
license.
614
Other participants argued for expansion of the statutory licensing framework to cover
additional services.
615
For instance, A2IM favored “narrowing the definition of
‘interactive service’ to cover only those services that truly offer a full on-demand
interactive experience.
616
SAG-AFTRA and AFM also supported such an expansion, as
“[a]rtists will continue to benefit most fairly from [customized services] through
receiving an equal share of the proceeds, paid to them directly and transparently by
SoundExchange.”
617
In addition to the interactive/noninteractive distinction of section 114, concerns were
raised about the sound recording performance complementwhich limits the number
of plays of a single featured artist or from a particular album in a three-hour period—as
well as section 114’s ban on the pre-announcement of songs.
618
Broadcasters said that
these requirements frustrate simulcasting activities of terrestrial radio stations that do
not adhere to these restrictions in their over-the-air broadcasts.
619
NAB contended that
the sound recording performance complement “merely serve[s] as a bargaining chip for
leverage in the negotiations with broadcasters, due solely to the undue burden such
restrictions place on radio stations that seek to stream their broadcasts,”
620
and pointed
out that record labels regularly grant broadcasters waivers of the restriction as evidence
that the record labels do not need these provisions to protect their interests.
621
NPR
noted the upstream effect of the limitation, explaining that because public radio has
limited resources, it is forced to “create separate programming depending on the
method by which it will be distributed.”
622
613
See id. (“[A]t this juncture, we do not necessarily advocate excluding from the statutory license
services that have been generally accepted as operating within the statutory license based on the
Launch decision.”).
614
ABKCO First Notice Comments at 3; see also RIAA First Notice Comments at 34.
615
Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 20-21.
616
A2IM First Notice Comments at 5.
617
SAG-AFTRA & AFM First Notice Comments at 6 (note however, that SAG-AFTRA & AFM also
support increased rates if a service has increased functionality).
618
17 U.S.C. § 114(d)(1)(C)(iv), (d)(2)(B)-(C), (j)(13).
619
NAB First Notice Comments at 4-5; NPR First Notice Comments at 5; SRN Broadcasting First
Notice Comments at 1.
620
NAB First Notice Comments at 4.
621
Id. at 5.
622
NPR First Notice Comments at 5.
116
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Technical Limitations of Section 112 c.
A number of digital services criticized technical limitations on the availability of the
section 112 license that applies to the ephemeral (i.e., server) copies needed to facilitate
their transmissions.
623
For example, some licensees criticized the requirement that the
licensee destroy such copies within six months’ time as “unreasonable” and “archaic”
and one that has no benefit for rightsholders.
624
NAB noted that this requirement is
particularly illogical as server copies “are not meant to be temporary.”
625
DiMA
suggested that section 112 should be substantially updated to reflect modern realities of
digital music services.
626
Others suggested that any ephemeral copies made in
furtherance of a public performance should be exempted entirely.
627
RIAA opposed a blanket exemption for ephemeral recordings, explaining that those
recordings “have value” by providing services with “improved quality of service,
operational efficiencies or other competitive advantages.”
628
RIAA also observed that
“[t]he current statutory scheme replicates marketplace agreements for sound recordings,
in which licensees commonly acquire performance and related reproduction rights in a
single transaction and pay a bundled royalty that covers both rights.”
629
Lack of Termination Provision d.
SoundExchange opined that while the section 112 and 114 licensing framework
generally works well,” noncompliance with the statutory requirementsby irregular
or inaccurate payments or missing or incomplete reporting—is “commonplace.”
630
SoundExchange described its efforts to bring services into compliance, but also
expressed its belief that the section 112 and 114 system needs “a clear mechanism for
termination of statutory licenses for services that repeatedly fail to act in compliance
with applicable requirements,” such as the one that exists under section 115.
631
623
“Ephemeral recordings are copies that are made and used by a transmitting organization to
facilitate its transmitting activities.” U.S.
COPYRIGHT OFFICE, DMCA SECTION 104 REPORT 144
(2001), available at http://www.copyright.gov/reports/studies/dmca/sec-104-report-vol-1.pdf.
624
CTIA First Notice Comments at 16-18; DiMA First Notice Comments at 35; DiMA Second
Notice Comments at 18.
625
NAB First Notice Comments at 7; Music Choice First Notice Comments at 13.
626
DiMA Second Notice Comments at 18.
627
See, e.g., NAB First Notice Comments at 2; Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 9-10.
628
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 31-32.
629
Id. at 32.
630
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 2, 5.
631
Id. at 5; see also 17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(6) (termination provision under section 115).
117
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Royalty Distribution Process e.
Unlike section 114—which provides a statutory formula for the direct distribution of
royalties by SoundExchange to artists, record labels and musicians—the related section
112 license contains no such requirement. Some submissions suggested that the
royalties collected by SoundExchange as the designated agent under the section 112
license should be distributed to artists directly, as under section 114, rather than through
record labels.
632
Music Choice commented that, “[d]ue to the terms of their agreements
with the record companies and various record company accounting practices . . . the vast
majority of recording artists never see a penny of the portion of the performance royalty
allocated to the Section 112 license.”
633
In addition, section 114 currently does not allocate a share of royalties to record
producers, so there is no statutory mandate for direct payment to producers. Instead,
individual contracts between recording artists and producers provide for producer
compensation, which may include a share of royalties.
634
SoundExchange has begun
processing direct payment of the producer’s share of performance royalties on a
voluntary basis when it receives written authorization from the featured artist.
635
NARAS has proposed to make this process a “consistent and permanent” feature of
section 114.
636
4. Public and Noncommercial Broadcasting
As discussed above, the activities of public and noncommercial educational broadcasters
are subject to two different statutory licenses as well as PRO licensing and ratesetting.
Noncommercial broadcasters complain about the divergent licensing mechanisms for
the various music rights they must acquire. Noncommercial religious broadcasters
observed that, to clear musical works rights, they could be required to participate in a
CRB proceeding under section 118 for over-the-air transmissions, two rate court
proceedings under the consent decrees for digital transmissions of ASCAP and BMI
works, and private negotiation for digital transmissions of SESAC works.
637
In addition,
632
See Music Choice First Notice Comments at 13; Resnick Second Notice Comments at 1.
633
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 13; see also Resnick Second Notice Comments at 1.
634
See NARAS First Notice Comments at 5.
635
2013 Letter of Direction, SOUNDEXCHANGE (Apr. 14, 2013), https://www.soundexchange.com/
wp-content/uploads/2013/05/Letter-of-Direction-04-14-13.pdf (“2013 SoundExchange Letter of
Direction”).
636
See NARAS First Notice Comments at 5-6.
637
NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 14-15.
118
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
ascertaining the rate for digital performances of sound recordings requires participation
in yet another CRB ratesetting proceeding under section 114.
638
Noncommercial broadcasters thus seek to expand the section 118 license to encompass
all music elements.”
639
Noncommercial religious broadcasters proposed, in particular,
“[f]olding digital transmissions of musical works into the existing section 118 license
applicable to broadcast transmissions.”
640
NPR advocated for a further step: broadening
the section 118 license to encompass all known and yet to be created distribution
methods and technologies,” including physical products and permanent digital
downloads.
641
Finally, noncommercial broadcasters seek to ensure that the policy-oriented 801(b)(1)
ratesetting standard will apply to any expanded version of the section 118 license.
642
5. Concerns Regarding CRB Procedures
As with the rate courts, many stakeholders expressed concern about the CRB ratesetting
processmany of which are governed by detailed statutory provisions
643
including
specific concerns regarding discovery procedures, the settlement process, and bifurcated
proceedings.
Inefficiencies and Expense a.
Copyright owners and licensees together complained about the inefficiency and high
cost of proceedings before the CRB.
644
RIAA and SoundExchange suggested that one
way to reduce costs would be to simplify the rate standards and move to a
638
EMF First Notice Comments at 8-9 (noting reasons noncommercial broadcasters are unlikely to
settle in section 114 proceedings).
639
NPR First Notice Comments at 7.
640
NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 15.
641
NPR First Notice Comments at 7; see also Public Television Coalition (“PTC”) First Notice
Comments at 11.
642
See NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 16. While the 801(b)(1) “reasonable terms and rates”
standard currently applies under section 118, sound recording uses under section 114(d) are
subject to the willing buyer/willing seller standard. 17 U.S.C. §§ 114(d), 801(b)(1);
Noncommercial Educational Broadcasting Compulsory License, 63 Fed. Reg. 49,823, 49,824 (Sept.
18, 1998) (noting the rate standard for section 118 is “reasonable terms and rates” with no further
statutory criteria, but the legislative history of section 118 indicated that “the rate should reflect
the fair value of the copyrighted material”).
643
See 17 U.S.C. § 801 et seq.
644
See, e.g., ASCAP First Notice Comments at 24 n.31; Music Choice First Notice Comments at 29-
31; RIAA First Notice Comments at 36; Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 17.
119
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
straightforward willing buyer/willing seller rate standard across the board.
645
SoundExchange noted that “[r]elative to a streamlined fair market value standard, every
specific factor included in a rate standard increases cost and decreases predictability.”
646
Stakeholders also pointed to the bifurcated ratesetting procedures contemplated by
statute—which references separate direct and rebuttal phases of ratesetting hearings
647
as a significant and costly inefficiency,
648
creating a “‘two ships passing in the night’
quality to the proceedings.”
649
There was broad support for eliminating the bifurcated
nature of trials before the CRB because “[b]ifurcation offers no advantages or efficiencies
in discovery, comprehension of complex issues, savings in judicial resources, or
elimination of duplicative presentations of evidence.”
650
Another shortfall of the system is that the rate adjustment process occurs only once
every five years. Parties representing both copyright owners and music users found the
process slow and insufficiently responsive to new and developing technologies and
services.
651
Because ratesetting occurs only on a periodic basis, copyright owners and
users must attempt to predict and accommodate each type of service that might arise in
the upcoming five-year period.
652
For instance, as RIAA recounted, “[t]he Section 115
rate-setting process . . . resulted in a rate schedule with 17 different rate categories, and
in which publishers and songwriters can receive varying percentages of the relevant
content royalty pool” based on those categories, causing the administration of payments
to beexceedingly complex.
653
645
See, e.g., RIAA First Notice Comments at 36; SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 6-8.
646
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 10; see also RIAA Second Notice Comments at 43
(noting a single-factor rate standard as a possible streamlining measure).
647
17 U.S.C. § 803(b)(6)(C).
648
NAB First Notice Comments at 19 & n.11; Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 17.
649
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 30; see Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 17 (same).
650
NAB First Notice Comments at 20.
651
See BMI First Notice Comments at 27; DiMA First Notice Comments at 23; RIAA First Notice
Comments at 45; Tr. at 256:02-06 (June 16, 2014) (Jason Rys, Wixen Music Publishing).
652
Kohn First Notice Comments at 14 (referencing the “unnecessarily complex set of individual
rate regimes for the various uses contemplated by Section 114 by various kinds of defined
transmitters”).
653
RIAA First Notice Comments at 24; see also id. at 11-12 (further noting frustrations with
mechanical royalty ratesetting).
120
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Settlement Obstacles b.
In theory, Congress designed the CRB procedures to facilitate and encourage settlement
rather than administrative ratesetting by the CRB. Several stakeholders, however, noted
practical and procedural hurdles they have encountered in finalizing settlements.
The most common stakeholder plea was to modify the CRB process so the Judges would
act quickly on any settlement.
654
Stakeholders complained that even where a settlement
is reached, the CRB has delayed ruling on the settlement,
655
sometimes adopting the
settlement only after the proceedings were concluded.
656
RIAA also observed that delay
of settlement has frustrated the business plans of services.
657
Music Choice commented
that delays during the voluntary negotiation period leave inadequate time for parties to
conduct rate proceedings.
658
To address these issues, SoundExchange proposed bypassing CRB approval of
settlements by granting the section 112 and 114 designated agent (i.e., SoundExchange)
the authority to enter into opt-in settlement agreements for a statutory license.
659
It
further suggested that the CRB could be required to adopt a negotiated settlement even
if it would not fully resolve a case.
660
SoundExchange also surmised that parties may be
reluctant to settle because the negotiated rate may be used as a benchmark or otherwise
in rate determinations, and suggested that parties be permitted to designate settlements
as non-precedential.
661
Discovery Process c.
Music services criticized the discovery process that applies to ratesetting proceedings
before the CRB on two grounds. First, they observed that because the statute specifies
that discovery occurs only after the submission of the parties’ direct cases—contrary to
the ordinary practice in civil litigation—“parties are required to assume what they will
654
See, e.g., Tr. at 141:16-21 (June 16, 2014) (Tegan Kossowicz, UMG) (“With respect to an earlier
mention of the implementation of CRB settlements, they should be expedited when possible, and
that doesn’t just pertain to both these sections, but as well as other proceedings that we may have
in the future on licensing.”).
655
Tr. at 99:16-100:03 (June 16, 2014) (Brad Prendergast, SoundExchange); Tr. at 129:17-130:03
(June 23, 2014) (Steven Marks, RIAA).
656
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 9 n.12; Tr. at 122:15-22 (June 23, 2014) (Colin
Rushing, SoundExchange).
657
RIAA First Notice Comments at 24-25.
658
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 30.
659
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 9-10.
660
Id. at 9.
661
Id. at 10.
121
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
develop during discovery and hope that relevant information will be voluntarily
revealed by their opponent in the opponent’s written case.”
662
Licensees believe that this
process puts them at a disadvantage, because much of the information regarding
benchmark rates is held by copyright owners.
663
In addition, the statutory procedures
limit discovery to documents directly related to the direct statements.
664
Licensees
suggested that this rule allows copyright owners to behave strategically in their own
direct statement and thus limit discovery.
665
Music providers also complained about the statutory limits on discovery.
666
While
recognizing the hypothetical benefits of a streamlined discovery process, some observed
that there are no actual cost savings and the restrictions are not fair.
667
According to
licensees, the 60-day discovery window is too short,
668
and the statutory limit of 25
interrogatories and 10 depositions for all parties on each side is insufficient.
669
Other
discovery-related suggestions included adoption of a standardized blanket protective
order that would be implemented for “non-public, commercially-sensitive information
produced in discovery and submitted as evidence.”
670
NAB also supported use of the
Federal Rules of Civil Procedure and Federal Rules of Evidence, with slight
modifications, for CRB proceedings.
671
In response to these concerns about discovery, copyright owners argued that the
commenting parties “did not identify any instance in which the Judges believed the
662
DiMA First Notice Comments at 38.
663
See id. at 38-39; Music Choice First Notice Comments at 29-30; Sirius XM First Notice
Comments at 15-16; Tr. at 104:10-105:12 (June 16, 2014) (Gary R. Greenstein, Wilson Sonsini
Goodrich & Rosati).
664
17 U.S.C. § 803(b)(6)(C)(v).
665
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 29; Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 16.
666
See 17 U.S.C. § 803(b)(6).
667
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 29; Tr. at 208:19-209:07 (June 4, 2014) (Lee Knife,
DiMA).
668
DiMA First Notice Comments at 38; see also NAB First Notice Comments at 20 (supporting
longer discovery periods); Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 16-17 (same).
669
DiMA First Notice Comments at 38-39; see also Music Choice First Notice Comments at 30
(“[G]iven the number of witnesses and the number of participants in most proceedings, the
Copyright Act’s limitation on depositions to ten per side (spread between direct and rebuttal
discovery) is clearly insufficient.”).
670
NAB First Notice Comments at 3; Music Choice First Notice Comments at 31 (“The cost of
participation in rate proceedings should not include the risk that confidential business
information may be publicly disclosed. A standardized blanket protective order, similar to that
employed by the Trademark Trial and Appeals Board, would be helpful.”).
671
NAB First Notice Comments at 21.
122
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
current procedures prevented a full record from being developed,”
672
and added that
“open-ended discovery” would add to the complication, expense, or inefficiency of
proceedings.
673
At the same time, copyright owners agreed that conducting discovery
“up front” could be “helpful,” along with eliminating the bifurcated nature of CRB
proceedings.
674
C. Licensing Efficiency and Transparency
1. Music Data
Lack of Reliable Public Data a.
Based on the record in this proceeding, there can be little doubt that the current music
licensing landscape is severely hampered by the lack of publicly accessible, authoritative
identification and ownership data.
675
There are several facets to this problem.
To begin with, there is a lack of comprehensive and reliable ownership data, particularly
for musical works. As RIAA noted, “it is difficult to identify and keep track of musical
work ownership due to changes when musical works and catalogs change hands.”
676
Further complicating the situation is that the rights to musical works are often split
among multiple songwriters, with differing publishers and PROs, making musical work
data harder to track and maintain.
677
In addition, digital music files often do not include the standard identifiers for the
copyrighted works the files embodyi.e., the ISRC for the sound recording and the
ISWC for the underlying musical work.
678
Even when the file includes the ISRC, as is
672
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 10.
673
Tr. at 115:20-116:07 (June 4, 2014) (Steven Marks, RIAA); see also SoundExchange Second Notice
Comments at 10.
674
Tr. at 107:19-108:22 (June 4, 2014) (Steven Marks, RIAA); see also RIAA Second Notice
Comments at 43 (favoring “earlier disclosure of a focused set of critical information”).
675
See, e.g., RIAA First Notice Comments at 17, 20, 22; NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at
10-12; Peter Menell First Notice Comments at 2; CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments
at 28; RMLC First Notice Comments at 7-9; TMLC First Notice Comments at 16; Spotify First
Notice Comments at 11; IPAC Second Notice Comments at 2; Music Licensing Hearings at 71-72
(statement of Jim Griffin, OneHouse LLC).
676
RIAA First Notice Comments at 46.
677
See Spotify First Notice Comments at 4.
678
DiMA Second Notice Comments at 6 (“Neither ISRC Codes nor ISWC Codes are applied to all
works, nor are they applied uniformly or correctly, even when they are attached to work.”); but
compare Tr. at 382:20-22 (June 23, 2014) (Andrea Finkelstein, SME) (“I would say for the majors,
everything that is in digital release has an ISRC associated.”), with MMF & FAC Second Notice
123
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
now commonplace for new releases, the ISWC for the underlying musical work is often
not yet assigned at the time of initial release.
679
And even after an ISWC has been
obtained by the musical work owner, there is no comprehensive, publicly accessible
database that can be used to match the ISRC to the ISWC.
680
Google noted that requiring
licensors to supply data helps to “identify exactly what it is they are licensing . . . both
from a deal implementation standpoint as well as a deal valuation standpoint,” adding
that “those sort of data requirements . . . work their way back up the chain, to the
creators.”
681
Beyond the ISRC and ISWC, there is also a lack of universal and uniform data to identify
songwriters and recording artists associated with individual works. While a global
identifier for creators—the ISNIhas been certified by ISO to replace older systems
employed by the PROs and others, it is not yet widely used.
682
These shortcomings cause serious inefficiencies. Licensees expend significant effort
attempting to identify particular sound recordings and the musical works they embody,
as well as tracking down their copyright owners. Because there is no centralized data
resource, stakeholders devote “significant resources to maintaining redundant and often
inconsistent databases of musical work ownership and split information.”
683
Digital
services noted that the lack of an authoritative source of data exposes even well-
intentioned actors to potential statutory damages for “inadvertently distributing works
without requisite authorization.”
684
According to DiMA, this risk is inequitable because
copyright owners inadequately identify themselves and their works.
685
Comments at 29 (“Contrary to oral testimony to the New York Roundtable in June, the [ISRC] has
not, in our experience, achieved the penetration that is seen with ISWC.”).
679
See Tr. at 336:17-19 (June 23, 2014) (Andrea Finkelstein, SME) (“No, we don’t have ISWCs, and
we certainly don’t have them at that point [when a sound recording is sent to a digital service
provider].”).
680
CCIA Second Notice Comments at 2 (“[A]lthough Industry Standard Recording Codes (ISRCs)
have existed for more than two decades, there is still not a recorded database of them.”); Tr. at
345:05-06 (June 23, 2014) (Andrea Finkelstein, SME) (“There is [an ISRC database] cooking at
SoundExchange.”).
681
Tr. at 53:09-17 (June 23, 2014) (Waleed Diab, Google/YouTube).
682
See Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 5; Tr. at 516:02-09 (June 23, 2014) (Bob Kohn,
Kohn on Music Licensing); Tr. at 558:11-14 (June 23, 2014) (Lynn Lummel, ASCAP); see also ISNI,
http://www.isni.org (last visited Jan. 30, 2015).
683
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 32; see also NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 10-11.
684
Menell First Notice Comments at 2.
685
DiMA First Notice Comments at 17, 29.
124
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Commenters also referenced the recent Pandora rate court decision, in which the court
found that withdrawing publishers did not supply catalog data that would have allowed
Pandora to pull their songs from its service.
686
Some were troubled by this tactic, and
urged that, if this type of publisher withdrawal is allowed, the withdrawing publisher
must be required to “provide immediate transparency as to the musical works that are
no longer subject to license.”
687
On the licensor side of the equation, the lack of reliable data means that royalty
payments may be delayed, misdirected, or never made.
688
SoundExchange highlighted
in particular the problems caused when digital services fail to include standard
identifiers in their reports of usage under the section 112 and 114 statutory licenses. It
explained that basic data elements—featured artist name, track title, album name, and
label name—“simply are not sufficient to distinguish unambiguously among the tens of
millions of recordings actively being commercialized today.
689
Instead, “standard
identifiers are the only practicable way to identify and accurately account for usage of all
those recordings.”
690
RIAA similarly noted that “[a] flourishing musical work licensing marketplace requires
both that potential licensees can get licensed and that royalties flow properly to music
publishers and songwriters,” and that “reliable and accessible information is critical to
making that happen.”
691
NMPA agreed, saying that a “database where we know the
rights” would be valuable.
692
Flawed or missing data is not a problem unique to major
labels or famous artists, and A2IM commented that inaccurate data is “especially
problematic for the independent label community” because it is harder to identify lesser-
known artists without accurate data.
693
686
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 358-60.
687
Spotify First Notice Comments at 11.
688
RIAA First Notice Comments at 46; Music Licensing Hearings at 74-75 (statement of Jim Griffin,
OneHouse LLC).
689
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 25.
690
Id.
691
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 17; see also Music Licensing Hearings at 75 (statement of Jim
Griffin, OneHouse LLC) (“[A]bsent the use of [global universal identifiers] money disappears
along its path to its intended receiver. Where does that money go? To pools of unattributed
income, divided through market share formulas at the organizations that collect the money.”).
692
Tr. 38:05-08 (June 4, 2014) (Brittany Schaffer, NMPA/Loeb & Loeb).
693
A2IM Second Notice Comments at 2.
125
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Parties’ Views b.
In light of the concerns identified above, there appears to be widespread agreement that
authoritative and comprehensive data related to the identity and ownership of works
would substantially enhance transparency in the music licensing system, reduce
transaction costs, and facilitate direct licensing through private negotiation in the open
market.
694
There is, however, less harmony about the best way to achieve this goal.
Some suggested that the government should play a central role. DiMA, for example,
proposed that the Copyright Office create and maintain a music database, while others
called for the Office to identify and publicize data standards, and facilitate or require
submission of such data in the registration or recordation process.
695
Others conceived
of quasi-governmental solutions. FMC stated that Congress might consider creating a
“nonprofit to oversee the development of a global registry database (or databases) that
could be overseen by government, in cooperation with international bodies.”
696
Several
licensees suggested ASCAP and BMI should be required to provide better and more
usable repertoire data.
697
Some proposed more market-based solutions, such as data
expert Jim Griffin’s proposal to emulate the registration system for websites, whereby
the government would engage in standards-setting to encourage the creation of profit-
seeking private registries, similar to domain name registries like GoDaddy.
698
Others groupsprincipally representing copyright ownersbelieved that government
involvement was unnecessary. In NMPA’s view, if the market for creative works were
unregulated and free of governmental price controls (including the section 115 license),
“transactional hubs, syndication platforms and other supply chain management
platforms” would develop to match buyers to sellers and to allocate and distribute
revenues.
699
For their part, the PROs highlighted their online repertoire databases and
efforts such as MusicMark to enhance access to reliable repertoire data.
700
The PROs
694
DiMA Second Notice Comments at 3-4, 7; Tr. at 381:08-11(June 23, 2014) (Waleed Diab,
Google/YouTube).
695
DiMA Second Notice Comments at 5; see also Sirius XM First Notice Comments at 6-7;
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 6; A2IM Second Notice Comments at 2; CCIA
Second Notice Comments at 3.
696
FMC First Notice Comments at 22; see also CFA & Public Knowledge First Notice Comments at
28.
697
NAB Second Notice Comments at 2; CTIA First Notice Comments at 7; DiMA Second Notice
Comments at 6-7.
698
Music Licensing Hearings at 72 (statement of Jim Griffin, OneHouse LLC).
699
NMPA & HFA Second Notice Comments at 3.
700
ASCAP Second Notice Comments at 12-13 (citing “ASCAP’s searchable database, named
ASCAP Clearance Express or ACE, at http://www.ascap.com/ace”); BMI Second Notice
Comments at 9 (citing BMI’s extensive searchable repertoire database at http//www.bmi.com).
126
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
acknowledged that their plans do not include making all of their data available to the
public, however, stressing that they face significant confidentiality concerns.
701
RIAA noted that assignment of ISRCs and ISWCs could be better coordinated (e.g., by
having the record company first recording a new song assign the ISRC and ISWC in
tandem to ensure that the ISWC will be available to relevant stakeholders upon a song’s
release).
702
Stakeholders generally shared the view that such solutions are worth
exploring.
703
Both SoundExchange and RIAA observed that there are fewer problems with sound
recording than musical work data.
704
According to them, sound recording identification
and ownership information is generally available from product packaging, or from
publicly available internet sources such as allmusic.com and discogs.com.
705
Additionally, digital services generally receive metadata from record companies and
distributors providing music files.
706
RIAA pointed out that, unlike musical works,
ownership of sound recordings is rarely divided among multiple co-owners, and record
companies owning commercially significant recordings are less numerous than music
publishers, with less frequent changes in ownership.
707
SoundExchange additionally explained that it maintains robust identification and
ownership information, including ISRCs for approximately 14 million sound
recordings.
708
SoundExchange is actively exploring means by which it might provide
statutory licensees with access to its database for statement of account purposes. For
example, SoundExchange may offer music services the capability to search for ISRCs or
supply music services with ISRCs that are missing from their reports of use.
709
701
Id. at 5; ASCAP Second Notice Comments at 7-8.
702
See, e.g., RIAA Second Notice Comments at 35-36; Tr. at 346:01-349:13 (June 23, 2014) (Lynn
Lummel, ASCAP; Andrea Finkelstein, SME; Jacqueline Charlesworth & Sarang Damle, U.S.
Copyright Office) (discussing assignment of ISRC in relation to ISWC).
703
See, e.g., Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 9; DiMA Second Notice Comments at 6-8;
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 35-36.
704
Id. at 33; SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 4.
705
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 33.
706
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 4; RIAA Second Notice Comments at 33; Tr. at
336:02-12 (June 23, 2014) (Andrea Finkelstein, SME; Sarang Damle, U.S. Copyright Office)
(describing metadata delivered by record companies).
707
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 33.
708
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 4-5.
709
Id. at 5.
127
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
SoundExchange and RIAA together emphasized that licensees operating under the
section 112 and 114 licenses should use available identifying information, particularly
ISRCs, when reporting usage to SoundExchange.
710
Such an obligation would increase
automatic matching of reported usage to known repertoire and facilitate accurate
manual matching when necessary, thus enhancing the data maintained by
SoundExchange.
711
Both parties noted that adoption of such a requirement would
encourage broader use of the ISRC standard.
712
2. Usage and Payment Transparency
Incomplete or inaccurate data frustrates the ability of creators and sellers of music to
track how music is used and what payments are made. Even when accurate data is
available, however, stakeholders had concerns about the effectiveness of music usage
and payment tracking for payment allocation and about the lack of audit rights for
certain licenses. At bottom, the issue in the music industry is that participants want
reassurance that they are being treated fairly by other actors.
713
Advances and Equity Deals a.
There was a growing concern that payments received by record companies and music
publishers from new digital music services as part of direct deals are not being shared
fairly with songwriters and recording artists.
714
SAG-AFTRA and AFM warned that
while direct licensing deals between digital music services and record labels or
publishers may result in more compensation from licensees, direct deals may actually
result in lower payments to artists than under the statutory licensing scheme.
715
710
Id.; RIAA Second Notice Comments at 35.
711
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 5.
712
Id.; RIAA Second Notice Comments at 35. These parties noted that the CRB is currently
considering updates to the relevant notice and recordkeeping regulations.
713
Tr. at 86:01-03 (June 4, 2014) (Brittany Schaffer, NMPA/Loeb & Loeb LLP) (explaining that
“there’s a lack of trust between the record companies and the publishers”); Tr. at 77:15-17 (June
16, 2014) (Eric D. Bull, Create Law) (noting that “there’s such distrust because of the amount of
the money that is going to be exchanged”); Tr. at 14:03-05 (June 17, 2014) (Garry Schyman, SCL)
(“[W]e really don’t trust a publisher who is not in a position to tell us what we are entitled to.”).
714
Resnick Second Notice Comments at 2 (“Spotify alone is reported to have paid hundreds of
millions in dollars in upfront and non-recoupable payments for the privilege of licensing major
label catalogues.”).
715
SAG-AFTRA & AFM First Notice Comments at 7; SAG-AFTRA & AFM Second Notice
Comments at 2 (“Whatever the individual royalty artist’s share, it will not be paid directly, it will
be subject to recoupment, and it will only be verifiable (if at all) through a complex and expensive
individual audit under the royalty contract.”).
128
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
A major objection to direct licensing is that labels and publishers do not necessarily
share advance payments of royalties—in particular, unrecouped advances or “breakage”
monieswith creators.
716
Advance payments of royalties can be significant; Google, for
instance, reportedly paid more than $400 million to WMG under a recent three-year deal
to license the label’s music for YouTube and its subscription offerings.
717
In many cases,
if an advance is not fully recouped (i.e., fully applied to royalties due) by the end of the
license term, the excess fees are retained by the label or publisher rather than returned.
The question is whether these funds are accounted for and paid out by the label or
publisher to its artists or songwriters.
Some record labels and publishers may share unrecouped advances with performers
and writers, but the practice is not universal.
718
And while well-established musicians
may occasionally negotiate a right to collect on breakage,
719
others are not as
successful.
720
Negotiating for these payments can be difficult, as artists and songwriters
are not necessarily aware of deal terms. For example, SGA commented that without the
testimony of an executive representing DMX in a BMI rate court proceeding, the
songwriting community would never have known of a $2.4 million advance paid by
DMX to Sony/ATV.
721
Similarly suspect for creators are equity deals between major labels and digital services.
It has been reported, for instance, that the major labels collectively acquired an 18%
ownership interest in Spotify.
722
Referencing Spotify, as well as YouTube and
Musicmaker, Perry Resnick, who conducts music audits, commented that “[m]any deals
are not done unless the major labels receive a share of equity in the licensee, which also
lowers the royalty rates paid for specific recordings, sometimes down to zero.”
723
There
716
See A2IM Second Notice Comments at 5-6 (defining breakage as “excess revenue that cannot
be attributed to specific recordings or performances and, therefore, is not required to be shared
with artists, songwriters or the actual sound recording copyright owner”); Resnick Second Notice
Comments at 2 (“[E]xcess payments are not shared with recording artists.”).
717
Karp, Artists Press for Their Share.
718
For example, Martin Bandier of Sony/ATV has stated that his company does not share extra
advance money because “there [isn’t] much to share.” Karp, Artists Press for Their Share.
719
A2IM Second Notice Comments at 6; Tr. at 143:08-11 (June 23, 2014) (Richard Bengloff, A2IM).
720
Tr. at 109:13-110:03 (June 5, 2014) (Robert Meitus, Meitus Gelbert Rose LLP).
721
SGA Second Notice Comments at 14-15 (Sony/ATV was also paid $300,000 for administrative
expenses).
722
See Lindvall, Behind the Music: The Real Reason Why the Major Labels Love Spotify.
723
Resnick Second Notice Comments at 2.
129
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
seems to be no reliable practice, however, under which artists and songwriters are
compensated for such equity arrangements.
724
PRO Distributions b.
PROs create value by licensing, administering, and enforcing music creators’ public
performance rights. Yet some songwriters voiced concerns that part of this value is lost
through inaccurate payment allocation. PROs frequently use sampling surveys to
estimate how many times a song has been performed during a payment period, and rely
upon those estimates to allocate royalties among their members.
725
An alternative, and more comprehensive, form of measurement is census reporting,
whereby licensees account for each use of a musical work (e.g., each individual stream)
to the collecting entity. Census reporting is more common for digital services, where it
is easier to track individual performances.
726
ASCAP relies upon census data only when
it is “economically feasible” to process.
727
For many usesincluding terrestrial radio
uses and some digital uses—ASCAP uses a sample survey.
728
BMI similarly relies upon
extrapolated data to pay royalties in many instances.
729
Information concerning
ASCAP’s and BMI’s distribution practices is publicly available on their websites.
730
Some musicians and publishers commented that increased use of census data instead of
surveys would result in more accurate payments by PROs to their members under
blanket licenses. For instance, Music Services stated that survey-based distribution,
particularly for radio and live performances, is “antiquated” and that “[m]any
724
Karp, Artists Press for Their Share.
725
According to one source, “[m]ost performance data is drawn from broadcast sources, under
the assumption that the music being performed over radio and television is roughly the same as
the music being performed in cafes, hotels, sports arenas, . . . restaurants, and nightclubs.” K
OHN
at 1281.
726
See NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 9. For instance, SoundExchange pays almost
entirely on a census basis, and does not generally use sampling. See SoundExchange Second
Notice Comments at 7.
727
ASCAP Payment System: Keeping Track of Performances, ASCAP, http://www.ascap.com/
members/payment/keepingtrack.aspx (last visited Jan. 30, 2014).
728
Payment System: The ASCAP Surveys, ASCAP,
http://www.ascap.com/members/payment/surveys.aspx (last visited Jan. 30, 2014).
729
Royalty Policy Manual, BMI, http://www.bmi.com/creators/royalty_print/detail (last visited Jan.
16, 2015).
730
ASCAP’s Survey and Distribution System: Rules & Policies, ASCAP (June 2014),
http://www.ascap.com/~/media/files/pdf/members/payment/drd.pdf; Royalty Policy Manual, BMI,
http://www.bmi.com/creators/royalty_print/detail (last visited Jan. 16, 2015).
130
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
publishers and writers believe they are not receiving their fair share of the PRO pot.”
731
Other participants observed that under a sampling system, musicians who do not have
“mainstream” songs on the radio are underpaid.
732
Under this view, since sampling is
more likely to identify hit songs, the PRO will likely undercount performances of works
by emerging or fringe musicians.
In response, a representative from ASCAP sympathized, stating “ideally, yes, I wish
everyone would get paid for every performance,” but noted the administrative
impracticality of identifying every use.
733
Others echoed this sentiment, commenting
that even if uses could be precisely tracked, some would be so small that they would not
be payable.
734
Nonetheless, ASCAP notes that[a]s new technologies make surveying a
given medium such as broadcast radio economically efficient, we implement those
technologies to move closer to a full census.”
735
For its part, BMI commented that there
is competition between PROs for members and the market will sufficiently drive
distribution methodologies.
736
Despite these concerns, songwriters generally expressed confidence in the PROs.
737
The
PROs are seen as relatively transparent
738
and as protecting the writer’s share of
performance royalties.
739
SGA noted that “licensing through the PROs . . . has benefited
and given protection to the community of American music creators for over one
hundred years” by “provid[ing] music creators with the crucial assurance that an
important source of revenue will be paid directly to them by the PRO.”
740
Similarly, in
NSAI’s estimation, ASCAP and BMI essentially act as not-for-profit collection arms for
songwriters and composers.”
741
Pass-Through” Licensing c.
As noted above, under section 115, compulsory licensees can authorize third-party
streaming services to transmit downloads and streams of musical works. Songwriters
731
Tr. at 261:20-262:03 (June 5, 2014) (Phil Perkins, Music Services).
732
Tr. at 22:14-25:19 (June 5, 2014) (Royal Wade Kimes, Wonderment Records); see Simpson First
Notice Comments at 2.
733
Tr. at 28:17-29:02 (June 5, 2014) (Sam Mosenkis, ASCAP).
734
Modern Works Music Publishing Second Notice Comments at 6-7.
735
ASCAP Second Notice Comments at 17.
736
BMI Second Notice Comments at 15.
737
Council of Music Creators First Notice Comments at 2-3.
738
SCL First Notice Comments at 11.
739
Music Choice First Notice Comments at 20.
740
SGA First Notice Comments at 7.
741
NSAI Second Notice Comments at 4.
131
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
and publishers complain vigorously about this system.
742
SGA pointed out that pass-
through licensing “creates a situation in which the creators and owners of musical
compositions have no privity of contract with online music distribution giants such as
Apple iTunes, and must therefore rely on sometimes adversarial record company
‘intermediaries’ for the monitoring and payment of royalties earned via online
download usage.”
743
Another commenter explained that “pass-through licensing, where
record labels can license mechanical rights directly on publishers’ behalf and without
publishers’ input, leaves songwriters with no clue as to whether or not they are properly
paid.
744
Stakeholders appear largely to agree that the pass-through approachwhich mimics the
traditional physical model, where record labels ship product to stores and report sales
back to publishers—is unnecessary in the digital environment, since it is feasible for
music owners to have a direct relationship with consumer-facing distributors.
Significantly, even RIAA, a presumed beneficiary of the section 115 pass-through
license, appears to favor the end of pass-through licensing: “The major record
companies generally support in principle the elimination of pass-through licensing . . .
within the context of a structure that makes it unnecessary.”
745
742
ASCAP and BMI also express displeasure with the analogous “through-to-the-audience”
licenses required under the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees, where a party that procures a
license from the PRO is able to authorize transmissions by additional distributors. See ASCAP
Consent Decree § V; BMI Consent Decree § IX. Originally conceived to allow networks to obtain
licenses that extend to downstream broadcasts by affiliates, the concept has been extended to
online services such as YouTube that allow their video content to be shared and embedded on
third-party websites that may be generating revenue through advertisements or otherwise.
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 19. Per ASCAP, “a through-to-the-audience license request can
give unfettered permission to a huge number of users without the benefit of full remuneration to
music creators.” Id. at 20.
743
SGA First Notice Comments at 6-7. In recently promulgated regulations, the Copyright Office
added a new requirement for section 115 licensees that requires them to break down royalty
statements to indicate usage by third-party services, so copyright owners can at least see what is
being reported to the section 115 licensee. 37 C.F.R. §§ 210.16-210.17.
744
LaPolt Second Notice Comments at 11; see also NMPA &HFA First Notice Comments at 12 (“To
the extent compulsory licensees pass through mechanical rights to a third-party digital music
distributor and do not report who the third-party distributor is, songwriters and music
publishers do not even know how their compositions are being used and cannot evaluate the
accuracy of the compulsory licensees reporting.”); Kohn First Notice Comments at 9 (“Pass-
through licenses, at least insofar as they apply to digital transmission, should be eliminated.”).
745
RIAA Second Notice Comments at 19.
132
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
IV. Analysis and Recommendations
It may be the very power of music that has led to its disparate treatment under the law.
The songs we enjoy in our early years resonate for the rest of our lives. Human beings
have a deep psychological attachment to music that often seems to approach a sense of
ownership; people want to possess and share the songs they love. Perhaps this passion
is one of the reasons music has been subject to special treatment under the law.
Regardless of what has animated our century-old embrace of government regulation of
music, the Copyright Office believes that the time is ripe to question the existing
paradigm and consider meaningful change. In recent years, we have seen piecemeal
efforts to address particular issues through focused legislation: there have been bills
directed to the lack of a terrestrial performance right for sound recordings, ratesetting
inequities, and payment for pre-1972 sound recordings. Each has targeted a specific
issue or issues within the existing system. In the current environment, however, these
sorts of limited proposals—standing alone—seem unlikely to generate broad enough
support to become law. It is for this reason, perhaps, that some members of Congress
have recently indicated interest in a more holistic approach.
746
How ambitious should any such approach be? As a number of commenters remarked
during the course of this study, if we were to do it all again, we would never design the
system that we have today. But as tempting as it may be to daydream about a new
model built from scratch, such a course would seem to be logistically and politically
unrealistic. We must take the world as we find it, and seek to shape something new
from the material we have on hand.
In this section, based on the information and commentary gathered in the study, the
Office analyzes critical areas of concern and—considering the record and merits of
disparate viewpoints—suggests ways to reshape our music licensing system to better
meet the demands of the digital era. Following a discussion of the role of government in
the music marketplace, the Office outlines a series of interrelated changes that might be
implemented to modernize our struggling system. The recommendations below seek to
capitalize on the value that existing institutions and methods could continue to provide
under an updated framework.
Rather than presenting a detailed plan, the Office’s recommendations should be
understood as high-level and preliminary in nature—more of a sketch than a completed
picture. It is also important that the proposals be contemplated together, rather than in
746
See, e.g., Daryl P. Friedman, MusicBus Gaining Speed as Members of Congress Climb On,
GRAMMY
NEWS (June 18, 2014), http://www.grammy.com/blogs/musicbus-gaining-speed-as-
members-of-congress-climb-on (noting support for omnibus legislation by Rep. Jerrold Nadler,
Rep. Kevin McCarthy and Rep. Nancy Pelosi).
133
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
isolation. The Office seeks to present a series of balanced tradeoffs among the interested
parties to create a fairer, more efficient, and rational system for all.
A. Guiding Principles
The Copyright Office appreciates and agrees with the four grounding principles that
were articulated by many during the course of this study, as discussed above. These are:
Music creators should be fairly compensated for their contributions
The licensing process should be more efficient
Market participants should have access to authoritative data to identify and
license sound recordings and musical works
Usage and payment information should be transparent and accessible to
rightsowners
As much as there may be consensus on these points, however, the opposite could be said
of stakeholders’ views as to how best to achieve them. Having considered the plethora
of issues that plague our current licensing systemand how they might practically be
addressed—the Office has identified some additional principles that it believes should
also guide any process of reform. These are:
Government licensing processes should aspire to treat like uses of music alike
Government supervision should enable voluntary transactions while still
supporting collective solutions
Ratesetting and enforcement of antitrust laws should be separately managed and
addressed
A single, market-oriented ratesetting standard should apply to all music uses
under statutory licenses
Each of these principles is explored below in the context of the Office’s overall
recommendations.
B. Licensing Parity and Fair Compensation
Questions of licensing parity and fair compensation are closely tied to the relative
treatment of music rights and rightsholders under the law.
747
The Office believes that
747
During the course of the study, the Office and others employed the term “platform parity” in
referencing the concern that existing licensing policies have a disparate impact on different
distribution platforms. The Office now adopts the broader term “licensing parity” in recognition
134
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
any overhaul of our music licensing system should strive to achieve greater consistency
in the way it regulates (or does not regulate) analogous platforms and uses. In addition
to rewarding those distribution models that are most resource-efficient and appealing to
consumers, evenhanded treatment will encourage more equitable compensation for
creators.
From today’s vantage point, at least, the impact of our current system on different
classes of copyright owners and users—favoring some while disadvantaging others
seems to be more the product of historical happenstance than conscious design. To the
extent our policies require copyright owners to subsidize certain business models
through reduced royalties, as copyright owners claim, this is not the result of a present-
day judgment that it is a fair way to treat creators, or promotes the values of our
copyright system. The same can be said of policies that impose higher royalty
obligations on one business model over competing platforms.
The policy rationales that animated the creation of the section 115 compulsory license,
the PRO consent decrees, and even the section 112 and 114 framework for digital
performances, are now decades behind us. The Office believes that the current
widespread perception that the system is outmoded and broken may provide an
opportunity to review and rationalize the playing field.
1. Equitable Treatment of Rights and Uses
As suggested above, the Copyright Office believes that an important element of a robust
and fair music marketplace is to treat equivalent uses of sound recordings and musical
worksand competing platforms—alike, or as alike as can practically be achieved.
Musical Works Versus Sound Recordings a.
Which is more important, the song or the sound recording? “It all begins with a song,”
runs the oft-cited refrain;
748
but then again, the song is brought to life through a sound
recording. While there is, of course, no definitive answer to this question, as reflected
throughout this report, the law nonetheless treats sound recordings and musical works
differently.
In the case of noninteractive streaming uses, sound recordings are subject to compulsory
licensing at government-set rates. But apart from this, sound recordings are licensed by
their owners in the free market.
of the fact that the current licensing framework also disparately impacts different classes of
copyright owners and creators.
748
NSAI, http://www.nashvillesongwriters.com (last visited Jan. 18, 2015).
135
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
As for musical works, while synch uses (including consumer-generated videos) are not
subject to government oversight,
749
the other core segments of the market (mechanical
reproduction and performance uses) are regulated. As indicated above, a recurring
complaint from publishers and songwriters is that significantly higher rates are paid for
sound recordings than for musical works in the online worldwhether the musical
work rates are set by the CRB or by one of the rate courts. At least some of this disparity
appears to arise from publishers’ inability to negotiate free from government constraint
where record companies can.
In keeping with the guiding philosophy that government should aspire to treat like uses
of music alike, the Office believes this should change, at least in the digital realm. That
is, where sound recording owners have the ability to negotiate digital rates in the open
market, so should owners of musical works.
Although the path to enabling this type of parity is complicated by the divergent
licensing frameworks for mechanical and performance rights on the musical work side,
the Office’s approach would offer a free market alternative to musical work owners, in
the form of an opt-out right, in the most significant areas where sound recording owners
enjoy unfettered digital rights—namely, interactive streaming uses and downloads.
And where sound recording owners are subject to statutory ratesettingi.e., in the case
of noninteractive streamingmusical works would remain regulated. To further
promote uniformity of approach, as discussed below, the Office is recommending that
all music ratesetting activities—whether on the sound recording or musical work side
take place before the CRB.
The Office believes that treating analogous uses alike in the digital environment is more
likely to yield equitable rates as between sound recordings and musical worksor will
at least make that goal more attainable.
750
This does not mean that the Office assumes
749
While synch uses by consumer video sites such as YouTube are not subject to compulsory
licensing, the degree of copyright owner control with respect to sites featuring user-posted
content is complicated by the safe harbor provisions of section 512, which limit such sites’
liability for hosting the content.
750
While the same argument can of course be made with respect to physical formats such as CDs
and vinyl recordswhere labels also have the freedom to negotiate and publishers do notin
pursuing issues of fair compensation, stakeholders appear overwhelmingly to be concerned with
digital, rather than physical, uses. Likely this is because they are looking to the future, and the
future is digital. In addition, even though section 115 applies to both digital and physical uses,
the licensing situation for physical goods is somewhat distinguishable. Most physical goods are
in album format, and thus generate significantly higher mechanical revenues by virtue of their
inclusion of multiple songs. Additionally, because the first use of a musical work is not subject to
compulsory licensing, publishers have the right to demand a higher than statutory rate when
licensing the original recordingat least in theory; for reasons that are not entirely clear, it
appears that publishers almost never exercise this option. See RIAA First Notice Comments at 16
136
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
that the rates for sound recordings and musical works necessarily should be equal.
Rather, the goal is to encourage evenhanded consideration of both rates by a single
body, under a common standard, to achieve a fair result.
The benefits of parallel treatment would not be limited to licensing at government-set
rates. Where a music publisher had chosen to opt out of the statutory license to
negotiate a direct deal, both the publisher and the sound recording owner would have
the same ability to make their case to the licensee. The licensee would then be in a
position to assess the value of each right and proceed accordingly, as happens in the
synch market today.
Finally, such an approach would also allow for the possibility of achieving an all-in
rate—and simplified rate structure—covering both sound recordings and musical works
for noninteractive uses under the section 112 and 114 licenses (including terrestrial
radio, which the Office proposes be brought under those licenses, as discussed below).
751
As suggested by the record labels, it might be possible for labels and publishers to agree
to a royalty split as between them—or have the split set in an initial phase of a CRB
proceedingand then proceed together as allies in litigating the rates to be paid by
statutory licensees.
752
n.31 (stating that “the system should recognize the reality that songwriters and publishers have
always chosen to license first uses at the same royalty rates as other recordings and allow that to
happen by means of the same business processes”); see also Tr. at 251:07-252:04 (June 4, 2014)
(Brittany Schaffer, NMPA/Loeb & Loeb LLP) (explaining that standard record agreement
provisions, such as controlled composition clauses, often prevent publishers and songwriters
from negotiating first use rates higher than the compulsory rate). Unlike in the digital realm,
once the original recording is released by the record company, it is not nearly as common for
third parties to seek a mechanical license to reproduce and distribute that same recording in a
physical format. For these reasonsas well as the scant record before the Office concerning
physical productthe Office believes that the question of whether the proposed opt-out right
should extend to physical uses is perhaps best left for future consideration.
751
Both digital music services and record companies have urged the Office to consider such an
approach. DiMA First Notice Comments at 25 (noting that “[i]n an ideal world, services that
require a combination of musical work public performance rights, as well as reproduction and
distribution rights under Section 115, would be able to acquire such rights from a single licensing
source under a single statutory license and pay a single royalty to a common agent”); Spotify
First Notice Comments at 10 (stating that “[a] licensing regime in which public performance
rights and mechanical reproduction rights could be obtained from a single source or pursuant to
a single license is an interesting idea and could in theory lead to efficiencies”); RIAA First Notice
Comments at 16-17 (supporting single blanket license covering all rights in a song).
752
If such an approach were adopted, some thought would need to be given as to whether and
how a separate settlement would be accommodated on the part of the sound recording owners or
musical work owners once the ratesetting aspect of the proceeding was underway.
137
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Terrestrial Radio b.
In the case of terrestrial radio, federal law exempts what is currently a 17-billion dollar
industry
753
from paying those who contribute the sound recordings that are responsible
for its success.
754
Apart from being inequitable to rightsholdersincluding by curtailing
the reciprocal flow of such royalties into the United States—the exemption of terrestrial
radio from royalty obligations harms competing satellite and internet radio providers
who must pay for the use of sound recordings. In a world that is more and more about
performance and less about record sales, the inability to obtain a return from terrestrial
radio increases the pressure on paying sources. The market-distorting impact of the
terrestrial radio exemption probably cannot be overstated.
The Office has long supported the creation of a full sound recording performance right,
advocating for Congress to expand the existing right so it is commensurate with the
performance right afforded to other classes of works under federal copyright law.
755
As
one of the few remaining industrialized countries that does not recognize a terrestrial
radio performance right, the United States stands in stark contrast to peer nations.
756
In
her recent testimony before Congress, the Register of Copyrights described the
753
According to figures from the Radio Advertising Bureau, radio revenues have increased each
year since 2009, when revenues were $16,029,000,000, to 2013, when revenues totaled
$17,649,000,000an increase of nearly 10%. RAB Revenue Releases, R
ADIO ADVERTISING BUREAU,
http://www.rab.com/public/pr/rev-pr.cfm?search=2013&section=press (click on “Annual Radio
Revenue Trends”) (last visited Jan. 22, 2015).
754
Although the Copyright Act exempts terrestrial performances of sound recordings, following
recent judicial decisions in California and New Yorkwhich interpreted those states’ laws as
supporting a right of public performance for sound recording ownersit is not clear that over-
the-air broadcasters enjoy a complete exemption under state law. See Flo & Eddie v. Sirius XM CA,
2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 139053; Capitol Records, LLC v. Sirius XM Radio Inc., No. BC520981 (order
regarding jury instruction); Flo & Eddie v. Sirius XM NY, 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 166492. Although
those cases were brought against digital providers, the courts’ reasoning does not appear to be
limited to digital performance rights.
755
See, e.g., Performance Rights Act Hearing (statement of Marybeth Peters, Register of Copyrights);
Ensuring Artists Fair Compensation Hearing (statement of Marybeth Peters, Register of Copyrights);
Internet Streaming of Radio Hearing at 8-22 (statement of David O. Carson, General Counsel, U.S.
Copyright Office); P
ERFORMANCE RIGHTS REPORT at 57-58.
756
See Public Performance Right for Sound Recordings, FUTURE OF MUSIC COALITION (Nov. 5, 2013),
https://www.futureofmusic.org/article/fact-sheet/public-performance-right-sound-recordings;
A2IM First Notice Comments at 8; Modern Works Music Publishing First Notice Comments at 7;
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 16-17. Supporters of a more complete terrestrial
sound recording performance right point out that the U.S. position on this is “in contrast to
nearly every developed nation on the planet [with] notable exceptions includ[ing] Iran and North
Korea.” FMC First Notice Comments at 14; see also The Register’s Call for Updates Hearing at 3
(statement of Rep. Melvin L. Watt).
138
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
terrestrial performance right issue as “ripe for resolution,”
757
recommending that any
congressional efforts to update the Copyright Act include a legislative answer.
758
Radio broadcasters argue that a sound recording performance royalty would unfairly
impose a “tariff” to subsidize the recording industry at the expense of broadcasters—in
their opinion, the limited performance right and lack of royalties in terrestrial radio have
not impacted the “growth or supremacy of the United States recording industry.”
759
This argument would seem to ring hollow, however, given the current challenges faced
by that industry.
Radio broadcasters also point to the promotional effect of traditional airplay on sales of
sound recordings as a reason for maintaining the status quo. Undoubtedly, sound
recording owners recognize value in radio airplay, in particular for new releases.
760
But
any such value must be considered and weighed in the context of the overall earnings of
the broadcast industry. Significantly, as consumer preferences shift away from music
ownership, the potential for sales is becoming less relevant, and the promotional value
of radio less apparent.
In this regard, the creation of a terrestrial sound recording performance right need not
overlook or negate the question of promotional value, because this factor can be taken
into account by a ratesetting authority, or in private negotiations, to arrive at an
appropriate royalty rate. Such an approach would appear to be a rational solution
because it seems fair to assume that a willing buyer and willing seller would do the
same.
761
757
The Register’s Call for Updates Hearing at 7 (statement of Maria A. Pallante, Register of
Copyrights and Director, U.S. Copyright Office); Maria A. Pallante, The Next Great Copyright Act,
36 C
OLUM. J. L. & ARTS 315, 320-21 (2013).
758
The Register’s Call for Updates Hearing at 63 (statement of Maria A. Pallante, Register of
Copyrights and Director, U.S. Copyright Office).
759
NAB First Notice Comments at 29.
760
Although the practice of “payola”whereby record companies pay radio stations to play
certain recordingshas been banned, labels still devote resources to encouraging broadcasters to
perform their songs. See GAO
REPORT at 50 (explaining that although “payola” has been formally
outlawed unless the station announces any arrangements to play songs in exchange for
consideration, it is common industry practice for record companies to employ independent
promoters).
761
Interestingly, despite the lack of legal recognition for such a right, there has been forward
movement on this issue in the private marketplace. Media conglomerate iHeartMedia (formerly
Clear Channel)which offers both terrestrial and streamed radiohas entered into voluntary
license agreements with WMG and a number of smaller record labels that cover both digital and
terrestrial performance rights (with the digital rates apparently more favorable to iHeartMedia
than those established by the CRB). See Christman, Here’s Why Warner Music’s Deal with Clear
139
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Pre-1972 Sound Recordings c.
Another area where the law diverges in the way it treats sound recordings and musical
works is the lack of federal protection for pre-1972 sound recordings, many of which
remain commercially valuable. This, too, impedes a fair marketplace. Satellite and
internet radio services appear to rely heavily on pre-1972 recordings in curating their
playlists, presumably because (at least until recent court rulings) these selections have
been viewed as free from copyright liability on the sound recording side.
762
At the same
time, the owners of the musical works embodied in these sound recordings are paid for
the same uses.
The Office is of the view that pre-1972 recordings should be brought under the
protection of federal copyright law. Such a change would serve the interests of licensing
parity by eliminating another market distortion. In addition, it would allow for a federal
compensation mechanism for the artists responsible for pre-1972 works.
In 2009, Congress instructed the Office to conduct a study on the “desirability and
means” of extending federal copyright protection to pre-1972 sound recordings.
763
After
considering input from stakeholders, the Office concluded that pre-1972 sound
recordings should be brought under federal copyright law with the same rights,
exceptions, and limitations as sound recordings created on or after February 15, 1972.
764
In the Office’s view, full federalization of pre-1972 sound recordings (with special
provisions to address ownership issues, terms of protection, and registration) would
improve the certainty and consistency of copyright law, encourage more preservation
Channel Could be Groundbreaking for the Future of the U.S. Music Biz (Analysis); Sisario, Clear
Channel-Warner Music Deal Rewrites the Rules on Royalties. Reportedly, iHeartMedia was
motivated to do this by its desire to have a more predictable cost structure to grow the digital
side of its business. Id. Such a step may point to the potential for broader industry compromise
on this issue.
762
Tr. at 183:07-18 (June 24, 2014) (Jim Mahoney, A2IM) (“One only need to turn on Sirius XM
and see the many stations that programmed fully with pre-1972 copyright songs, recordings and
conclude that they still have value to listeners. They still want to hear those songs a lot. To
programmers who program multiple stations there’s a 40’s station, a 50’s station, a 60’s station.
There’s classic rock, all the pre-1972 sound recordings. So, the public still values them,
corporations still value them. They should still maintain a value for the recording artists.”).
763
Specifically, Congress directed the Office to discuss: “(1) the effect that federal protection
would have with respect to the preservation of pre-1972 sound recordings; (2) the effect that
federal protection would have with respect to providing public access to the recordings; and (3)
the impact that federal protection would have on the economic interests of right holders of the
recordings” and to provide appropriate recommendations. P
RE-1972 SOUND RECORDINGS REPORT
at vii.
764
Id. at viii.
140
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
and access activities, and provide the owners of pre-1972 sound recordings with the
benefits of any future amendments to the Copyright Act.
765
The Office has not changed its mind. Indeed, since the Office issued its 2011 report,
there have been significant developments under both California and New York state law
which underscore the need for a unified federal approach to sound recordings. As a
result of lawsuits brought by pre-1972 sound recording owners against Sirius XM and
Pandora, there have been trial court decisions in California and New York upholding
claims that performances of the plaintiffs’ sound recordings in those jurisdictions are
protected under applicable state law.
766
Subject to any further judicial developments,
this means that the defendant services need to obtain licenses from sound recording
owners to perform the recordings. But because the requirement to do so is based on
state, rather than federal law, users may not rely upon the section 112 and 114 licenses
for this purpose.
The legal question of state protection of pre-1972 sound recording performance rights
will undoubtedly continue to percolate in other states as well.
767
In addition, there is the
significant related question of whether and how the pre-1972 rulings may be applied to
performances by terrestrial broadcasters, which of course currently enjoy an exemption
under federal law. This aspect of the story has yet to unfold.
In the last Congress, SoundExchange, joined by others, pursued legislation known as the
RESPECT Act that would expand the jurisdiction of that organization to collect royalties
for pre-1972 performances and provide a safe harbor from state liability for paying
services.
768
But this proposed amendment to federal law would not offer the full
panoply of federal copyright protection to pre-1972 rightsowners, nor would it allow for
application of the DMCA safe harbors or rights-balancing exceptions such as fair use. In
addition, there are important policy considerations relating to the preservation of older
works and access to “out-of-print” recordings still subject to state protection that the
RESPECT Act does not address. For these reasons, while the Copyright Office
recognizes the potential value of enacting a relatively expedient fix to make sure older
artists get paid and to eliminate liability concerns of digital services seeking to exploit
765
Id. at ix-x.
766
See Flo & Eddie v. Sirius XM CA, 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 139053; Capitol Records, LLC v. Sirius XM
Radio Inc., No. BC520981 (order regarding jury instructions); Flo & Eddie v. Sirius XM NY, 2014
U.S. Dist. LEXIS 166492, reconsideration denied, 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 174907.
767
Paul Resnikoff, What the pre-1972 Decision Really Means for the Future of Radio . . . ., DIGITAL
MUSIC NEWS (Oct. 13, 2014), http://www.digitalmusicnews.com/permalink/2014/10/13/pre-1972-
decision-really-means-future-radio-2 (noting pending litigation by Flo & Eddie (of the band The
Turtles) against Sirius XM in Florida, in addition to suits in California and New York).
768
RESPECT Act § 2.
141
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
pre-1972 recordings, it continues to believe that full federalization remains the best
alternative.
2. Consistent Ratesetting Standards
Where the government has stepped in to establish rates for the use of music, it has
likewise acted in an inconsistent fashion. While in some cases the law provides that the
ratesetting authority should attempt to emulate the free market, in other cases it imposes
a more policy-oriented approach.
769
In this regard, the ratesetting standards under the section 112 and 114 licenses have been
a persistent source of unhappiness for both music owners and users. This is hardly
surprising, as these licenses prescribe different rate standards for competing platforms—
internet radio versus satellite radio—thus allowing both sides to complain.
Satellite radio and “pre-existing” subscription services (such as those provided through
cable television) are able to benefit from the four-factor section 801(b)(1) test, which
allows the CRB to ponder broader concerns than what negotiating parties might
consider in the marketplace—for example, whether a contemplated rate will result in
“disruptive impact on the structure of the industries involved and on generally
prevailing industry practices.”
770
Many interpret the section 801(b)(1) language as
enabling the ratesetting body to protect the vested interests of licensees by establishing
rates lower than what would (at least theoretically) prevail in the free market.
Rates for the reproduction and distribution of musical works in digital and physical
formats are also set under the more policy-oriented 801(b)(1) standard. This is a
significant point of contention for music publishers and songwriters, who have been
lobbying for legislation to substitute the willing buyer/willing seller standard.
771
By contrast, rates paid by internet radio services are set by the CRB according to a
“willing buyer/willing seller” rate standard. Most perceive the willing buyer/willing
seller standard to be more market-oriented in its approach.
772
But internet radio
providers have twice taken their case to Congress to override the rates set by the CRB
769
See “Existing Ratesetting Framework” chart, Appendix D, for a depiction of the current
ratesetting standards and bodies.
770
17 U.S.C. § 801(b)(1)(D).
771
See SEA, H.R. 4079.
772
See EMF First Notice Comments at 6, 8 n.14 (noting negotiated agreements are rare for
webcasters, but noncommercial rates were successfully negotiated before a final decision in
Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings and Ephemeral Recordings, 76 Fed. Reg. 13,026
(Mar. 9, 2011)).
142
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
under that rubric,
773
and Congress has given them the opportunity to negotiate
substitute agreements with SoundExchange.
774
As for public performance rights in musical works, by virtue of the consent decrees,
ASCAP and BMI are subject to a “reasonable fee” approach, which seeks to approximate
hypothetical “fair market value.”
775
Though the term “reasonable fee” is not defined in
either consent decree, each places the burden of proof on the PRO to establish that its
proposed rates are reasonable.
776
The PROs attempt to meet this burden by offering
negotiated rates as benchmarks, economic evidence that may or may not be accepted by
the court after considering its relevance—often through the lens of quasi-antitrust
analysis.
777
While there are those who might argue that the particular wording of a discretionary
rate standard will not have much impact on a results-oriented tribunal, there is at least
some evidence to the contrary. For example, in 2008, in establishing rates for satellite
radio services, the CRB found it “appropriate to adopt a rate . . . that is lower than the
upper boundary most strongly indicated by marketplace data,” stating that they did so
“in order to satisfy 801(b) policy considerations related to the minimization of disruption
that are not adequately addressed by the benchmark market data alone.”
778
In any
event, there appears to be a shared perception among many industry participantsboth
those that chafe at the section 801(b)(1) standard and those that like it—that the standard
yields lower rates.
779
773
Small Webcaster Settlement Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-321, 116 Stat. 2780 (2002) (codified as
amended at 17 U.S.C. § 114(f) (2010)); Webcaster Settlement Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-435, 122
Stat. 4974 (2008) (codified as amended at 17 U.S.C. § 114(f) (2010)).
774
17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(3)(B).
775
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 353-54; see also BMI v. DMX, Inc., 726 F. Supp. 2d 355, 356
(S.D.N.Y. 2010) (citing “well-established” reasonable fee approach to determine fair market
value).
776
BMI v. DMX, 683 F.3d at 45 n.14 (noting in both the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees, the
burden of proof is on the PRO to establish the reasonableness of the fee it seeks).
777
United States v. BMI, 316 F. 3d 189, 194 (2d Cir. 2003) (“This determination [of whether a rate is
reasonable] is often facilitated by the use of a benchmarkthat is, reasoning by analogy to an
agreement reached after arms’ length negotiation between similarly situated parties.”); see also
ASCAP v. MobiTV, 681 F. 3d at 82 (“In [setting a rate], the rate-setting court must take into
account the fact that ASCAP, as a monopolist, exercises market-distorting power in negotiations
for the use of its music.”).
778
Determination of Rates and Terms for Preexisting Subscription Services and Satellite Digital
Audio Radio Services, 73 Fed. Reg. 4080, 4097 (Jan. 24, 2008).
779
See, e.g., DiMA First Notice Comments at 33-34 (noting relatively higher rates under the willing
buyer/willing seller standard); NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 27 (“Pandora . . . paid
143
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The Office believes that all government ratesetting processes should be conducted under
a single standard, especially since the original justifications for differential treatment of
particular uses and business models appear to have fallen away. There is no longer a
threatened piano roll monopoly, and satellite radio is a mature business. Further,
however that single rate standard is formulatedi.e., whether it is articulated as
“willing buyer/willing seller” or “fair market value”it should be designed to achieve
to the greatest extent possible the rates that would be negotiated in an unconstrained
market. To the extent that it enumerates specific factors, they should be ones that might
reasonably be considered by copyright proprietors and licensees in the real world. In
the Office’s view, there is no policy justification to demand that music creators subsidize
those who seek to profit from their works.
Under such a unified standard, the CRB or other ratesetting body would be encouraged
to consider all potentially useful benchmarksincluding for analogous uses of related
rights (e.g., fees paid for the comparable use of sound recordings when considering
musical work rates
780
)—in conducting its analysis. But again, it should take into account
only those factors that might be expected to influence parties who negotiated rates in the
open market. These might include, for example, the substitutional impact of one model
on other sources of revenue, or whether a service may promote sales of sound
recordings or musical works through other channels.
781
But upon arriving at rates
believed to reflect what would be agreed in the open market, those rates would not be
discounted on the basis of abstract policy concerns such as “disruptive” impact on
48% of its revenue to artists and labels using the willing buyer willing seller standard and only
4% of its revenue to publishers and songwriters using rates set by the rate court.”); Spotify First
Notice Comments at 7.
780
But see Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings and Ephemeral Recordings, 72 Fed.
Reg. 24,084, 24,094-95 (May 1, 2007) (musical work benchmark rejected as being “flawed” for
sound recordings because the sellers were different and selling different rights, use of the
benchmark would ignore the different investments and incentives of the each seller, and the
record contained ample empirical evidence that the markets were not necessarily equivalent);
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 333, 366-67 (court declined to use royalty rates for sound
recordings as a benchmark, explaining, “[t]he disparity between rates for the public performance
of compositions versus sound recordings does not exist for most of ASCAP’s revenue streams
since . . . the need to acquire sound recording licenses only applies to services who conduct
digital audio transmissions”; for those digital audio transmissions, whose rates are set by the
CRB, there is a “statutory prohibition on considering sound recording rates in setting a rate for a
license for public performance of a musical work”; and otherwise “the record is devoid of any
principled explanation given . . . why the rate for sound recording rights should dictate any
change in the rate for composition rights”).
781
As expressed in section 114, the willing buyer/willing seller standard includes consideration of
several specific factors, including these. See 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(2)(B).
144
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
prevailing industry practices or solicitude for existing business models notwithstanding
their competitive viability in the marketplace.
C. Role of Government in Music Licensing
Government regulation of music has focused on the interrelated concerns of access,
pricing and competition. As noted above, section 115—the first compulsory license in
our copyright law—was enacted to prevent a single piano roll company from exercising
exclusive control over song copyrights. The PRO consent decrees are the result of the
government’s attempt to balance the efficiencies of collective licensing with concerns
about anticompetitive conduct. More recently, Congress chose to extend the public
performance right for digital uses of sound recordings on the condition that certain of
those uses would be subject to compulsory licensing under sections 112 and 114 of the
Copyright Act, thus further extending the practice of regulatory oversight.
As a result of these policy determinations, an administrative tribunal, the CRB, sets the
fees paid for the reproduction and distribution of musical works, as well as the royalties
due for radio-style digital performance of sound recordings. Two federal judges in New
York City are responsible for establishing the fees for the public performance of musical
works across traditional and digital platforms. For better or worse, these decades-old
regimes are deeply embedded in our licensing infrastructure.
782
Viewed in the abstract, it is almost hard to believe that the U.S. government sets prices
for music. In todays world, there is virtually no equivalent for this type of federal
interventionat least outside of the copyright arena.
783
The closest example is the
retransmission by cable and satellite providers of copyrighted television programming
(including the music embodied in that programming), which is also subject to
compulsory licensing under the Copyright Act and government-set rates.
784
But
782
Notably, in the deliberations leading to the adoption of the 1976 Act, then Register of
Copyrights Abraham L. Kaminstein recommended elimination of the section 115 compulsory
license, concluding that the underlying concerns about a publisher monopoly were no longer
relevant. See G
ENERAL REVISION OF COPYRIGHT REPORT at 36. Publishers did not ultimately
pursue that opportunity, however, instead agreeing to maintain the compulsory license in
exchange for a statutory rate hike from 2 to 2.75 cents per use. See Music Licensing Reform Hearing
(statement of Marybeth Peters, Register of Copyrights); S.
REP. NO. 94-473, at 88-92.
783
Outside of the copyright context, rare instances of government price-fixing involve
commodities, not differentiated goods. The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission conducts a
ratesetting process for interstate transmission of electricity and natural gas, see 16 U.S.C. § 824d-e;
15 U.S.C. § 717c-d, and the United States Department of Agriculture issues federal milk
marketing orders that set minimum (not maximum) prices for the sale of milk in most regions of
the United States, see 7 U.S.C. § 608c(5).
784
17 U.S.C. §§ 111, 119, 122; see also U.S. COPYRIGHT OFFICE, SATELLITE TELEVISION EXTENSION AND
LOCALISM ACT: § 302 REPORT 129-40 (2011), available at http://www.copyright.gov/reports/
145
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
retransmission rights represent a much more limited segment of the overall revenues for
the television industry than do the core music markets subject to government
ratesetting, and even there, broadcasters are permitted separately to negotiate non-
government-controlled fees for access to the signals that carry the copyrighted works.
785
1. Antitrust Considerations
As explained above in discussing the section 115 statutory license and PRO consent
decrees, much of the rationale—indeed, the original rationalefor government
regulation of the music marketplace revolves around antitrust concerns. The
government has long wanted to ensure that the market is not unduly influenced by
monopoly power. Thus, Congress’ uneasiness with the dominant position of the
Aeolian piano roll company in 1909 led it to enact a compulsory license for musical
works so others could compete with that company.
Concerns about potential monopoly effects are heightened when would-be competitors
decide on the prices to be charged for products that are or are required to be purchased
together, as is the case when musical works are licensed by multiple owners on a blanket
basis through ASCAP or BMI. The government, however, including the Supreme Court,
has acknowledged the social benefits of this type of collective blanket licensing, and has
endorsed it under a “rule of reason” approach rather than finding it per se unlawful.
786
But the government has also, since the World War II era, subjected ASCAP and BMI to
extensive regulation under their respective consent decrees.
It is worth noting that the longevity of these two decrees represents a rather extreme
exception to the modern DOJ guidelines which, since 1979, have required that such
decrees terminate, generally after a period of no longer than ten years.
787
More recently,
in March 2014, the DOJ announced a policy to facilitate the “fast track” review and
termination of most perpetual or “legacy” decrees.
788
Under that policy, the DOJ will
section302-report.pdf (“STELA REPORT”) (recommending ways in which the cable and satellite
compulsory retransmission licenses might be phased out).
785
See 47 U.S.C. § 325 (defining retransmission consent rights).
786
BMI v. CBS, 441 U.S. at 23-25 (holding that the blanket license should be subject to rule of
reason analysis and remanding to lower courts to apply that analysis); CBS v. ASCAP, 620 F.2d at
932 (on remand from Supreme Court, sustaining blanket license under rule of reason analysis
because CBS had failed to prove the non-availability of alternatives to the blanket license); Buffalo
Broad. v. ASCAP, 744 F.2d at 926-32 (sustaining blanket license under rule of reason analysis in
context of local television stations).
787
U.S. DOJ, ANTITRUST DIV., ANTITRUST DIV. MANUAL III 146-47 (5th ed. 2014), available at http://
www. justice.gov/atr/public/divisionmanual/atrdivman.pdf.
788
Id. (explaining that the DOJ’s adoption of a policy that favors sunset provisions was “based on
a judgment that perpetual decrees were not in the public interest”). In addition to policy
146
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
“advise courts that pre-1980 ‘legacy’ decrees, except in limited circumstances, are
presumptively no longer in the public interest.”
789
The DOJ has suggested, however,
that among those “limited circumstances” is “when there is a long-standing reliance by
industry participants on the decree.”
790
The revised DOJ policy would thus appear to
exclude the PRO decrees.
The word “monopoly” came up many times in the written and oral presentations of
participants in this study in discussing the continuing significance of the decrees and
antitrust oversight. But it is important to understand that there are two distinct types of
“monopoly” being referenced, and each requires separate analysis.
The first type of “monopoly” refers to alleged anticompetitive practices on the part of
the PROs, and also sometimes of the major publishers and record labels with significant
market share. Here the concern is that licensees—for example, a television network or
online service—have insufficient leverage to negotiate appropriate licensing fees with
the licensor.
791
Excessive market power is the linchpin of antitrust analysis, whether in a
government-initiated enforcement action or private litigation;
792
typically, howeverand
as discussed below in connection with the Pandora litigationthe remedies for civil
concerns, there may be some interesting due process questions concerning the length of the
consent decrees.
789
Press Release, U.S. DOJ, Antitrust Div., Antitrust Division Announces New Streamlined
Procedure for Parties Seeking to Modify or Terminate Old Settlements and Litigated Judgments
(Mar. 28, 2014), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2014/304744.pdf
(noting that “[s]ince 1980, there have been significant changes in markets and technology and
substantial changes in antitrust law”).
790
Id.
791
Interestingly, the Office heard considerably less about the market power of large technology
companies or other dominant distributors of music and whether that poses similar concerns. But
see, e.g., MMF & FAC Second Notice Comments at 21-22 (noting the “market power of a few tech
giants”).
792
See U.S. DOJ & FTC, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS:
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION 110 (2007), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/
public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf (“A
NTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND IP RIGHTS REPORT”) (“Whether the
legal analysis applied to intellectual property bundling is some form of the per se rule or the
more searching rule of reason, a plaintiff will have to establish that a defendant has market
power in the tying product.”); cf. Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 42-43 (2006)
(explaining the following about tying arrangement involving patented products: “While some
such arrangements are still unlawful, such as those that are the product of a true monopoly or a
market wide conspiracy, . . . that conclusion must be supported by proof of power in the relevant
market rather than by a mere presumption thereof.”); see also H
ERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL
ANTITRUST POLICY: THE LAW OF COMPETITION AND ITS PRACTICE 2 (4th ed. 2011) (“An important
goal of antitrust law—arguably its only goalis to ensure that markets are competitive.”).
147
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
antitrust violations do not involve long-term government price controls. Such remedies
instead tend to focus on injunctive relief to address the particular anticompetitive
behavior in question and/or the payment of one-time fines.
793
The second type of monopoly referenced by participants is a wholly different one,
namely, the limited “monopoly” in an individual work that is conferred by virtue of the
exclusive rights granted under the Copyright Act. Even though it is not a product of
collective activity, these exclusive rights probably play no less of a significant role in
debates about music licensing. Many licensees—for example, large online providers
believe they must have access to complete, or virtually complete, catalogs of sound
recordings and musical works in order to compete in the marketplace. A compulsory
license—at least in theory—can make that possible.
But compulsory licensing removes choice and control from copyright owners who seek
to protect and maximize the value of their assets. An increasingly vocal number of
copyright owners believe they should be able to withhold their works from low-paying
or otherwise objectionable digital services, in part because such services may cannibalize
sales or higher-paying subscription models. Taylor Swift’s widely publicized decision to
pull her catalog from the leading streaming provider Spotify because she did not want
her songs available on Spotify’s free tier of service has been widely reported, and other
artists appear to be following suit.
794
Similarly, artist manager Irving Azoff of GMR has
reportedly threatened YouTube with a billion-dollar lawsuit if it does not remove his
clients’ repertoire from their site.
795
In order to take such action—and demand higher
793
See, e.g., Farrell Malone & J. Gregory Sidak, Should Antitrust Consent Decrees Regulate Post-
Merger Pricing?, 3 J.
COMPETITION L. & ECON. 471, 477 (2007) (explaining that, in expressing its
preference for structural remedies over conduct remedies in situations involving anticompetitive
merger, the DOJ “explicitly criticizes price agreements as a component of consent decrees” and
that the “[DOJ] disfavors using consent decrees to fix a price or an allowable range of prices for
the post-merger firm”); see also H
ERBERT HOVENKAMP, MARK D. JANIS, MARK A. LEMLEY &
CHRISTOPHER R. LESLIE, IP AND ANTITRUST: AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES APPLIED TO
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 22-62 (2d ed. Supp. 2013) (“As a general matter, antitrust should not
favor solutions that turn the federal courts into price control agencies.”).
794
Dickey, Taylor Swift on 1989, Spotify, Her Next Tour and Female Role Model (quoting Taylor Swift:
I think that people should feel that there is a value to what musicians have created, and that’s
that.”); see also Mitchell Peters, Big Machine’s Scott Borchetta Explains Why Taylor Swift Was Removed
From Spotify, B
ILLBOARD (Nov. 8, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/articles/news/6312143/big-
machine-scott-borchetta-explains-taylor-swift-1989-removal-from-spotify-nikki-sixx (quoting Big
Machine Label Group CEO Scott Borchetta: “We determined that her fan base is so in on her, let’s
pull everything off of Spotify, and any other service that doesn’t offer a premium service . . . Now
if you are a premium subscriber to Beats or Rdio or any of the other services that don’t offer just a
free-only, then you will find her catalogue.”); Bogursky, Taylor Swift, Garth Brooks and other artists
lead the fight against Spotify.
795
Gardner, Pharrell Williams’ Lawyer to YouTube: Remove Our Songs or Face $1 Billion Lawsuit.
148
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
compensation—the use cannot be subject to mandatory licensing.
796
But for those under
a compulsory license or a consent decree, it is not possible to say no.
In this regard, it is interesting to compare music to other types of copyrighted works, for
example, television shows and movies. Like music, a particular television show or
movie may not be a fully satisfying substitute for another—or a substitute at all. But
consumers do not expect to be able to access every television show through Hulu, or
every movie through Netflix. It is understood that different services can and will offer
different content.
Even within the music universe, the law treats sound recordings and musical works
differently with respect to the right to say no. We seem to accept the fact that a licensee
offering downloads or interactive streaming will need to negotiate deals with major and
independent record labels, or forgo the content. On the musical work side, however,
government policy has subjected these same uses to government-mandated licensing.
Even given greater latitude to make licensing decisions, it would seem that musical
work owners would be strongly incentivized to license services that they believed
would pay a reasonable return. This seems to be true of the record labels, which have
authorized a wide range of download and interactive music services outside of a
mandatory licensing regime.
797
But the labels are not required to license services that
show little promise or value. Why is this demanded of music publishers and
songwriters?
The Office believes that the question of whether music copyright owners should be able
to choose whether to agree to a license is an especially critical one. Understandably,
those seeking permission to use music appreciate the security of compulsory licensing
processes and certainty of government-set rates—as buyers of content likely would in
any context.
798
But modern competition law does not view the rights enjoyed by
copyright owners as intrinsically anathema to efficient markets. As the DOJ itself has
explained, “antitrust doctrine does not presume the existence of market power from the
mere presence of an intellectual property right.”
799
796
Notably, Swift’s sound recordings are not subject to compulsory licensing when used for
interactive services, and GMR’s clientswho are not represented by ACSCAP or BMIhave
asserted rights not covered by the consent decrees.
797
RIAA First Notice Comments at 30 n.43; see also Find a Music Service, WHYMUSICMATTERS.COM,
http://whymusicmatters.com/find-music (last visited Feb. 2, 2015) (listing licensed music
services).
798
For example, in a 2011 study conducted by the Copyright Office, cable and satellite operators
operating under the section 111, 119 and 122 compulsory licenses expressed strong opposition to
the possibility of phasing them out. STELA
REPORT at 8.
799
ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND IP RIGHTS REPORT at 2.
149
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
As a general matter, the Office believes that certain aspects of our compulsory licensing
processes can and should be relaxed. But this does not mean that antitrust concerns
should be overlooked. Many pertinent considerations have been raised in the DOJ’s
parallel consideration of the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees. The Office strongly
endorses that review, and—in light of the significant impact of the decrees in today’s
performance-driven music markethopes it will result in a productive reconsideration
of the 75-year-old decrees. At the same time, the Office observes that it is Congress, not
the DOJ, that has the ability to address the full range of issues that encumber our music
licensing system, which go far beyond the consent decrees.
2. The PROs and the Consent Decrees
Since the first part of the twentieth century, ASCAP and BMI have provided critical
services to songwriters and music publishers on the one hand, and myriad licensees on
the other, in facilitating the licensing of public performance rights in musical works.
SESAC, though smaller, has also played an important role in this area, administering
performance rights for a select group of clients. More recently, GMR has come onto the
scene as a fourth contender in the performance rights arena, with an impressive client
roster. Each of these organizations offers repertoire-wide—or “blanket”—licenses for
the musical works they represent, with the four together essentially representing the
entire spectrum of musical works available for licensing in the U.S., including many
foreign works. Blanket licenses are available for a wide range of uses, including
terrestrial, satellite, and internet radio, on-demand music streaming services, website
and television uses, the performance of recorded music in bars, restaurants, and other
commercial establishments, and live performances as well.
As detailed above, both ASCAP and BMI, unlike their smaller competitors SESAC and
GMR, are subject to continuing consent decrees. The decrees, overseen by federal
district courts in New York City (typically referred to as the “rate courts”), were last
updated before the rise of licensed digital music servicesin the case of BMI, in 1994,
and in the case of ASCAP, in 2001. The consent decrees impose significant government-
mandated constraints on the manner in which ASCAP and BMI may operate. Among
other things, ASCAP and BMI are required to grant a license to any user who requests
one, without payment of royalties until a royalty rate is set by negotiation or following
litigation before the rate court. Under its decree, ASCAP may not issue mechanical
licenses for the reproduction or distribution of musical works; while the BMI consent
decree is silent on this point, BMI has not itself issued mechanical licenses. Except to the
extent a licensee seeks a narrower licensesuch as a “per-program” license or a blanket
license with “carveouts” for directly licensed worksASCAP and BMI are required to
license all works in their repertoire.
150
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Pandora Analysis a.
Publisher Withdrawals
In 2013, as part of pending ratesetting litigation with the internet radio service Pandora,
both the ASCAP and BMI rate courtsapplying slightly different logicinterpreted the
consent decrees as prohibiting music publishers from withdrawing authorization to
license their songs for particular types of uses.
800
Major music publishers had sought to
withdraw their “new media” (i.e., online and mobile usage)
801
rights from the PROs in an
effort to negotiate with Pandora directly to achieve higher rates than what they believed
they would otherwise be awarded in court.
802
Following their decisions to withdraw, EMI agreed to a rate equivalent to the existing
ASCAP rate of 1.85% for services like Pandora (but without deductions for ASCAP’s
fees); Sony/ATV negotiated for a prorated share of an industrywide rate of 5% (which
translated to a 2.28% implied rate for ASCAP); and UMG obtained a prorated share of
7.5% (or a 3.42% ASCAP rate).
803
Subsequently, however, the two rate courts held that
these publishers could not selectively withdraw specific rights from ASCAP or BMI to be
negotiated independently. Instead, the publishers had to be “all in” or “all out.”
804
In the wake of these decisions, the three publishers who had sought to withdraw (now
two, as Sony/ATV has since become affiliated with EMI) are, for the moment, back “in,”
and ASCAP and BMI have petitioned the DOJ to modify their decrees to allow these
sorts of partial withdrawals by their publisher members. With the petitions pending,
however, both Sony/ATV and UMPG—which together represent some 50% of the music
publishing market
805
—have made it clear that they may well choose to withdraw all
rights from the PROs in the future.
800
In re Pandora, 2013 WL 5211927, at *11; BMI v. Pandora, 2013 WL 6697788, at *5.
801
”New media” services are those available by means of the internet, a wireless mobile
telecommunications network, and/or a computer network. In re Pandora, 2013 WL 5211927, at *2;
BMI v. Pandora, 2013 WL 6697788, at *2.
802
To some degree, the move to withdraw was also likely spurred by technological evolution.
Unlike traditional media such as broadcast radio stations, digital providers are equipped to track
and report each use of a musical work (for example, each time a song is streamed to an individual
subscriber) and thus provide full census reporting to a copyright owner. When such census
reporting is available, there is no need for an intermediary organization such as a PRO to survey
or sample the service to allocate royalty payments among songwriters; a publisher has the means
to allocate the royalties itself. Thus, it is more feasible for the publisher to self-administer a
directly negotiated license.
803
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 330, 339-40, 355.
804
In re Pandora, 2013 WL 5211927, at *11; BMI v. Pandora, 2013 WL 6697788, at *5.
805
Christman, First-Quarter Music Publishing Rankings: SONGS Surges Again.
151
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The specter of across-the-board withdrawal by the major publishers from ASCAP and
BMI is concerning to many in the music sector. The three major publishers—Sony/ATV,
UMPG, and Warner/Chappell—together represent approximately 63% of the U.S. music
publishing market,
806
and the songwriters they in turn represent (as well as the
publishers themselves) currently license the vast majority of their performance rights
through the PROs.
807
The Office agrees that the full withdrawal of leading publishers
from ASCAP and BMI would likely significantly disrupt the music market by
fundamentally altering the licensing and payment process for the public performance of
musical works without an established framework to replace it, at least in the short run.
On the user side, as might be predicted, many strongly prefer the government-
supervised PRO system over the unregulated negotiation of rights, and oppose the
movement toward withdrawal. While many licenseessuch as commercial radio and
television stations represented by RMLC and TMLCare successful in negotiating
(rather than litigating) rates with ASCAP and BMI under the current regime, it is
reassuring to them to know that they can turn to a federal court if they view it as a better
option. Like the radio and television sectors, digital services, including Pandora (whose
recent rate court litigation is discussed below), also strongly favor government oversight
of music publishers’ licensing practices.
Notably, although SESAC is not subject to a consent decree, television and radio
licensees recently sued that organization in separate actions for alleged anticompetitive
licensing practices.
808
SESAC settled the television case by agreeing to reimburse the
television station plaintiffs almost $60 million in licensing fees
809
(the radio case remains
pending). Without opining on their merits, the Office observes that these cases illustrate
the importance and corrective potential of private enforcement actions outside of the
consent decree environment.
Concerns about the impact of large publisher withdrawals are not limited to the user
side. Songwriters, too, are apprehensive. According to longstanding industry practice,
songwriters are paid their “writer’s share of performance royalties directly by the
PROs; these monies do not flow through the publishers. In a world of direct licensing,
publishers would not be required to adhere to established standards for the reporting
and payment of royalties, such as those employed by ASCAP and BMI. Songwriters
806
See id.
807
See Sisario, Pandora Suit May Upend Century-Old Royalty Plan.
808
See Meredith Corp., 1 F. Supp. 3d 180; RMLC v. SESAC, 29 F. Supp. 3d 487.
809
See Memorandum of Law in Support of Plaintiffs’ Unopposed Motion for Preliminary
Approval of Settlement 1-2, Meredith Corp. v. SESAC, LLC., 1 F. Supp. 3d 180 (S.D.N.Y. 2014) (No.
09-cv-9177); Meredith Corp. v. SESAC, LLC, No. 09-cv-9177 (S.D.N.Y. Oct. 31, 2014) (order granting
preliminary approval of settlement).
152
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
worry that direct licensing could thus result in a system with much less accountability
and transparency than they currently enjoy under the PROs.
There is a particular concern about publishers’ treatment of advance payments and
licensing fees by music services, as such monies may not be accounted for by the
publisher in a transparent fashion. This, in turn, raises a question in songwriters’ minds
as to whether withdrawal would exacerbate this problem.
810
In addition, apart from any
contractual issues in relation to American songwriters, non-U.S. writers who assign their
rights exclusively to their local societies—which in turn enter into contractual
relationships with ASCAP and BMI to collect royalties on their behalf in the United
States—do not see how they can properly be subject to U.S. publisher withdrawal.
811
On
top of all this, a precipitous decline in overall royalty throughput would almost certainly
result in markedly increased—and perhaps prohibitive—administrative costs for those
who remained affiliated with ASCAP and BMI.
An interesting question is whether significantly decreased market shares on the part of
ASCAP and BMI due to major publisher withdrawals would, paradoxically, obviate the
need for ongoing government control of those organizations. From a practical
perspective, one might question why ASCAP and BMI would remain subject to
significant government controls if larger market competitors (i.e., the major publishers)
were not subject to such supervision. We assume that the DOJ may address this issue in
its forthcoming analysis.
Rate Decision
Following the rulings on withdrawal, the ASCAP court, in a lengthy opinion, proceeded
to determine a “reasonable fee” of 1.85% for Pandora, applying a “hypothetical” “fair
market value” standard.
812
In so doing, the court was dismissive of the publishers’
frustrations with the rate court process and their “envy” of the much higher rates being
paid by Pandora to sound recording owners (over 50% of revenues versus the
publishers’ combined market share of 4%)
813
which sound recording rates in any event
the court could not consider as a result of the statutory bar in section 114(i).
814
810
See, e.g., SGA First Notice Comments at 8-9.
811
MMF & FAC Second Notice Comments at 46 (reproducing the “MMF Public response to the
Sony/ATV Statement”).
812
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 353-54, 372.
813
Id. at 333, 366.
814
17 U.S.C. § 114(i) provides that “[l]icense fees payable for the public performance of sound
recordings . . . shall not be taken into account in any . . . proceeding to set or adjust the royalties
payable to copyright owners of musical works for the public performance of their works.”
153
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The court sharply criticized Sony/ATV’s and UMPG’s efforts to negotiate higher rates
with Pandora outside of the confines of the consent decree that could then serve as
benchmarks in the rate court proceeding. Finding the publishers’ tactics objectionable
especially in light of the fact that Pandora could face large-scale copyright liability if it
failed to conclude licenses—it rejected the outside agreements as suitable benchmarks.
815
Among other things, the court took issue with Sony/ATV’s and UMPG’s failure to
provide lists of the compositions they owned to Pandora so Pandora could remove their
respective works from its service if necessary.
816
While the court’s opinion suggests that Sony/ATV and UMPG may have engaged in
anticompetitive behavior by “purposefully set[ting] out” to “create higher benchmarks,”
and also expressed concern about the publishers’ “coordinated” behavior in
withdrawing new media rights—as well as their aggressive negotiation strategies—the
court ultimately concluded that it had “no need to explore which if any of [their] actions
was wrongful or legitimate.”
817
In this regard, while it was not the only aspect of the
publishers’ conduct that troubled the court, it is hard to see how the mere desire to seek
higher royalty rates—or the fact that the CEO of Sony/ATV appeared in a news article
“in shirt sleeves with a large cigar in his mouth” to boast of the higher rate he had
negotiated with Pandora—could constitute an antitrust violation.
818
Undoubtedly, the Pandora court believed itself to be carrying out the purpose of the
ASCAP decree, and the decree, of course, is meant to address antitrust concerns. But the
opinion is notable for its focus on the behavior of a handful of actors instead of an
empirically based economic analysis of the proper rate for Pandora. For example,
rejecting ASCAP’s arguments that the court should consider Pandora’s commercial
success as part of its inquiry, the court opined that “market share or revenue metrics are
poor foundations on which to construct a reasonable fee.”
819
Yet it seems that these
factors might well be considered by parties in an actual market negotiation.
Additionally, even assuming for the sake of argument that Sony/ATV’s and UMPG’s
tactics had unequivocally been found by the court to cross the line from forceful
negotiations to anticompetitive conduct, it must be remembered that the rate set by the
court applies not only to those companies, but to all other publisher and songwriter
members of ASCAP as well. Such a court-ordered rate is also likely to heavily influence
the market for the other PROs, and hence the industry as a whole. A question arises,
then, as to whether the court’s repudiation of specific conduct on the part of some by
815
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 360-61.
816
Id. at 345-46, 361.
817
Id. at 357-58.
818
Id. at 347.
819
Id. at 369.
154
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
rejecting the possibility of a higher rate represents a fair outcome for the rest of the
industry.
Availability of Song Data
As a general matter, the Office concurs with the apparent view of the Pandora court that
a service should be able to ascertain what works are covered under a license so as to
permit the service to remove unauthorized works if necessary. Infringement liability
should not arise from a game of “gotcha.” Since the Pandora decision, it appears that
both Sony/ATV and UMPG have made efforts to make their song data available to
licensees.
820
In addition to such voluntary efforts, the Office believes that government
policies should strongly incentivize the public availability of song ownership data for
works in the marketplace, a topic that is addressed in more depth below.
PRO Ratesetting Process b.
This above section reviews the Pandora decision in some detail because it illuminates an
important policy concern: namely, whether we should continue to blend antitrust
oversight with industry rate proceedings as envisioned under the consent decrees. In
the Pandora litigation, this approach appears to have yielded a mixture of competition
and ratesetting considerations, without a satisfying analysis of either. The Office is of
the view that allegations of anticompetitive conduct are worthy of evaluation (and, if
appropriate, remedial action) separate and apart from the question of a fair rateand
vice versa. Each of these two critical policy objectives merits government attention in its
own right.
821
The Office therefore proposes that the ratesetting aspects of PRO oversight be separated
from whatever government supervision is determined still to be necessary to address
antitrust concerns.
Migrate to Copyright Royalty Board
Assuming PRO ratesetting is separated from any ongoing antitrust oversight, the Office
proposes that the function of establishing rates be migrated to the CRB.
822
Industry
820
See Ed Christman, Sony/ATV Makes Organized Catalog Available Online, BILLBOARD (July 16,
2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/publishing/6157855/sonyatv-makes-
organized-catalog-available-online; Ed Christman, UMPG to Make Entire Database Easier for
Licensees, B
ILLBOARD (June 27, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/publishing/
6140985/umpg-to-make-entire-database-easier-for-licensees.
821
See EPSTEIN at 36 (concluding that “there is no comparative advantage in using a judicial body
as opposed to some administrative agency” for ratesetting).
822
ASCAP and BMI also seek to have rate disputes decided outside of federal court. Both have
recommended some sort of system of (apparently private) arbitration without providing much
detail. ASCAP First Notice Comments at 4, 23-24 (recommending “expedited private
155
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
ratesetting is, of course, a primary function of the CRB, and the CRB has the benefit of
experience assessing a broader spectrum of rate-related questions than the federal rate
courts. Significantly, the CRB sets rates on the sound recording side as well as for
musical works. It also has in-house economic expertise. While, as discussed below,
interested parties appear to agree that the statutory framework governing the CRB’s
procedures could stand some improvement, on the whole it seems only logical to
consolidate music ratesetting proceedings in a single specialized tribunal.
In offering the suggestion that the CRB assume responsibility for the rates applicable to
the public performance of musical works, the Office does not mean to suggest that the
CRB should not question the legitimacy of particular benchmarks if there is reason to do
so (as the CRB in fact routinely does in ratesetting proceedings). But the ultimate aim of
the proceeding should be a fair rate for the industry as a whole, rather than the
enforcement of antitrust policy. The Office believes that a process focused on industry
economics rather than antitrust analysis offers a more auspicious framework to establish
broadly applicable rates.
Under the Office’s proposal, discussed in more detail below, the CRB, like the rate
courts, would step in to set a rate only when it could not be agreed as between the
relevant parties. Such ratesetting activities would not need to occur on a five-year
schedule, as under the current CRB system, but would be commenced on an as-needed
basis, like today’s proceedings before the ASCAP and BMI rate courts. Additional
parties seeking to resolve the same rate issue could be offered the opportunity to join the
proceeding. Assuming the experience were similar to that of the rate courts, the vast
majority of rates would be agreed voluntarily rather than litigated.
Assuming the ratesetting authority for the public performance of musical works were
transferred from the rate courts to the CRB, a question arises as to whether the
separation of ratesetting and antitrust responsibilities would provide the occasion to
sunset the decrees and adopt a more modern approach to antitrust oversight in this area.
Under a more flexible approach, the DOJ would investigate and address potential
anticompetitive behavior on an as-needed basis, rather than continue to impose
presumptive restrictions under the consent decrees. As noted above, private
arbitration”); Music Licensing Hearings at 52 (statement of Michael O’Neill, CEO, BMI) (“We
believe that replacing the current rate court with arbitration in New York under the American
Arbitration Association rules would be a faster, less expensive, and a more market-responsive
mechanism for all parties to obtain fair, market-value rate decisions.”). For the reasons discussed
above, the Office believes the CRB is the logical venue to determine public performance rates. As
an added benefit, the CRB does not depend upon the payment of private arbitration fees (a
significant factor in the demise of the CARPs that preceded the CRB). See H.R.
REP. NO. 108-408,
at 21, 99-100. At the same time, based on stakeholders’ input, the Office is recommending certain
changes to the CRB system, which are outlined below.
156
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
enforcement actions, as well, could play a role in policing alleged misconduct. We leave
such questions of antitrust policy for the DOJ to answer.
Section 114(i)
Regardless of whether PRO ratesetting is migrated to the CRB, as further discussed
below, the Copyright Office endorses the proposalembodied in the proposed SEA
legislation
823
—that the prohibition in section 114(i) that currently prevents ratesetting
tribunals from considering sound recording performance royalties be eliminated.
Originally designed as a protective measure to benefit songwriters and publishers, it
appears to be having the opposite effect. Contrary to the suggestion of the Pandora
court,
824
the Office does not understand why, absent such a restriction, it might not be
relevant to consider sound recording royalties in establishing a fair rate for the use of
musical works should a ratesetting authority be so inclined.
825
Interim Fees
Under the consent decrees, anyone who applies for a license receives one. There is no
requirement of immediate payment. As discussed above, an applicant has the right to
perform musical works in a PRO’s repertoire pending the completion of negotiations or
rate court proceedings resulting in an interim or final fee.
826
Since the consent decrees
do not provide for immediate and concurrent payment for uses made during these
periodsand do not establish a timeframe for the commencement of a rate court
proceeding—an applicant is able to publicly perform a PRO’s catalog of works for an
indefinite period without paying.
827
Needless to say, commercial entities do not
typically receive a steady supply of product for months or years based on a mere letter
request. But such is the case with music.
The problem is exacerbated by the substantial burden and expense of litigating a rate in
federal courta contingency both sides seek to avoid. Licensees may pay nothing or
greatly reduced fees for years as negotiations drag on, while still enjoying all of the
benefits of a license. The Office agrees with those commenters who have suggested that
this system—under which services may launch and continue to operate without an
agreed rate—significantly increases the leverage of licensees at the expense of the PROs
823
SEA, H.R. 4079; SEA, S. 2321, 113th Cong. (2014).
824
Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 366-67.
825
The Office does not believe that the fact that the limitation was originally proposed by musical
work owners, even if ill-conceived, is a sufficient basis to determine it should continue in effect.
826
See ASCAP Consent Decree § IX.E; BMI Consent Decree § XIV.A.
827
ASCAP First Notice Comments at 15-16; BMI First Notice Comments at 16-17.
157
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
and their members.
828
Because the licensee already has access to the works it needs,
there is no urgency to agree to a rate.
Once again, the Office does not see why music is treated differently from the goods of
other suppliers in the marketplace. A fair and rational system should require licensees
to pay at least an interim rate from the inception of their service, subject to a true-up
when a final rate is negotiated with the PRO or established by the ratesetting authority.
Notably, both the ASCAP and BMI consent decrees include a process for the rate court
to set interim rates. In practice, however, it seems that this option—which, at least for
BMI, entails up to four months of discovery and motion practice
829
is not commonly
exercised. Likely this is due to parties’ reluctance to undertake the considerable burden
and expense of federal court litigation, especially when the result is only a temporary
one.
830
The Office is of the view that to the extent a licensing entity is required to grant a license
upon request, there should be a viable (not merely theoretical) mechanism—for
example, a brief, single-day hearing before the ratesetting authority (e.g., the CRB)to
set an interim royalty rate without undue burden or expense. While nothing is ever as
simple as it seems, the Office believes that a workable system should be feasible. For
example, a licensee could be required to share a written description of the material
aspects of its proposed service, after which both parties would proffer lists of relevant
rates already in effect, which together would serve as guidance for the decisionmaker. It
should not be necessary to have an elaborate procedure when the temporary rate can be
adjusted retroactively. In addition to being more equitable for music owners, the Office
believes requiring licensees to pay an interim rate would provide greater incentive to
resolve rates through voluntary negotiations at the outset.
Partial Withdrawal of Rights c.
A primary focus of the commentary to the Copyright Office—and to the DOJ in its
review of the consent decreesis music publishers’ ability (or inability) to withdraw
specific categories of licensing rights from their authorizations to the PROs. The
828
See also, e.g., MMF & FAC Second Notice Comments at 10 (“As far as we know most of the
societies in the EU require potential licensees to provide important financial and operational data
(and in the case of a startup, their business projections, and projected user numbers) when
making their application. To us this seems sound common sense and, coupled with an ability by
societies to require an interim payment, would rebalance the negotiating process more fairly.”).
829
See BMI Antitrust Consent Decree Review Comments at 20-21. The ASCAP consent decree
requires that the court set an interim rate within 90 days of a request. See ASCAP Antitrust
Consent Decree Review Comments at 12.
830
See ASCAP Antitrust Consent Decree Review Comments at 14 n.20; BMI Antitrust Consent
Decree Review Comments at 21.
158
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
purpose of such withdrawals would be to allow music owners to negotiate in the
marketplace for the exploitation of their songs—or, if not satisfied with the price offered,
to withhold their songs from particular services. This has an analog in much of the
discussion surrounding section 115, another area where publishers and songwriters seek
the ability to escape from mandatory licensing.
As noted above, except in the case of internet radio providers that qualify for the section
112 and 114 statutory licenses, record companies are free to negotiate with potential
licensees in the open market. But for music publishers, it is the exception rather than the
norm, as the licensing of both mechanical and performance licenses is largely subject to
government mandate.
There is substantial evidence to support the view that government-regulated licensing
processes imposed on publishers and songwriters have resulted in depressed rates, at
least in comparison to noncompulsory rates for the same uses on the sound recording
side. Setting aside efficiency concerns, the Office does not see a principled reason why
sound recording owners are permitted to negotiate interactive streaming rates directly
while musical work owners are not. The Office is therefore sympathetic to the
publishers’ position that they should be permitted to withdraw certain rights from the
PROs to permit market negotiations. The Office believes that partial withdrawal—in the
form of a limited right to “opt out”—should be made available to those who want it.
This view is reinforced by the possibility of wholesale defections by major (and perhaps
other) publishers from ASCAP and BMI if government controls are not relaxed, and the
potential chaos that would likely follow.
Any such opt-out process would need to be carefully managed to ensure licensees did
not face undue burdens in the licensing process as a result. At least for now, the Office
believes that withdrawal of performance rights should be limited to digital rights
equivalent to those that the record labels are free to negotiate outside of sections 112 and
114—essentially, interactive streaming rights for new media services. In the case of such
a partial withdrawal, the publisher would be free to pursue a direct deal for the rights in
question (or, if not satisfied with a licensee’s offer, withhold songs from the service in
question).
Publishers who chose to opt out would need publicly to identify the particular uses
subject to withdrawal, the licensing organization from which they were being
withdrawn, each of the affected works, where a direct license might be sought, and other
pertinent information.
831
As discussed below, it is the Office’s recommendation that a
non-profit general music rights organization (“GMRO”) be designated by the Copyright
Office to receive, maintain and offer access to this information. The Office additionally
proposes that the current PROs be permitted to expand to become music rights
831
The proposed opt-out right would be by publisher, not by individual work.
159
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
organizations (“MROs”) that would be capable of administering not just performance
rights but mechanical and perhaps other musical work rights as well.
832
While the publisher would presumably choose to be paid directly by the licensee under
any resulting outside licensing arrangement rather than through an MRO, in order to
ensure songwriters’ confidence in the accounting and payment process, the Office
believes that songwriters affiliated with that publisher should retain the option of
receiving their writer’s share of royalties directly from the licensee through their chosen
MRO.
833
Finally, to the extent publishers failed to affiliate with an MRO, their performance rights
would fall under the default licensing authority of the GMRO, which, as described
below, would collect royalties and distribute them to publisher claimants. The
combination of direct deals, MRO-issued licenses, and the GMRO backstop would allow
licensees to secure full licensing coverage for necessary performance rights.
Bundled Licensing d.
During the study, industry stakeholders broadly supported increased bundling of rights
to facilitate greater licensing efficiency. On the sound recording side of the equation,
this does not appear to be much of an issue. To the extent noninteractive services
procure licenses under sections 112 and 114, they obtain both digital performance rights
and the reproduction rights (e.g., server copy rights) needed to engage in the streaming
process. When services negotiate licenses outside of the statutory scheme, the labels are
free to bundle all necessary rights together.
On the musical work side, however, the story is different. Licenses for the reproductions
necessary to support an interactive streaming service are issued under section 115,
whereas licenses for the streamed performances of works are obtained from the PROs.
In 2008, following a lengthy Copyright Office administrative proceeding and
industrywide settlement, the CRB adopted regulations that effectively establish bundled
rates for various types of streaming activities, under which the total cost of licensees’
PRO performance licenses is deducted from the overall percentage rate applicable to the
relevant service under section 115.
834
But while the royalty rate problem may have been
832
As discussed above, the concept of MROs was proposed by former Register Marybeth Peters in
testimony before Congress in 2005. Copyright Office Views on Music Licensing Reform Hearing at 21-
36 (statement of Marybeth Peters, Register of Copyrights).
833
This option could also help to alleviate concerns about the status of non-U.S. writers affiliated
with foreign PROs if the U.S. publisher of their works chooses to pursue partial withdrawal.
834
See Mechanical and Digital Phonorecord Delivery Rate Determination Proceeding, 74 Fed. Reg.
at 4531-32 (setting forth the CRB’s proposed regulations that established the rates and terms for
the use of musical works in limited downloads, interactive streaming and incidental digital
phonorecord deliveries); see also Compulsory License for Making and Distributing Phonorecords,
160
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
addressed, an interactive service must still obtain separate mechanical and performance
licenses and report complex accounting information under these two different licensing
regimes (song-by-song licensing under section 115 versus blanket licensing by the
PROs).
In 2005, former Register of Copyrights Marybeth Peters proposed moving from a
dualistic approach for the licensing of musical works for mechanical and performance
purposes to a system of integrated music rights organizations, or MROs.
835
At the
timewhen mechanical royalties represented a more significant income stream than
they do todaymusic publishers and songwriters expressed considerable skepticism
about such a bundled approach.
836
Today, in an era where mechanical royalties are
becoming more marginal, Register Peters’ proposal appears prescient, and enjoys
support among publishers, songwriters andnot surprisinglydigital licensees.
837
It
now seems apparent that the government should pursue appropriate changes to our
legal framework to encourage bundled licensing, which could eliminate redundant
resources on the part of both licensors and licensees.
As touched upon above, the most obvious step in this regard would be to allow existing
music licensing organizations to expand to fill this rolethe PROs would be permitted
to take on mechanical licensing, and mechanical licensing entities such as HFA or MRI
could integrate performance rights into their businesses. To satisfy reporting and
payment obligations under songwriter or other agreements that distinguish between
these rights, some sort of allocation of income as between the two rights would likely be
required. This perhaps could be addressed by the CRB in establishing bundled rates (as
under the section 112 and 114 licenses), or by the individual MROs in administering
negotiated licenses.
838
Including Digital Phonorecord Deliveries, 73 Fed. Reg. 66,173, 66,180 (adopting rule that
permitted server and other copies necessary to certain streaming processes to be licensed under
section 115).
835
See Copyright Office Views on Music Licensing Reform Hearing at 6 (statement of Marybeth Peters,
Register of Copyrights).
836
See, e.g., id. at 62 (statement of NMPA) (“[W]e believe the Copyright Office proposal is fatally
flawed and would be harmful to songwriters and music publishers.”).
837
Such a unified licensing model has been in effect for 17 years in the United Kingdom. Our
History, PRS
FORMUSIC, http://www.prsformusic.com/aboutus/ourorganisation/ourhistory/Pages/
default.aspx (last visited Jan. 22, 2015).
838
The U.K.’s unified licensing system may provide a helpful model in this regard. PRS for Music
was created by joining together the U.K. Performing Right Society (“PRS”) and the Mechanical
Copyright Protection Society (“MCPS”). For royalties received under its unified licenses, the PRS
for Music distribution committee determines various splits between PRS and MCPS depending
upon the type of use, which allocations are subject to ratification by the PRS and MCPS boards.
161
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
3. Mechanical Licensing and Section 115
As sales of CDs continue to slip away, mechanical licensing revenues for the
reproduction and distribution of musical works under section 115once the primary
source of income for publishers and songwriterslikewise continue to decline.
839
Although sales of digital downloads through services like Apple iTunes have bolstered
mechanical royalties in recent years, even DPD sales have fallen off with the rise of
streaming services such as Spotify. Even so, mechanical revenues still currently
represent about 23% of income for musical works (as compared to 52% generated by
performances, 20% by synch uses, and 5% by other uses).
840
Of the mechanical share, a
small amount is generated by the server and other reproductions of musical works
required for online providers to operate interactive streaming services which, as noted
above, also pay performance royalties.
Commenting parties have focused on two primary areas of concern with respect to the
106-year old compulsory license embodied in section 115. The first, put forth by music
publishers and songwriters, is that the compulsory license does not permit them to
control the use of their works or seek higher royalties. Relatedly, rightsowners also
complain about the lack of an audit right under section 115 and practical inability to
enforce reporting or payment obligations against recalcitrant licensees.
The second overarching concern with respect to section 115 is its song-by-song licensing
requirement, which dates back to the original incarnation of the compulsory license in
1909. Song-by-song licensing is viewed by music users as an administratively
daunting—if not sisyphean—task in a world where online providers seek licenses for
millions of works.
Free Market Negotiation Versus Collective Administration a.
One of the most challenging issues to arise in this study has been whether musical work
owners should be liberated from the section 115 compulsory licensing regime. Citing
PRS Distribution Policy Rules, PRSFORMUSIC, http://www.prsformusic.com/creators/
memberresources/Documents/Distribution%20policy/Distribution%20Policy%20Rules%20as%
20at%20November%202014.pdf (last visited Jan. 22, 2015). Out of those splits, 100% of
mechanical royalties are paid to the publisher, while performance royalties are split 50/50
between writer and publisher unless an alternate division of royalties is specified. Music
Registration Policy, PRS
FORMUSIC, http://www.prsformusic.com/creators/memberresources/
how_it_works/musicregpolicy/Pages/musicregpolicy.aspx (last visited Jan. 22, 2015).
839
See ASCAP Second Notice Comments at 23.
840
Ed Christman, NMPA Puts U.S. Publishing Revenues at $2.2 Billion Annually, BILLBOARD (June
11, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/publishing/6114215/nmpa-puts-us-
publishing- revenues-at-22-billion-annually.
162
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
the significantly higher rates paid to sound recording owners for uses where musical
work owners are regulated and sound recording owners are notand the contrasting
example of the unregulated synch licensing market, where in many cases licensing fees
are evenly apportioned—music publishers and songwriters have made a convincing
case that government regulation likely yields rates below those they would enjoy in a
free market. Motivated by concerns similar to those raised in connection with the
consent decrees, many musical work owners would like to see an end to section 115.
The Office—which, as noted, believes that compulsory licensing should exist only when
clearly needed to address a market failure—is sympathetic to these claims.
On the other hand, in comparison to the record industrywhere three major companies
can issue licenses for much of the most sought-after content, with independent labels
representing the balance
841
—U.S. musical work ownership is more diffusely distributed
over a greater number of entities and self-published songwriters.
842
Unlike sound
recordingswhich are typically wholly owned by an individual labelmany musical
works are controlled by two, three or even more publishers. Notwithstanding the
default rules of joint copyright ownership, publishers and songwriters frequently have
understandings that they are not free to license each other’s respective shares.
843
And
there are millions of musical works in the marketplace. Spotify, for instance, reports that
it offers some 30 million songs on its service.
844
Understandably, as described above, digital music providers are intensely opposed to a
system that would require individual licensing negotiations with thousands of musical
work owners. Even publisher proponents of the proposal to sunset section 115 do not
841
Although three record companies dominate, independent record labels enhance the market
with a rich variety of content, including well-known hit recordings. A2IM First Notice
Comments at 1 (“Billboard Magazine, using Nielsen SoundScan data, identified the Independent
music label sector as 34.6 percent of the music industry’s U.S. recorded music sales market in
2013.”). Many independent labels are represented by organizations that aggregate repertoire for
collective licensing, such as the U.K.-based Merlin, which issues licenses to digital services such
as YouTube and Spotify on a global basis. Merlin Strikes Licensing Deal with YouTube, M
ERLIN (Oct.
19, 2011), http://www.merlinnetwork.org/news/post/merlin-strikes-licensing-deal-with-youtube.
842
In recent years, as with recorded music, there has been significant consolidation in the music
publishing industry, such that the three major publishers now represent some 63% of the
marketapproaching the record company figure of 65%. See Christman, First-Quarter Music
Publishing Rankings: SONGS Surges Again; Bruce Houghton, Indie Labels Now Control 34.6% Of U.S.
Market, H
YPEBOT (Jan. 16, 2014), http://www.hypebot.com/hypebot/2014/01/indie-labels-now-
control-346-of-us-market.html.
843
See, e.g., PASSMAN at 304-05 (explaining that “[t]rue co-administration” deals, in which all
parties retain the right to administer their own share of a composition, are among the most
common arrangements for songs co-owned by publishers of approximately equal status).
844
Information, SPOTIFY, https://press.spotify.com/us/information/ (last visited Jan. 22, 2015).
163
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
deny that it would be extraordinarily difficult for services to negotiate with myriad
small copyright owners for all of the mechanical licenses they seek, and concede that
there needs to be some sort of collective system to facilitate licensing from smaller
rightsowners.
845
But apart from the optimistic view that should section 115 be retired,
new entities will spring forth to meet this need, publisher participants offered little
detail concerning how a collective solution would reliably be implemented.
The difficulty, then, is how to reconcile the competing values of free market negotiation
and collective management of rights. Each represents an express goal of reform: fair
compensation to creators, on the one hand, and licensing efficiency, on the other. A
middle path may provide the best answer.
Publisher Opt-Out Right
The Office believes that rather than eliminating section 115 altogether, section 115
should instead become the basis of a more flexible collective licensing system that will
presumptively cover all mechanical uses except to the extent individual rightsowners
choose to opt out. At least initially, the mechanical opt-out right would extend to the
uses that could be withdrawn from blanket performance licenses—that is, to interactive
streaming rights—as well as to downloading activities
846
(which, by judicial
interpretation, do not implicate the public performance right
847
). To reiterate, these are
uses where sound recording owners operate in the free market but publishers do not.
848
845
IPAC First Notice Comments at 6 (“Owners of musical works are sympathetic to those entities
that need an efficient process by which to obtain licenses for musical works. In that regard, IPAC
supports the creation of one or more licensing agencies to negotiate fair market license rates and
grant licenses on behalf of the copyright owners of the musical works on a blanket license or
individual song basis.”); NMPA First Notice Comments at 18 (“Compulsory licensing is not
needed to achieve the efficiency of bundled licenses . . . the only thing stopping performance
rights organizations such as ASCAP and BMI from offering a bundle of reproduction,
performance, and distribution rights from songwriters/publishers willing to appoint them as
their agents for such rights are outdated consent decrees.”).
846
The category of downloads includes both permanent downloads and limited downloads.
While permanent downloads are available to the purchaser indefinitely, limited downloads can
be accessed for only a limited period of time or limited number of plays. 37 C.F.R. § 385.11.
Download uses also include ringtones, for which a separate rate has been established under
section 115. 37 C.F.R. § 385.3; see also Mechanical and Digital Phonorecord Delivery Rate
Adjustment Proceeding, 71 Fed. Reg. at 64,316 (setting forth the Copyright Office’s 2006
Memorandum Opinion concluding ringtones qualify as DPDs).
847
See United States v. ASCAP, 627 F.3d 64, 68 (2d. Cir. 2010) (holding that downloading a digital
music file over the internet does not constitute a public performance of the work embodied in
that file); In re Cellco Partnership, 663 F. Supp. 2d 363, 374 (S.D.N.Y. 2009) (holding that
downloading a ringtone to a cellular phone does not in and of itself constitute a public
performance of a musical work). Also note that musical work owners do not collect mechanical
164
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Full Market Coverage
As envisioned by the Office, the collective system would comprise MROs (as noted, with
the ability to represent both performance and mechanical rights) acting on behalf of their
respective publisher members; individual publishers (including self-published
songwriters) representing their own mechanical licensing interests who had exercised
their opt-out right; and the GMRO. Unless they had a direct deal in place, publishers
would be paid through their chosen MRO. The GMRO would collect for works (or
shares of works) not covered by a direct deal or represented by an MROincluding
works with unknown owners—and attempt to locate and pay the relevant rightsholders.
Licensees could thus achieve end-to-end coverage through the combination of MROs,
direct licensors, and the GMRO.
As in the case of those seeking to withdraw specific performance uses from mandatory
licensing, publishers who wished to opt out from one or more of the categories of
mechanical licensing would need to identify the uses in question and provide this
information (via their MRO if applicable) to the GMRO, along with identification of their
works, licensing contact information, and other relevant data.
849
They would then be
free to negotiate directly with, and be paid directly by, the licensee.
850
Absent provision
of a notice that the publisher was exercising its right to opt out, that publisher’s works
would be licensable through its MRO.
851
royalties for noninteractive streaming uses subject to section 112 and 114 statutory licensing. See
NMPA First Notice Comments at 24; Mechanical and Digital Phonorecord Delivery Rate
Determination Proceeding, 74 Fed. Reg. at 4513.
848
Although physical products, such as CDs and vinyl records, also fall into this category,
stakeholder concerns have focused far less on the physical marketplace, which (despite a recent
increase in the niche market of vinyl records) continues to decline. As noted above, the Office
believes that the question of opt-out rights for physical product could be deferred for future
consideration.
849
As noted above, at least for the time being, the Office believes that opt-out rights for publishers
should be by publisher, not by individual work. Thus, opt-out publishers would be responsible
for their entire catalog.
850
In contrast to performance rights, songwriter agreements do not assume that the writer’s share
of mechanical royalties will flow through a PRO. Accordingly, while it may be a matter worthy
of further discussion, the Office is not now suggesting that songwriters should have the right to
redirect their mechanical shares through a chosen MRO.
851
Some publishers could opt out only to find that the licensee declined to pursue individual
negotiations with them. For this reason, it seems it would be useful to have some sort of
mechanism for such a rightsowner to reverse its opt-out and return to the collective system if it
wished.
165
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Cover Recordings
Section 115 permits digital services and others to reproduce and distribute copies of
musical works embodied in existing recordings, provided that the user is also
authorized to use the recording.
852
Another dimension of section 115 is that it can be
used for permission to make new, “cover” recordings of songs, so long as the new
version does not change the basic melody or “fundamental character” of the work.
853
While the ability to make a cover recording has long been a feature of the law, it is not
without controversy, especially among recording artists who write their own works.
While some artist songwriters may view imitation as flattery, others do not appreciate
that they are unable to prevent the re-recording of their songs by others. Many music
creators seek more control over their works. As some artists see it, “[a]pproval is by far
the most important right that an artist possesses.”
854
With respect to cover recordings, the Office recommends an approach whereby those
who seek to re-record songs could still obtain a license to do so, including in physical
formats. But the dissemination of such recordings for interactive new media uses, as
well as in the form of downloads, would be subject to the publisher’s ability to opt out of
the compulsory regime. Thus, a publishers choice to negotiate interactive streaming
and DPD rights for its catalog of songs would include the ability to authorize the
dissemination of cover recordings by those means. Or, put another way, where the
852
17 U.S.C. § 115(a)(1).
853
Id. § 115(a)(2).
854
See, e.g., Dina LaPolt and Steven Tyler, Comments Submitted to the Department of
Commerce’s Green Paper on Copyright Policy, Creativity, and Innovation in the Digital
Economy, at 2 (Feb. 10, 2014), available at http:// www.uspto.gov/ip/global/copyrights/lapolt_and_
tyler_comment_paper_02-10-14.pdf (objecting to a compulsory remix license). This perspective
was voiced by a number of prominent artists in response to a suggestion to consider a new
licensing framework for remixes that has been put forth by USPTO and NTIA as part of the
“Green Paper” process of the Internet Policy Task Force. See generally G
REEN PAPER; Steve
Knopper, Don Henley, Steven Tyler Condemn Potential Copyright Law Change, R
OLLING STONE (Feb.
13, 2014), http://www.rollingstone.com/music/news/don-henley-steven-tyler-condemn-potential-
copyright-law-change-20140213. The Green Paper suggestionmotivated by a desire to facilitate
the reuse of creative workswould extend to music. See G
REEN PAPER at 28-29 (citing concerns
about music sampling). Various commenters addressed the Green Paper suggestion in their
comments to the Copyright Office. Because it is not a Copyright Office initiative, this report does
not address the remix issue other than to note that, based on the comments submitted to the
Office, it appears to have drawn opposition within the music community. See, e.g., CCC Second
Notice Comments at 3; LaPolt First Notice Comments at 15; NMPA & HFA Second Notice
Comments at 37-38. But see Menell First Notice Comments at 3 (advocating for the creation of a
compulsory license for remixes). The Office hopes that this report will prove useful to the
USPTO and NTIA in their evaluation of the remix issue as it relates to music.
166
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
publisher had opted out, someone who produced a cover recording would need to
obtain a voluntary license to post the song on an interactive streaming or download
service (just as would someone who wished to offer streams or downloads of the
original recording of that work).
Audiovisual Uses
In their comments, the record companies explain that because consumers now access
music on computers, phones and other devices with screens, they expect to see
something when a song is playing—whether it is a video, album cover, or lyrics. The
labels’ observation corresponds to the fact that for music fans of today, YouTube—with a
billion users a month—is “the largest service in terms of listening to music.”
855
The record companies urge that the licensing system for musical works needs to be
updated to respond to the consumer desire for moreand more innovative
audiovisual content. To illustrate the point, the labels cite a recent record release—
involving a variety of distinct consumer productsthat necessitated over 1,400
individual licenses.
856
The combination of music with visual content requires a synchronization license—and
synch rights are not subject to government oversight. Section 115 is limited to audio-
only uses of musical works. While not proposing a specific approach, the labels would
like to see section 115 replaced with an updated blanket system that would extend to
consumer audiovisual products.
857
In their view, such a change would facilitate many
common synch transactions, such as the licensing of music videos to online services and
incorporation of music in user-posted videos.
In the eyes of music publishers and songwriters, however, the labels’ suggestion
represents a dramatic and unacceptable expansion of the compulsory system. This
reaction is perhaps not terribly surprising in light of the publishers’ present desire to
phase out mandatory audio-only licensing under section 115.
858
855
Tr. at 155:16-17 (June 4, 2014) (Steven Marks, RIAA); see also Glenn Chapman, YouTube debuts
subscription music service, Y
AHOO NEWS (Nov. 12, 2014), http://news.yahoo.com/youtube-debuts-
subscription-music-video-190223540.html (“YouTube is the world’s biggest online source of free
streaming music and the site has about a billion users a month.”).
856
RIAA First Notice Comments at 10 (“The record company responsible for one current,
successful release obtained 1481 licenses for the project.”).
857
The labels are not proposing to extend any synch licensing solution to uses in “third-party
created product[s],” such as in advertisements and television, which have always required
individualized negotiations with both labels and publishers. See id. at 17.
858
See NMPA Second Notice Comments at 32-33 (“The RIAA rationalizes this approach by
claiming a total abdication of approval rights by musical work owners combined with expanding
167
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The Office is sympathetic to the labels’ concerns, but cannot at this time recommend that
consumer synch uses be incorporated into a government-supervised licensing regime.
As may be apparent from much of the foregoing discussion, once a compulsory license
is implemented it becomes deeply embedded in industry practices andeven when its
original rationale is lost in time—is difficult to undo. That alone should counsel caution
in all but the most manifest instances of market failure.
Here, the Office does not observe such a failure and believes there is even some reason
to be optimistic about private market solutions. First, in the case of new releases, the
labels presumably have some ability (and leverage) to work through audiovisual
licensing issues by virtue of their role with respect to the creation of music videos,
album art, etc. Notably, in the RIAA’s own example of “a single album project”
requiring over a thousand licenses, it seems that licenses were obtained.
859
Additionally, over the last decade, labels and publishers have entered into a series of
NDMAs to facilitate the labels’ licensing of music videos and other products from music
publishers.
860
And in another significant development, YouTube has developed a robust
licensing program and entered into voluntary agreements that enable large and small
labels and publishers to claim and monetize their content.
861
Taken together, these
the scope of formats authorized under Sec. 115 would promote greater efficiency and would
simplify the music licensing process. With an Orwellian spin, they promote the idea that musical
work owners would be enriched if they are, ultimately, disempowered in the digital music
marketplace.”); NSAI Second Notice Comments at 8 (“While the concept of a more efficient
licensing system is something everyone agrees on, the RIAA proposal would basically eliminate
the ability of music publishers or self-published songwriters and composers to initiate or directly
negotiate their own agreements.”). Interestingly, just a few years ago, the publishers were of a
somewhat different mindset, with NMPA advocating for a blanket-style license to cover synch
uses by YouTube and similar services: “If we don’t . . . figure out a way to do mass
synchronizations, we are going to miss out on many business opportunities that could provide
solutions to the declining fortunes of the whole music industry.” David Israelite, David Israelite,
NMPA President’s Guest Post: Why Music Publishers Must Adopt Blanket Licensing, B
ILLBOARD (June
24, 2011), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/publishing/1177339/david-israelite-nmpa-
presidents-guest-post-why-music-publishers.
859
RIAA First Notice Comments at 6, 10.
860
For example, in 2012, NMPA negotiated a licensing framework with UMG to permit
independent publishers to grant UMG the synch rights necessary to stream videos containing
their works on VEVO and YouTube. See NMPA Second Notice Comments at 33; Butler,
UMG/NMPA Broker Model License Agreement; Christman, NMPA Inks Deal With Universal Music
Group Over VEVO, YouTube Videos.
861
In this regard, however, it is worth noting that independent publishers had to pursue an
infringement action against YouTube before YouTube presented them with a licensing offer under
168
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
examples suggest that the market appears to be responding to the need for licensing of
audiovisual uses by consumers and that there is probably no pressing need for
government intervention.
Shift to Blanket Licensing b.
Regardless of its scope or whether it includes an opt-out right, the Office believes that
section 115 should be updated to better meet the needs of the digital age. Congress
attempted to do this in 2006 with the proposed SIRA legislation, which would have
created a blanket mechanical license for digital uses. Although that bill got as far as
passing the relevant House subcommittee,
862
it faced a degree of resistance from certain
industry participants and ultimately foundered.
Based on stakeholders’ sentiments, however—especially those of the digital services
the time seems ripe to revisit the concept of blanket mechanical licensing. Users have
made a strong case in pointing out the inefficiencies of a system that requires multiple
licensees to ascertain song-by-song licensing information and maintain it in redundant
databases. At the same time, they have repeatedly expressed a willingness to pay
royalties in cases where they are unable to track down licensing information for
particular songs in order to mitigate their potential liability for unmatched works.
863
a settlement negotiated by NMPA. See Football Ass’n Premier League v. YouTube, 633 F. Supp. 2d
159.
862
See SIRA, H.R. 5553. In 2006, the House Judiciary Committee’s Subcommittee on Courts, the
Internet, and Intellectual Property forwarded SIRA to the full Judiciary Committee by unanimous
voice vote. See H.R. 5553, C
ONGRESS.GOV (June 8, 2006), https://www.congress.gov/bill/109th-
congress/house-bill/5553.
863
Notably, section 115 has, since its inception, provided a mechanism to file a notice of intent to
use a musical work with the Copyright Office if the owner of the work cannot be found in
Copyright Office records. See 17 U.S.C. § 115(b)(1). Under section 115, no royalties are required
to be collected by the Office in connection with these filings. See id. It is the Office’s
understanding, however, that this provision does little to ameliorate concerns of digital services
in light of the filing fees that the Office must charge to administer such song-by-song notices,
which may number in the thousands or perhaps even the millions for a large service. See DiMA
First Notice Comments at 20 (“[T]o the extent that a service chooses to file statutory license
notices with the Copyright Office for the many musical works for which the relevant
rightsowners cannot be identified, the costs can be overwhelming given the volume of works at
issue.”). Under its current fee schedule, the Office charges a fee of $75 for a notice of intention
covering a single title, and for notices incorporating additional titles, a fee of $20 per 10 additional
titles submitted on paper, and $10 per 100 additional titles submitted electronically. 37 C.F.R. §
201.3(e). Moreover, due to IT constraints within the Library of Congress, the Office is still not
able to accept such submissions in bulk electronic form.
169
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
But while considerably more user-friendly for licensees, blanket licensing cannot be
viewed as a panacea. It does not cure the problem of bad or missing data, or the
inability to match sound recordings with the musical works they embody. In any
situation where a licensed transaction takes place, in order for a royalty to be paid to the
rightsowner, there must be a link between the work used and the owner of that work.
Especially in the case of lesser known works, it can be challenging to match a sound
recording with the musical work it embodies, and that musical work to its owner.
Today, under section 115, the burden of identifying the song and its owners is on the
licensee (or sometimes a third-party agent retained by the licensee); the link is made in
the song-specific license that issues. Blanket licensing merely kicks this responsibility
down the road for another actor to address. Under a blanket system, the obligation to
make the match between the exploited work and its owner falls on the licensing
organizationfor example, the PROwhich must identify the use and connect it to the
owner.
Nonetheless, the Office believes that on the whole, the benefits of a blanket licensing
approach clearly outweigh the conceded challenges of matching reported uses with
copyright owners. Throughout this study, the Office has heard consistent praise for the
efficiencies of blanket licensing by SoundExchange and the PROs, and widespread
frustration with the song-by-song process required under section 115including from
publishers who find themselves burdened with deficient notices and accountings.
Ultimately, it is in the interest of music owners as well as licensees to improve the
licensing process so it is not an obstacle for paying services. To further facilitate the
rights clearance process and eliminate user concerns about liability to unknown
rightsowners, the Office believes that mechanical licensing, like performance licensing,
should be offered on a blanket basis by those that administer it. This would mean that a
licensee would need only to file a single notice to obtain a repertoire-wide performance
and mechanical license from a particular licensing entity. Song-by-song licensing is
widely perceived as a daunting requirement for new services and an administrative
drag on the licensing system as a whole. The move to a blanket system would allow
marketplace entrants to launch their services—and begin paying royaltiesmore
quickly.
Ratesetting c.
As explained above, the Office supports integration of mechanical with performance
rights administration to simplify the licensing process, especially where both rights are
implicated, as in the case of interactive streaming.
864
Even if both rights are not
864
Although publishers traditionally have not sought royalties for the server and other
reproductions necessary to facilitate noninteractive streaming, it would probably be helpful to
clarify the law to provide that any necessary mechanical rights were covered as part of a bundled
170
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
implicatedas in the case of DPD licensing—it would still appear to make sense to
combine licensing resources into unified MROs, especially in a world of declining
mechanicals. In order to reap the rewards of a more unified licensing structure, the
Office further recommends that the ratesetting procedures for mechanical and
performance also be combined.
“As-Needed” Ratesetting
The CRB establishes mechanical rates for the various categories of use that fall under
section 115.
865
The Office believes this responsibility should continue, though with an
important modification: as is now the case with performance rights, rather than
establish rates across the board every five years, the CRB should set rates for particular
uses only on an as-needed basis when an MRO and licensee are unsuccessful in reaching
agreement.
There are currently 17 distinct rate categories under the section 115 license,
866
each with
its own specific rate. Under the current CRB regime, the parties are required to identify
at the outset of the ratesetting proceeding every business model that may be relevant in
the next five years so that a rate can be established for that use. As digital business
models proliferate, so do the rates. The determination of government rates for a
plethora of specific distribution models would seem to be an inefficient way to go about
the ratesetting process. In the first place, new digital models spring up every day, so it is
impossible to keep up with the changing marketplace prospectively. In addition, many
of the rates required to be included in a global ratesetting process might be easily agreed
by the parties without the need for government interventionespecially in the case of
uses that are less economically significant.
license. Cf. Compulsory License for Making and Distributing Phonorecords, Including Digital
Phonorecord Deliveries, 73 Fed. Reg. at 66,180-81 (“[I]f phonorecords are delivered by a
transmission service, then under the last sentence of 115(d) it is irrelevant whether the
transmission that created the phonorecords is interactive or non-interactive.”).
865
A section 115 license is only available after phonorecords of the work in question have first
been distributed to the public in the United States under the authority of the copyright owner. 17
U.S.C. § 115(a)(1). The Office is not recommending any change to this aspect of the statutory
system, which permits musical work owners to control the so-called “first use” (or initial
recording) of their works.
866
These categories include: physical phonorecords and permanent digital downloads (see 37
C.F.R. § 385.3(a)); ringtones (see 37 C.F.R. § 385.3(b)); five compensation models for services
offering interactive streams and limited downloads (see 37 C.F.R. § 385.13(a)); three types of
promotional activities involving interactive streams and limited downloads (see 37 C.F.R. §
385.14(b)-(d)); mixed service bundles, music bundles, limited offerings, paid locker services, and
purchased content locker services (see 37 C.F.R. § 385.23(a)); and free trial periods for certain
service offerings (see 37 C.F.R. § 385.24).
171
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Under the Office’s approach, the CRB would be called upon to set a rate only in the case
of an impasse between two parties. But to borrow from the existing CRB system, other
interested parties (such as other MROs and other users) could choose to join the relevant
proceeding, in which case those parties would also be bound by the CRB-determined
rate (except for publishers opting out of the MRO for the use in question.
867
)
Use of Benchmarks
Throughout the study, there has been significant debate concerning the ratesetting
standard that should be employed by the CRB—some supporting section 801(b)(1)’s
four-factor test that applies to satellite radio and pre-existing subscription services under
section 114, as well as mechanical uses under section 115, while others favor the willing
buyer/willing seller standard that governs internet radio. As discussed above in
connection with the issue of licensing parity, the Office believes that all music users
should operate under a common standard, and that standard should aim to achieve
market rates to the greatest extent possible.
But regardless of the rate standard invoked by the CRB (or for that matter, a rate court),
a critical aspect of the ratesetting analysis is comparison of the requested rates with
relevant market benchmarks, to the extent they exist. In the case of compulsory
licensing, this is an elusive enterprise, since there are no freely negotiated licenses to
inform the tribunal.
As noted above, the Office believes that all potentially informative benchmarks should
be reviewed and evaluated in the ratesetting process. An advantage of the proposed
opt-out system is that there would be a greater likelihood that actual market
benchmarks would exist to inform the ratesetting tribunal. Even where rates remain
subject to government oversight, the Office believes that copyright policy—and
specifically the desire to fairly compensate creators—will be better served by a greater
opportunity to establish rates with reference to real market transactions.
868
867
Section 115 already recognizes that a voluntary agreement can supersede the statutory rate. 17
U.S.C. § 115(c)(3)(E)(i). As a practical matter, however, while voluntary rates for uses subject to
mandatory licensing may be lower, they will not exceed the statutorily fixed rate because the user
may always resort to the compulsory process.
868
Of course, this was the concept pursued by the publishers who withdrew from ASCAP and
BMI to negotiate separate rates with Pandora. There, as explained above, the court rejected two
of the proffered benchmarks due to what it viewed as coercive conduct on the part of the
publishers in the negotiation process. The CRB, too, is free to reject benchmarks that it perceives
to be unreasonable or otherwise without merit. Music Choice v. Copyright Royalty Board, Nos. 13-
1174, 13-1183, 2014 WL 7234800, at *7 (D.C. Cir. Dec. 19, 2014) ( “The [CRJs] were within their
broad discretion to discount [SoundExchange’s proposed] benchmarks and look elsewhere for
guidance,” as the CRJs’ “mandate to issue determinations . . . does not hamstring the Judges
when neither party proposes reasonable or comparable benchmarks.”). Copyright owners would
172
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Interim Rates
There is no current process for establishing an interim rate under the section 115 license.
As with performance rights, the Office believes there should be a simple and expeditious
procedure available to have the CRB establish a temporary mechanical rate for a new
user pending final resolution of the applicable royalty by agreement of the parties or
through a ratesetting proceeding.
Audit Right d.
Publishers and songwriters have long complained about the lack of an audit right under
section 115.
869
In addition to monthly statements of use, the statute provides that each
licensee must provide to the copyright owner a cumulative annual statement that is
certified by a CPA.
870
But section 115 confers no express right for a copyright owner to
audit a licensee’s statements.
871
Although section 114 does not include such an express audit right, it does provide that
the CRB shall “establish requirements by which copyright owners may receive
reasonable notice of the use of their sound recordings under [section 114], and under
which records of such use shall be kept and made available by entities performing
sound recordings.”
872
Based on this authority, the CRB has promulgated regulations to
permit audits of royalty payments of statutory licensees by SoundExchange.
873
Notably,
there is parallel language in section 115, though it is limited to reporting in connection
with the making of DPDs, and no equivalent royalty verification rules have been
promulgated by the CRB under that provision.
874
Regardless of any other potential adjustments to section 115, the Office believes that the
mechanical licensing system should be amended to provide for an express audit right
of course need to ensure that they proceeded carefully and independently in their dealings with
licensees so as not to undermine the value of their agreements for ratesetting purposes.
869
See, e.g., Castle First Notice Comments at 2-3; NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 14-15.
870
In a notable departure from the terms of section 115, HFA, which licenses mechanical rights on
behalf of numerous publishers, does not rely upon the submission of certified annual statements
but instead conducts royalty examinations of significant licensees to verify their payments.
871
By contrast, the section 111 and 119 cable and satellite compulsory licenses, as well as the
Audio Home Recording Act (“AHRA”), provide for a royalty verification process for the benefit of
copyright owners. See 17 U.S.C. §§ 111(d)(6) (cable licensees), 119(b)(2) (satellite licensees),
1003(c)(2) (manufacturers of digital audio recording devices and media).
872
Id. § 114(f)(4)(A).
873
37 C.F.R. §§ 380.6, 380.15, 380.25.
874
17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(3)(D).
173
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
covering the full range of uses under section 115, with the particular logistics of the
audit process to be implemented by regulation.
875
The Office was not made aware during the study of any audit issue in relation to the
PROs.
876
But the Office notes that in any updated system, it would be critical for
copyright owners to be able to verify not just mechanical royalties but performance
income as well (which could be combined under a bundled license). Audit activities
could perhaps be coordinated through the GMRO; once an audit was noticed by one
MRO, others could choose to participate in the audit process, sharing in its costs and any
recovery.
877
This type of coordinated audit process has been implemented under the
cable and satellite licenses as well as under the AHRA.
878
Sunset of Existing Section 115 Licenses e.
PRO licenses typically have an initial term of up to five years.
879
A licensee may
therefore need to renegotiate its license with one or more PROs every several years. For
this reason, while specific details would undoubtedly need to be addressed, existing
875
In light of the Office’s primary responsibility under the existing section 115 framework for
determining the requirements for statements of account, it may be sensible to assign rulemaking
responsibility for audits of these statements to the Office rather than the CRB. See 17 U.S.C. §
115(c)(5); id. § 803(c)(3) (CRBs may specify recordkeeping requirements as part of a ratesetting
determination); see also Division of Authority Between the Copyright Royalty Judges and the
Register of Copyrights under the Section 115 Statutory License, 73 Fed. Reg. 48,396 (Aug. 19,
2008) (explaining responsibilities of the Office versus the CRB in this area).
876
It appears that currently, PROs do not have any significant audit rights, compelling them to
accept “payments at best-effort levels and face value, but not necessarily accurate.” Derek
Crownover, Small Music Publishers Face Uphill Battle, T
ENNESSEAN (Aug. 14, 2014),
http://www.tennessean.com/story/money/industries/music/2014/08/15/small-music-publishers-
face-uphill-battle/14075783/. In fact, the ASCAP consent decree merely suggests that ASCAP
“may require its . . . licensees to provide ASCAP with all information reasonably necessary to
administer the per-program or per-segment license,” while the BMI consent decree has no such
requirement. ASCAP Consent Decree § VIII.C; BMI Consent Decree.
877
Publishers who had negotiated direct licenses with digital providers would be responsible for
managing their own audits in keeping with their individual contracts.
878
See 37 C.F.R. § 201.30 (setting forth the procedure for verification of statements of account
submitted by cable operators and satellite carriers).
879
See ASCAP Consent Decree § IV.D (ASCAP is prohibited from “[g]ranting any license to any
music user for rights of public performance in excess of five years’ duration.”). This restriction is
not found in the BMI Consent Decree, although the Office understands that BMI’s licensing
practices tend to track ASCAP’s in this regard, perhaps due to the fact that “the DOJ often takes
the view that BMI and ASCAP should operate under similar rules.” BMI First Notice Comments
at 16. It is the Office’s further understanding that such licenses may be subject to automatic
extensions unless terminated by either the PRO or licensee.
174
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
PRO licenses would not appear to present an obstacle to implementing the changes
proposed here. A license granted under section 115, on the other hand, does not have an
end date. A question therefore arises as to how the millions of existing section 115
licenses would be retired.
The Office believes there is an answer to this question—as, apparently, do the digital
companies who have advocated for a new blanket system (as well as the publishers that
have advocated for an end to section 115 altogether). Significantly, the rates and terms
in a section 115 license do not continue in perpetuity but instead are adjusted every five
years in accordance with the CRB’s statutory schedule.
880
Thus, there can be no
expectation on the part of a licensee that particular rates or terms will continue beyond
the five-year statutory period.
In sunsetting the song-by-song licensing system, there would need to be a period of
transition, of course, during which the user would apply for licenses from the several
MROs. Assuming, however, that that period of transition were tied to the then-
applicable rate period, the changeover should not harm any legitimate expectation
concerning rates.
4. Section 112 and 114 Licenses
One of the few things that seems to be working reasonably well in our licensing system
is the statutory license regime under sections 112 and 114, which permits qualifying
digital services to engage in noninteractive streaming activities at a CRB-determined (or
otherwise agreed) rate. The section 112 and 114 licenses—administered by
SoundExchange, a nonprofit entity designated by the CRB—cover both internet and
satellite radio providers and certain subscription music services. Although the differing
ratesetting standards for these licenses—as well as some of the rates established under
those standardshave been a source of controversy, from the record in this study, the
licensing framework itself is generally well regarded.
Recording artists, as well as backup musicians and vocalists, appreciate the fact that they
are paid their respective shares of royalties for digital performances under the statutory
formula administered by SoundExchange.
881
SoundExchange deducts a modest
880
Notably, because HFA licenses incorporate the key aspects of section 115, they too are subject
to the periodic statutory rate adjustments.
881
Section 114 provides that 45% of royalties are to be paid to the featured artist, 2.5% to the
union that represents nonfeatured musicians, and 2.5% to the union for nonfeatured vocalists,
with the remaining 50% paid to the owner of the sound recording, typically a record label. 17
U.S.C. § 114(g)(2).
175
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
administrative fee from distributed royaltiescurrently approximately 4.5%to offset
its costs of operations.
882
SoundExchange engages in significant efforts to locate and register artists whose
royalties it is holding. By regulation, unattributed royalties that remain unclaimed after
a period of at least three years may be used to help defray SoundExchange’s ongoing
administrative expenses.
883
In recent years, the pool of unclaimed royalties that are three
or more years old has ranged as high as $31 million dollars.
884
By comparison, however,
SoundExchange’s annual distributions totaled $773 million in 2014.
885
Scope of Licenses a.
Notwithstanding the comparatively positive reviews of the section 112 and 114 licenses,
there are a few ways in which some have suggested they should be tweaked.
Adjust to Include Terrestrial
In contrast to the general sentiments of musical work owners, some independent record
labels and artistswho may be more challenged in negotiating with music services than
their larger counterparts, and also like being paid through SoundExchangehave
suggested that the section 112 and 114 compulsory licenses be expanded to cover
interactive streaming in addition to noninteractive models.
886
Digital providers, too,
would welcome such a change.
887
882
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 4.
883
37 C.F.R. § 380.8.
884
Press Release, SoundExchange, SoundExchange Releases List of Recording Artists and Record
Labels with Unclaimed Digital Performance Royalties (Aug. 15, 2012), http://www.
soundexchange.com/pr/soundexchange-releases-list-of-recording-artists-and-record-labels-with-
unclaimed-digital-performance-royalties/. SoundExchange recently reallocated $9.3 million from
its unclaimed royalty pool to its administrative fund. Glenn Peoples, SoundExchange Finally
Releases Old, Unclaimed Royalties, B
ILLBOARD (Jan. 31, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/biz/
articles/news/5893782/soundexchange-finally-releases-old-unclaimed-royalties.
885
See Glenn Peoples, SoundExchange Paid Out a Whopping $773 Million in 2014, BILLBOARD (Jan.
29, 2015), http://www.billboard.com/articles/business/6457827/soundexchange-digital-
performance-royalty-distributions-2014.
886
See FMC First Notice Comments at 11-12; Kohn First Notice Comments at 13-14; SAG-AFTRA
& AFM First Notice Comments at 6; see also A2IM First Notice Comments at 5 (supporting a
narrower definition of “interactive”).
887
See Tr. at 138:19-139:09 (June 4, 2014) (Lee Knife, DiMA) (“The idea that we [DiMA services]
have to go to all of these different people, depending on whether you’re interactive, you’re
noninteractive, whether you’re downloading, whether you’re streaming it and the download is
available to be heard while it’s downloading . . . most of my services want to or do engage in all
176
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
While the Office understands these points of view, it seems unlikely as a political matter
that the major record labels could be persuaded to give up their current ability to
negotiate such rates in the open market. Moreover, the Office does not perceive that the
voluntary market for licensing of sound recording rights is not functioning.
That said, assuming Congress broadens the sound recording performance right to
include terrestrial broadcasts, in keeping with the principle that analogous uses should
be treated alike, it would seem only logical that terrestrial uses should be included
under the section 112 and 114 licenses. The CRB would be in the best position to
establish equitable rates to apply to both over-the-air and internet radio.
Qualifying Versus Nonqualifying Services
The section 112 and 114 licensing framework excludes interactive streaming and
imposes additional technical requirements as well on those seeking a statutory license.
While licensees complain about the constraints of section 114, on the other side of the
coin, questions arise as to how much control a listener should be able to have over a
customized radio playlist before the service is considered to be offering more of an on-
demand than passive experience.
Section 114 defines an interactive service in relevant part as “one that enables a member
of the public to receive a transmission of a program specially created for the recipient, or
on request, a transmission of a particular sound recording, whether or not part of a
program, which is selected by or on behalf of the recipient.”
888
In 2009, the Second
Circuit Court of Appeals held that the Launchcast music service—which did not offer
on-demand streaming but customized its programming for recipients based on their
individual ratings of songs—was not interactive within the meaning of this definition.
889
As a result of this precedent, internet radio services offering customized listening
experiences are able to operate under the compulsory license regime.
Some question the Second Circuit’s interpretation of the line between interactive and
noninteractive streaming.
890
As articulated by the RIAA, “[t]he [Launch Media] decision
has emboldened services to offer listeners an increasingly personalized listening
experience under color of the statutory license, and all but extinguished voluntary
of those different activities at once. We’d love to be able to just get a license for music and simply
report what the type of use was and pay for it.”).
888
17 U.S.C. § 114(j)(7).
889
Launch Media, 578 F.3d at 164.
890
See RIAA First Notice Comments at 33-34; SAG-AFTRA & AFM First Notice Comments at 5-6;
see also NARAS First Notice Comments at 5; NAB First Notice Comments at 4; NRBMLC First
Notice Comments at 24; NPR First Notice Comments at 5; SRN Broadcasting First Notice
Comments at 1.
177
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
licensing of personalized streaming services at a premium to the statutory rate.”
891
The
RIAA’s chief concern appears to be that the rate for customized radio is the same as that
for completely nonpersonalized offerings.
While the Office has some reservations about the interpretation of section 114 by the
Launch Media courtwhich seems somewhat in tension with the statutory language
there appears to be no overwhelming entreaty to remove custom radio from the
statutory regime.
892
Within that regime, however, it may be appropriate to distinguish
between custom and noncustom radio, as the substitutional effect of personalized radio
on potentially competing interactive streaming services may be greater than that of
services offering a completely noncustomized experience. While the issue could be
addressed legislatively, such an approach would not appear to require statutory change,
as the CRB has the discretion to set different rate tiers today when the record supports
such an outcome.
893
For their part, internet providers have criticized the constraints that section 114 imposes
on services that seek to operate under the compulsory license.
894
These include the
“sound recording performance complement,” a restriction that limits the frequency with
which songs from the same album or by the same artist may be played by the service.
895
There is also a statutory prohibition against announcing upcoming songs—a practice
that is common in the terrestrial world, and therefore presents problems for online
simulcasters.
896
Congress included these limitations in the section 114 license to mitigate
the potential substitutional impact of noninteractive streaming on sales or other revenue
streams.
897
In the Office’s view, these sorts of requirements fall into a category of relative fine-
tuning of the license. But for the fact that they are laid out in the statute itself, their
891
RIAA First Notice Comments at 34.
892
See, e.g., id. (“While, at this juncture, we do not necessarily advocate excluding from the
statutory license services that have been generally accepted as operating within the statutory
license based on the [Launch Media] decision, we do think it is important, at a minimum, that
services offering more functionality, such as personalization features, should pay higher rates.”).
893
See 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(A)-(2)(A) (rates and terms “shall distinguish among different types of .
. . services in operation”); id. § 803(c)(3) (CRB’s determination to be supported by written record).
894
See NAB First Notice Comments at 4; NRBMLC First Notice Comments at 24; NPR First Notice
Comments at 5; SRN Broadcasting First Notice Comments at 1.
895
17 U.S.C. § 114(j)(13).
896
Id. § 114 (d)(2)(C)(ii); see also, e.g., NAB First Notice Comments at 4-5; NRBMLC First Notice
Comments at 24; NPR First Notice Comments at 5; SRN Broadcasting First Notice Comments at
1.
897
See H.R. REP. NO. 104-274, at 13-15, 20-21.
178
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
particulars would seem to be more appropriately the province of regulation. As
suggested below, the Office believes that in updating the music licensing system,
Congress should commit more of its nuances to administrative oversight. The technical
conditions for eligibility under the section 112 and 114 licenses would seem to fall into
this category, as the effectiveness and impact of these provisions has likely changed, and
will continue to change, over time.
Finally, some have suggested a modification of the provisions of sections 112 and 114
that permit the making of server—or “ephemeral”—copies to facilitate licensed services.
These parties seek to confirm that multiple server copies may be made and retained
indefinitely by a licensed service.
898
Although the main provision at issue—17 U.S.C. §
112(e)—is less than a model of clarity,
899
the Office is not aware that the imprecision has
resulted in any real-world disputes, and does not see this as an especially pressing
issue.
900
Nonetheless, it would probably be worthwhile in any general update of
sections 112 and 114 to refine the statutory language with respect to the number and
retention of server copies so as to eliminate any doubt as to the operation of the section
112 license.
Ratesetting b.
The embattled ratesetting standards for internet and satellite radio—section 801(b)(1)
versus willing buyer/willing seller—are discussed at some length above in connection
with overall questions of licensing parity. As explained there, the Office believes that
government ratesetting processes for both sound recordings and music should be
conducted under a single, market-oriented standard. Accordingly, in the Office’s view,
898
CTIA First Notice Comments at 16-18; NAB First Notice Comments at 2, 7; Music Choice First
Notice Comments at 11-13; DiMA Second Notice Comments at 18.
899
Section 112(e) somewhat cryptically indicates that only a single phonorecord (i.e., server copy)
can be made “unless the terms and conditions of the statutory license allow for more.” 17 U.S.C. §
112(e).
900
A larger question may be whether the provisions of the section 112 license pertaining to the
copies made to support section 114 services should be folded into section 114 to create a truly
unified license covering both performances and necessary reproduction rights. As it currently
stands, the CRB is obligated in the relevant ratesetting proceedings to set a separate (and in
practice, essentially nominal) rate for the ephemeral uses. See 17 U.S.C. § 112(e)(3);
SoundExchange, Inc. v. Librarian of Congress, 571 F.3d 1220, 1225-26 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (remanding to
the CRB to specify a royalty for the use of the ephemeral recordings); Determination of Rates and
Terms for Preexisting Subscription Services and Satellite Digital Audio Radio Services, 75 Fed.
Reg. 5513 (Feb. 3, 2010) (setting a separate rate for the 112(e) license). The proportion of royalties
payable under section 112 is of some economic consequence, however, as unlike section 114
royaltieswhich are paid directly to performing artists and musicians as well as to record
labelssection 112 royalties are paid only to sound recording owners. See Review of Copyright
Royalty Judges Determination, 73 Fed. Reg. at 9146. Because it was not a focus of discussion
during the study, the Office has not formed an opinion on this.
179
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
the section 112 and 114 rates currently set under the 801(b)(1) standard (i.e., those
applicable to satellite radio and pre-existing subscription services) should be migrated to
the willing buyer/willing seller standard or some alternative formulation aimed at
establishing rates equivalent to those that would be negotiated in the free market.
901
The
Office further recommends that ratesetting should occur on an “as-needed” basis, as
described above.
Producer Payments c.
The Office notes the further concern of some that the section 112 and 114 royalty
allocations do not recognize the contributions of sound recording producers, who in
many instances not only supervise, but also have significant creative input into, finished
recordings. Despite the fact that many producers are creators of sound recordings in
their own right, they are not among the parties entitled by statute to direct payment by
SoundExchange.
902
Compensation of producers is contractually based. They may be paid an up-front fee for
their efforts and/or receive a share of the artist’s future royalties.
903
In some cases, an
artist may provide a letter of direction requesting SoundExchange to pay the producer’s
share of the artist royalties collected by SoundExchange, which SoundExchange will
honor.
904
NARAS has suggested that this informal practice—which is not contemplated
by the statutory payment mechanism set forth in section 114—be recognized through a
legislative amendment. In NARAS’ words, this will provide producers “the same fair,
direct-payment option available to performers.”
905
Because the producer’s share comes out of the featured artist’s statutory entitlement,
such recognition would not require a change in the current statutory allocation, but
would merely clarify the authority of SoundExchange to honor a letter of direction.
901
Section 114 provides for an interim ratesetting process for new services. See 17 U.S.C. §
114(f)(2)(C) (allowing copyright owners or new services to initiate out-of-cycle proceeding). It
does not provide for expedited proceedings, however. The Office did not hear much about the
use or efficacy of this process in the course of its study, perhaps because it is rarely invoked. As
discussed in connection with musical work performance and mechanical licenses, however, the
Office believes it is important to have a cost-effective and expeditious interim ratesetting
procedure, which could be implemented for the section 112 and 114 licenses as well under the
Office’s proposed system.
902
These include sound recording owners, featured artists, and unions representing nonfeatured
musicians and vocalists. 17 U.S.C. § 114(g)(2).
903
PASSMAN at 121-126.
904
2013 SoundExchange Letter of Direction.
905
See NARAS First Notice Comments at 5-6.
180
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Though it would be beneficial to hear more from artists on this issue,
906
the Office agrees
that NARAS’ proposal to confirm the existing practice through a technical amendment
of the statute merits consideration.
Termination Provision d.
Unlike section 115, sections 112 and 114 do not include a right to terminate a licensee
that fails to account for and pay royalties. This not only severely undermines the ability
of SoundExchange to police noncompliant licenses, but also allows such licensees to
continue to exploit valuable sound recordings without payment to their owners. As
SoundExchange explains it:
Noncompliance with statutory license requirements is commonplace. For
2013, approximately a quarter of royalty payments were not made on
time; two-thirds of licensees required to deliver reports of the recordings
they used have not delivered at least one required report; and at least one
quarter of such licensees have not delivered any such reports at all.
907
SoundExchange observes that it tries to work with problem licensees to improve their
compliance. But when such efforts prove unsuccessful, SoundExchangeand the
copyright owners it represents—should have a remedy. The Office does not see a
justification for continued licensing of a user that is not meeting its obligations. The
Office therefore agrees with SoundExchange that the section 112 and 114 statutory
licenses should be amended to include a termination provision akin to that in section
115.
908
5. Public and Noncommercial Broadcasting
Public broadcastersincluding noncommercial educational broadcasters—lament the
inefficiencies and limitations of the statutory provisions in sections 114 and 118 that
906
Recording artists did not comment on this proposal in the course of the study.
907
SoundExchange First Notice Comments at 5.
908
Section 115 provides that:
If the copyright owner does not receive the monthly payment and the monthly
and annual statements of account when due, the owner may give written notice
to the licensee that, unless the default is remedied within thirty days from the
date of the notice, the compulsory license will be automatically terminated. Such
termination renders either the making or the distribution, or both, of all
phonorecords for which the royalty has not been paid, actionable as acts of
infringement under section 501 and fully subject to the remedies provided by
sections 502 through 506.
17 U.S.C. § 115(c)(6).
181
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
govern their use of music content.
909
The Office concurs that these provisions are
unwieldy and believes that they should be reviewed and updated to better reflect
Congress’ desire to accommodate public broadcasting activities.
910
Especially in light of the relatively low royalty rates paid by public broadcasters, it
makes little sense to require them to engage in a multitude of negotiations and
ratesetting proceedings in different forabefore the CRB under sections 112 and 114 for
digital sound recording performance rights, before the CRB under section 118 for over-
the-air musical work performance and associated reproduction rights, under the consent
decrees for digital musical work performance rights covered by ASCAP and BMI, and
through private negotiations for musical work performance and reproduction rights
falling outside of the foregoing categories.
911
Instead, the Office suggests that the
ratesetting processes applicable to public broadcasters be consolidated within a unified
license structure under section 118 under the auspices of the CRB.
912
By separating out
all noncommercial uses for consideration under a single framework, the royalty rates for
public broadcasters would likely be much more efficiently resolved.
913
909
See EMF First Notice Comments at 5-15; NPR First Notice Comments at 4-7; NRBNMLC First
Notice Comments at 14-22; PTC First Notice Comments at 3-12.
910
See, e.g., H.R. REP. NO. 94-1476, at 117 (noting “that encouragement and support of
noncommercial broadcasting is in the public interest” and “that the nature of public broadcasting
does warrant special treatment in certain areas”).
911
See generally NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 14-15.
912
See EMF First Notice Comments at 14-15. In so amending the section 118 license to cover both
sound recording and public performance rights, it may be appropriate to expand the antitrust
exemption currently contained in section 118 to facilitate collective negotiation of rights between
noncommercial users and copyright owners for uses outside the statutory license as well. See
PTC First Notice Comments at 11.
913
Compare NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 14 (noting that “[f]or the last several license
terms, religious broadcasters . . . have been able to agree upon rates and terms with ASCAP, BMI,
and SESAC without the need for a rate-setting proceeding”), with EMF First Notice Comments at
8-9 (noting that the section 114 rulemaking joins both commercial and noncommercial entities,
and that noncommercial entities “are rarely able to negotiated a pre-litigation settlementforcing
their participation in the CRB litigation process”).
In establishing a unified license for public broadcast activities, the Office sees no need to depart
from its view that, as with other statutory uses, the CRB should consider such rates under a
generally applicable, market-based standard. Experience with the section 112 and 114 ratesetting
process for noncommercial entities has shown, for example, that the willing buyer/willing seller
standard can adequately account for the limited financial resources of, and other factors
particular to, noncommercial users. See NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 11-13 (noting that
the CARP and CRB have consistently set lower rates for noncommercial broadcasters).
182
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
In reforming the section 118 license, Congress should ensure it appropriately facilitates
digital transmissions by public broadcasters, including the streaming of archived
programming.
914
But absent a significant change in congressional policy, the Office sees
no need to expand the statutory license to include permanent uses such as downloads or
physical products, as some noncommercial broadcasters have suggested.
915
The current
statutory provisions for public broadcasting focus on performances in the course of
over-the-air programming, rather than the distribution of copyrighted works.
Permanent uses by noncommercial entitiesor even on-demand streaming of individual
songs outside of the context of the original programmingcould displace commercial
sales, making it less clear that special treatment is appropriate.
D. Licensing Efficiency and Transparency
There seems to be universal agreement among industry participants that accurate,
comprehensive, and accessible licensing information, as well as transparent usage and
payment data, are essential to a better functioning music licensing system.
1. Industry Data
Publicly Accessible Database a.
Some stakeholders have suggested that the government—for example, the Copyright
Office—could undertake the task of creating and maintaining a comprehensive database
of musical work and sound recording information, including a system of standard
identifiers.
916
As appealing as such a vision may be, the Office believes that it would not
be the best result for the twenty-first century marketplace to have the government start
from scratch. The relevant universe of music data comprises tens of millions of musical
works, sound recordings and information about them. Setting aside any legal
impediments, as a practical matter, it would be extremely challenging for the
government to gather, ingest, and standardize this ocean of information to be made
available within a useful time frame. Any such database would be highly dynamic and
require a constant flow of information from MROs, publishers and others concerning
newly created works, transfers of ownership, and changes in licensing authority to be
kept up to date. These are functions already performed in varying degrees by existing
private organizations in collaboration with individual stakeholders.
In light of the above considerations, the Office believes that any solution to the music
data problem should not compete with, but instead draw upon, existing industry
resources. As a threshold matter, any centralized database should be closely tied to the
914
NRBNMLC First Notice Comments at 14.
915
See NPR First Notice Comments at 7.
916
ABKCO First Notice Comments at 4; DiMA Second Notice Comments at 5.
183
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
interests of the copyright owners and licensees it serves. That said, the government
should establish incentives through the statutory licensing regime to encourage private
actors to coordinate their efforts and contribute to a publicly accessible and authoritative
database. In other words, there is a role for both the government and private sector
alike.
917
Adoption of Data Standards b.
The lack of unique and universally employed identifiers for the millions of musical
works and sound recordings in the marketplace has been a topic of discussionand
source of discouragement—among industry participants for many years. As a result,
there have been some laudable efforts within the industry to address the data problem
by persuading market participants to adopt standard identifiers and messaging formats,
with some amount of success. The DDEX messaging system appears to have emerged as
a leading industry standard for the formatting and delivery of metadata relating to
transactions involving digital music.
918
A more recent example of collaboration is the
MusicMark initiative, which would rationalize and reconcile sometimes conflicting PRO
song data among the American and Canadian PROs ASCAP, BMI, and SOCAN.
919
But despite these efforts, so far, no comprehensive solution to the data issue has
emerged.
920
In part, this appears to be a problem of coordinating private actors, many of
whom are invested in, and understandably rely upon, their own data systems and do
not wish to undermine these important assets. It is also a legacy problem, in that much
of the data used today originated in the pre-digital era, when standardization and
interoperability were not critical concerns. For example, the industry did not implement
standard conventions for the treatment of artist or songwriter names. Some actors may
917
This does not mean that the Copyright Office should not itself seek to maintain more robust
music data. To the extent it has the resources to modernize its systems to accommodate more
comprehensive data, it should. For example, the copyright registration database could be
modified to incorporate identifiers such as ISRCs and ISWCs. The Office’s paper-based
recordation system should be reengineered to become an electronic process so it is easier to
record and research transfers of ownership. Both of these changes would help would-be
licensees locate music owners. The Office has been reviewing these and other technology and
data-driven questions in separate public processes. See, e.g., B
RAUNEIS; see also Maria Pallante,
Next Generation Copyright Office: What it Means and Why it Matters, 61 J. Copyright Soc’y U.S.A. 213
(2014).
918
About DDEX, DDEX, http://www.ddex.net/about-ddex (last visited Jan. 9. 2015).
919
Tr. at 263:21-264:03 (June 24, 2014) (Stuart Rosen, BMI); see also ASCAP, BMI and SOCAN
Collaborate on MusicMark, ASCAP (Apr. 2, 2014), http://www.ascap.com/playback/2014/04/action/
ascap-bmi-socan-musicmark-collaboration.aspx.
920
PRS ‘disappointed’ at Global Repertoire Database collapse, MUSIC ALLY.
184
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
see little short-term gain to be realized from the substantial investment of resources it
would take to clean up and harmonize older records.
Some stakeholders advocate for an entirely new approach to tracking creative works and
usage, suggesting that we should look to new technologies to attach unique identifiers to
each different version of a song, each different recording of that song, each individual’s
interest in that song, and each individual use of that song.
921
One interesting proposal
would rely on audio fingerprinting rather than just metadata to identify songs.
922
The
Office hopes that these or other technological innovations may someday be deployed to
the benefit of the music marketplace.
For now, though, the Office believes it is important to focus on what might be
reasonably achieved in the near term—again taking into consideration and capitalizing
upon industry practices as they exist today. To this end, the Office solicited comments
on the most commonly used and useful identifiers, and received helpful guidance from
a number of parties.
923
Based on these comments, it appears that the most critical and
widely (though not universally) used identifiers are, in the case of musical works, the
ISWC, and in the case of sound recordings, the ISRC. The Office believes these two
identifiers should, over a period of time (e.g., five years), become required elements
within the proposed GMRO-managed database, as described below.
A more recent standard is the ISNI, which can be used to identify songwriters and
recording artists, and is gaining acceptance in the industry. There appears to be general
agreement that, as new users and uses continue to proliferate, and individual writers
and artists seek to participate in the marketplace, it is of critical importance to be able to
identify creators unambiguously.
924
ASCAP and BMI have already begun implementing
the use of ISNI.
925
This is another data standard that the Office believes should be
encouraged and possibly made mandatory over a plausible time frame.
921
Music Licensing Hearings at 71-72 (statement of Jim Griffin, OneHouse).
922
Tr. at 243:13-18 (June 17, 2014) (Helene Muddiman, CEO, Hollywood Elite Composers); see also
How Content ID Works, G
OOGLE, https://support.google.com/youtube/answer/2797370?hl=en (last
visited Jan. 23, 2015).
923
Of particular assistance was the student submission from the Pipeline Project 2014, Belmont
University’s Mike Curb College of Music Business and Entertainment, which provided an
insightful summary and analysis of relevant data standards based on a series of interviews the
students conducted with music industry professionals. See generally Pipeline Project Second
Notice Comments.
924
Kristin Thomson, Metadata for Musicians.
925
ASCAP Second Notice Comments at 8; see also Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 4-
5.
185
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
The ISWC standard and the ISRC standard are internationally recognized, as is the ISNI.
The ISWC, developed by CISAC, is assigned by individual qualified regional or local
numbering agencies; in the U.S. and Canada, ASCAP is the appointed ISWC
administrator.
926
The ISRC, administered by IFPI, is allocated by appointed regional
agencies in each country; the U.S. ISRC agency is the RIAA.
927
The ISNI standard,
launched with CISAC’s participation, is meant to replace existing, disparate
identification standards for individual creators.
928
ISNIs are assigned to U.S. authors by
one or more designated private registration agencies.
929
The Office’s focus on the above standards does not mean that others are unimportant or
irrelevant.
930
Legacy standards remain useful for particular entities,
931
and new
standards may come into play. The possibility of identifying sound recordings and
musical works through audio-based sampling technologies is especially intriguing.
Based on the current state of affairs, however, the Office believes that the most realistic
strategy to address the data issues plaguing the music industry at present would be to
strongly incentivize the universal adoption and dissemination of at least the three data
standards described above. Beyond this, as discussed below, it would make sense to
provide for regulatory authority to allow for the consideration and adoption of
additional data standards over time as appropriate.
2. Fair Reporting and Payment
Writer and Artist Shares a.
Throughout the study, a paramount concern of songwriters and recording artists is
transparency in reporting and payment. As digital licensing deals multiply and increase
in complexity, it can become quite difficult to follow the money. Songwriters and artists
926
Frequently Asked Questions, ISWC INTERNATIONAL AGENCY, http://www.iswc.org/en/faq.html
(last visited Jan. 23, 2015); Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 5.
927
Obtaining Code, USISRC.ORG, http://www.usisrc.org/about/obtaining_code.html (last visited
Jan. 23, 2015); Pipeline Project Second Notice Comments at 6.
928
See Gatenby & MacEwan at 5-6.
929
The first U.S. registration agency is Bowker, an affiliate of the research and technology
company ProQuest. See id.; Bowker Becomes First ISNI Registration Agency in the U.S., B
OWKER
(June 21, 2012), http://www.bowker.com/en-US/aboutus/press_room/2012/pr_06212012a.shtml;
Bowker, Use of ISNI Is Growing Fast Among Authors, Says New Bowker Analysis, Y
AHOO FINANCE
(May 7, 2014), http://finance.yahoo.com/news/isni-growing-fast-among-authors-144800650.html.
930
As suggested below, additional standards that might be useful in either the short or long term
could be evaluated and potentially adopted by regulation.
931
For example, if IPIs and UPCs (discussed above) continue to be relevant in some contexts, they
might be considered as potential additional data elements to be collected in the GMRO database.
186
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
want to ensure that they understand the royalty scheme, are able to track the use of their
works, and are paid what they are owed.
In the case of performance royalties, such concerns are greatly diminished when the
songwriter or artist is paid through a PRO or SoundExchange. PROs employ
distribution rules that are generally known by their members,
932
while SoundExchange
allocates royalties according to the statutory formula. In the case of a direct deal,
however, the label or publisher is obligated only by the terms of the artist or songwriter
agreement, which may not expressly address these issues.
933
Of particular concern are the sometimes sizeable advances against future royalties that
are paid by online services to major record labels and music publishers, and whether
and how these are reported to and shared with artists and writers. Sometimes, if royalty
obligations are less than anticipated, such an advance may not be fully recouped by the
service during the licensing period, so there are leftover funds. In such a situation, there
may be no clear understanding—or contractual provision—that addresses whether those
funds should be paid out to the songwriter or artist, or if so, on what basis. A recent
example of the advance issue cited by songwriters is a direct deal between the publisher
Sony/ATV and DMX music service for public performance rights, in which Sony/ATV
apparently received a large advance from the service—possibly in exchange for a lower
royalty rate.
934
Songwriters worry that they are not able to monitor this type of
arrangement to ensure that they receive their fair share of the total consideration paid
for the use of their works.
Also concerning to music creators is the fact that labels and publishers are now known
to take equity stakes in online services as part of their licensing arrangements. For
example, the major labels together reportedly negotiated a nearly 18% stake in Spotify.
935
932
ASCAP’s Survey and Distribution System: Rules & Policies, ASCAP (June 2014),
http://www.ascap.com/~/media/files/pdf/members/payment/drd.pdf; Royalty Policy Manual, BMI,
http://www.bmi.com/creators/royalty_print (last visited Jan. 16, 2015). Although songwriters
appear generally to have confidence that the PROs are reporting to them accurately, there are
some writers who take issue with the distribution rules themselves. For example, ASCAP and
BMI pay substantial bonuses for current hits, which reduce the royalty pool for “evergreen” titles.
In addition, PROs rely on sampling techniques rather than census data to calculate royalties in
many contexts, which some complain may cause less popular songs to be overlooked. Tr. at
22:11-27:01 (June 5, 2014) (Royal Wade Kimes, Wonderment Records) (“We do need a collective,
ASCAP, BMI, somebody to collect the stuff, but we also need it to be distributed rightly.”).
933
Indeed, at least until recently, songwriter agreements with publishers simply assumed
payment of the writer’s share of performance royalties by a PRO. See, e.g., Tr. at 71:13-72:03 (June
5, 2014) (Brittany Schaffer, NMPA/Loeb & Loeb LLP).
934
MMF & FAC Second Notice Comments at 16-17, 47 n.70; SGA Second Notice Comments at 14-
15, Exhibit 2 n.7.
935
See Lindvall, Behind the Music: The Real Reason Why the Major Labels Love Spotify.
187
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Questions arise as to how such equity deals are (or are not) reported to artists and
songwriters, and whether the value received by the label or publisher impacts the
royalties that are paid.
936
Again, the artist or songwriter contract may not address such
issues.
937
These concerns must be addressed as part of any updated licensing framework,
especially one that allows publishers to opt out of the statutory licensing system and
pursue direct deals. As mentioned above, under any such deal, songwriters should have
the option of being paid their writer’s share of performance royalties directly through
their preferred MRO. That is, even if the music service is paying the publisher’s
royalties (including mechanicals) to the publisher directly, it would transmit a copy of
its usage report and the writers share of performance royalties to the MRO for the MRO
to administer.
938
The Office trusts that such an approach could be acceptable to the
publishers, since the major publishers who have been contemplating withdrawal from
the PROs appear also to be considering the possibility of continuing administration of
royalty distributions by the PROs under directly licensed deals.
939
While there has been less focus on this issue in relation to SoundExchange—which is not
facing a large-scale “withdrawal” problem
940
—the Office notes that the same principle
936
See A2IM Second Notice Comments at 5-7 (explaining that some of the largest digital music
services have entered into direct licensing deals with record labels or publishers that include
compensation in the form of advances or equity, but that such compensation is not necessarily
shared with creators); SGA Second Notice Comments at 14-15.
937
Notably, however, music publishers have addressed this issue in their negotiated streaming
settlement under section 115, since adopted as regulation. 37 C.F.R. § 385. The definition of
revenue to which the percentage royalty rate is applied in the streaming regulations requires
record companies to account for “anything of value given for the identified rights to undertake
the licensed activity, including, without limitation, ownership equity, monetary advances, barter
or any other monetary and/or nonmonetary consideration . . .” Id. § 385.11, 385.21 (definition of
“applicable consideration”).
938
To ensure the transparency of such a hybrid arrangement, the withdrawing publishers should
make the material financial terms of their direct dealsthe royalty rates, advances, and any other
consideration from the licensee attributable to the use of the songwriter’s workavailable to their
songwriters.
939
See Pandora Ratesetting, 6 F. Supp. 3d at 337; see also Tr. at 38:06-08 (June 17, 2014) (David
Kokakis, UMPG); BMI Second Notice Comments at 14 (“In the context of partial rights
withdrawal, BMI can still assist publishers in providing certain royalty administration services
for their direct licenses covering the withdrawn rights, with administration terms and fees as
agreed to by the parties. BMI would continue to provide its customary licensing and distribution
services to the publishers and songwriters with regard to all other aspects of the public
performing right.”).
940
In this regard, however, it should be noted that there has recently been some direct licensing of
noninteractive digital performance rights outside of SoundExchange. As mentioned above,
188
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
should apply there. To the extent record companies enter into direct licensing
relationships with digital providers, artists and musicians should have the option of
continuing to receive their share of royalties through that organization.
Best Practices for Transparency b.
More generally, issues surrounding transparency in reporting and payment by music
publishers and record labels under songwriter and artist agreements are concerns that
might be productively addressed through the consideration and adoption of best
practices to ease friction in this area. In 2009, for instance, record labels and music
publishers agreed to a series of voluntary changes to improve licensing practices and the
flow of royalties under section 115, which have been memorialized in a continuing
memorandum of understanding.
941
A similar effort might be undertaken to establish
best practices to ensure transparency in label and publisher reporting and payment to
creators. The Office hopes that major labels and publishers will consider engaging with
artists and publishers in a voluntary fashion to make progress on these issues in the
private realm.
E. An Updated Music Licensing System
As noted above, nearly ten years ago, music publishers and digital media companies
appealed to Congress to pass SIRA, legislation that would have created a new collective
licensing system under section 115 for the digital use of musical works. While SIRA was
more limited in scope than what would seem to be called for today, it nonetheless
featured some concepts that the Office believes could help to inform a more general
overhaul of our licensing system.
iHeartMedia has entered into licensing agreements with WMG and some independent labels for
deals covering both terrestrial and internet radio. Christman, Here’s Why Warner Music’s Deal
with Clear Channel Could be Groundbreaking for the Future of the U.S. Music Biz (Analysis). Pandora
recently struck a direct deal with Merlin, an entity that negotiates on behalf of independent
record labels; under this arrangement, though, Pandora agreed to continue to pay artist royalties
through SoundExchange. Glenn Peoples, Pandora Signs First Direct Label Deal with Merlin,
B
ILLBOARD (Aug. 6, 2014), http://www.billboard.com/articles/business/6207058/pandora-label-
deal-merlin.
941
See NMPA Late Fee Program, NMPA LATE FEE SETTLEMENT.COM, http://www.
nmpalatefeesettlement.com/index (last visited Jan. 22, 2015) (explaining the terms of the MOU in
which record labels and music publishers (represented by RIAA and NMPA/HFA respectively)
agreed to improve mechanical licensing practices and encourage prompt resolution of disputes);
see also Memorandum of Understanding (MOU 2), NMPA
LATE FEE SETTLEMENT.COM,
http://www.nmpalatefeesettlement.com/docs/mou2.pdf (last visited Jan. 22, 2015) (in which the
record labels and music publishers extended the 2009 MOU through 2017).
189
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
First, SIRA recognized that it could be appropriate to allow more than one entity
(referred to as a “designated agent”) to administer licenses, so long as each such entity
represented at least a certain prescribed share of the publishing market. Second, SIRA
would have offered licensees the opportunity to obtain licenses on a blanket, rather than
song-by-song, basis by serving notice on the designated agents. Third, SIRA recognized
that one such agent (the “general designated agent”) should serve as a default licensing
entity for publishers that had not selected a different agent. And finally, SIRA provided
for each designated agent to maintain a database listing ownership information for the
musical works it administers.
942
While there was disagreement about the details of
SIRA, these basic organizing principles were appealing to many.
943
The Office’s
proposal for an updated licensing framework also draws upon these concepts.
But even though SIRA may represent a good starting point, it is only that. As digital
models have proliferated, the drawbacks of our current system have become more
pronounced. The intervening decade has produced a greater sense of urgency
concerning the strains on the current system.
Stakeholders focus in particular on the lack of reliable licensing data, which leads to
inefficiencies and failures in the licensing process. The Office agrees with commenting
parties that much of what is ailing our system would be greatly ameliorated if all those
who needed it had access to authoritative data concerning the ownership of musical
works and sound recordings. In addition, because digital services typically receive only
track-based information for sound recordings that is not tied to the underlying musical
work, there needs to be an efficient mechanism for licensees to associate the sound
recordings they use with the musical works they embody.
1. MROs
Under the Office’s proposal, except to the extent they chose to opt out of the blanket
statutory system, publishers and songwriters would license their public performance
and mechanical rights through their MROs.
944
As explained above, an MRO would have
942
SIRA, H.R. 5553.
943
See HFA, Legislative News: Section 115 Reform Act of 2006 (SIRA) Introduced, SOUNDCHECK, June
2006, at 1, available at https://secure.harryfox.com/public/userfiles/file/Soundcheck/
viewSoundCheck606.pdf (“While [DiMA, the NMPA, and the RIAA] have not reached complete
agreement on all aspects of this legislation, we are optimistic that in the coming weeks we will
work together with Chairman Smith and Representative Berman to ultimately pass historic
legislation that will promote greater innovation and competition among digital music providers,
deliver fair compensation to music creators and most importantly, greatly expand music choice
and enjoyment for music fans.”).
944
Regardless of opt-out status, however, just as is the case today, a willing publisher could agree
to a voluntary license with a willing licensee outside of the statutory regime. But in order to
require the licensee to negotiate outside of the statutory process, the publisher would need to
190
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
the ability to administer, and bundle, performance and mechanical rights on behalf of
the publishers and songwriters it represented. It would also collect and distribute the
royalties due under such licenses.
945
An MRO could be any entity representing the musical works of publishers and
songwriters with a market share in the mechanical and/or performance market above a
certain minimum threshold, for example, 5%. Existing rights organizations, such as
ASCAP, BMI, HFA and others, could thus qualify as MROs. Each MRO would enjoy an
antitrust exemption to negotiate performance and mechanical licenses collectively on
behalf of its members—as would licensee groups negotiating with the MROswith the
CRB available to establish a rate in case of a dispute.
946
But MROs could not coordinate
with one another and, as discussed above, would be subject to at least routine antitrust
oversight to guard against anticompetitive behavior. They would also be subject to
potential CRB ratesetting for all uses of their members’ works except for those that had
been withdrawn.
Each MRO would be required to supply a complete list of the publishers, works,
percentage shares and rights it represented, as well as the MRO’s licensing contact
information, to the GMRO, and would be obligated to keep that information current.
The requirement to identify the titles and writers of represented works essentially tracks
what is required today under the ASCAP consent decree and has long been voluntarily
provided by the PROs and HFA through their public “lookup” databases.
947
The critical
assert its opt-out right. Additionally, to effectuate such a voluntary arrangement, the publisher
would need to notify the MRO of the agreement, so that the MRO could make appropriate
adjustments to its collection and distribution processes.
945
Under the new MRO-based system, record labels would no longer engage in “pass-though”
licensing of musical works as they are entitled to do today under section 115. Third-party
services would instead seek blanket licenses from the MROs, or directly from any publishers who
had opted out. Apart from long-time concerns by publishers and songwriters about their
inability to receive direct payment from digital services under the pass-through regime, the
possibility of varying rates under the updated licensing framework being proposed would
seemingly render pass-through licensing inefficient at best. In their comments, record labels
indicated a willingness to eliminate this aspect of section 115. See RIAA Second Notice
Comments at 19 (“The major record companies generally support in principle the elimination of
pass-through licensing.”).
946
The section 112, 114, and 115 licenses contain antitrust exemptions to allow copyright owners
and users to negotiate collectively, and the PROs are permitted to do so under the consent
decrees. See 17 U.S.C. §§ 112(e)(2), 114(e)(1), 115(c)(3)(B).
947
See ASCAP Consent Decree § X; Ace Title Search, ASCAP, https://www.ascap.com/Home/ace-
title-search/index.aspx (last visited Jan. 29, 2015); BMI Repertoire, BMI, http://repertoire.bmi.com/
startpage.asp (last visited Jan. 29, 2015); HFA, Songfile Search, S
ONGFILE, https://secure.harryfox.
com/songfile/public/publicsearch.jsp (last visited Jan. 16, 2015).
191
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
difference is that the publicly accessible data would be available in a more sophisticated
database format that would facilitate automated matching functions, bulk licensing
processes, and reconciliation of third-party databases.
MROs would also be responsible for notifying the GMRO of any members that had
exercised opt-out rights by providing the relevant opt-out information, including where
a direct license might be sought, for the central database so potential licensees would
know where to go for license authority. Additionally, under requirements that would be
phased in over time, MROs would need to supply the ISWC—and over time, the ISNI
identifiers for each of the works they represented. As everyone appears to agree, the
move to unique identifiers as a primary means to recognize both musical works and
sound recordings is essential to an efficient licensing system.
But MROs would not have to share all of their data for purposes of the public database.
For example, there would be no need for an MRO to provide contact information for its
members (other than those that opted out) since the MRO would be responsible for
distributing royalties under the licenses it issued. Details about contractual
arrangements between publishers and their songwriters that the MROs might need for
their own distribution purposes would seem to be unnecessary to provide for public
use. Under the Office’s approach, MROs would only be required to furnish such
information as would be necessary to facilitate accurate licensing transactions and usage
reporting in a system of multiple MROs. As suggested below, the specific data to be
supplied could be subject to regulatory oversight and adjusted over time.
2. The GMRO
Even though the preponderance of licensing activity would be carried out by the MROs
and directly licensing publishers, the hub of the new licensing structure would be the
GMRO. Similar to SoundExchange, the GMRO (“SongExchange”?) would be a non-
profit entity designated, and regulated, by the government.
948
The GMRO would be
overseen by a board that included representatives from both the music publishing and
songwriter communities.
By virtue of maintaining authoritative and accessible ownership data, the GMRO would
help to coordinate licensing and royalty payments across the MROs and individual
publishers. But it would not serve as a centralized collection facility other than with
respect to unidentified royalty recipients. The Office believes that adding an additional
administrative layer to core royalty collection and distribution functions would add time
948
SoundExchange is regulated by the CRB as the designated collective. See, e.g., 37 C.F.R. §§
380.2(c), 380.4.
192
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
and expense to these processes and should be avoided if possible.
949
At the same time,
the GMRO would serve as the recipient for payments on behalf of unidentified owners.
Data-Related Responsibilities a.
The GMRO would ingest data from MROs and other authoritative sources to create its
master database. The GMRO database would list the publishers, musical works,
percentage shares and rights represented by the various MROs, along with prescribed
identifiers such as ISWCs and ISNIs. In addition, the database would flag opt-out
publishers, the specific rights and works that were opted out, and provide the
publishers’ licensing contact information.
In addition to musical work data, it seems that the GMRO could and should also
incorporate sound recording data into the public database, including track titles, record
labels, featured artists, play times and ISRCs. It is the Office’s understanding that
SoundExchange currently has identification and ownership informationincluding
ISRCsfor approximately 14 million sound recordings.
950
The GMRO could absorb this
data from SoundExchange. Through SoundExchange’s continuing administration of the
section 112 and 114 licenses, an ISRC requirement for remaining tracks—as well as the
ISNI standard—could be phased in under those licenses, with the ongoing results to be
shared with the GMRO.
951
Like SoundExchange, the GMRO would play an active role in gathering missing data,
reconciling conflicting data, and correcting flawed data. It would need to establish a
process to handle competing ownership claims as necessary.
But perhaps most important among the data-related responsibilities of the GMRO
would be to gather or generate “matches” of musical works with sound recordings.
There is simply no easy means for licensees to acquire generalized data identifying the
musical works embodied in individual sound recordings. Some private entities such as
HFA have made substantial progress on this front through a combination of automated
and manual matching protocols, but there is no comprehensive source for this
information, and even HFA has yet to match millions of titles.
952
949
SIRA took a similar approach by providing for direct payment to the individual designated
agents. SIRA, H.R. 5553.
950
SoundExchange Second Notice Comments at 4-5.
951
SoundExchange is currently exploring making its data available to others. See id. at 5
(“SoundExchange is actively exploring means by which it might provide interested services a
means of accessing [its sound recording] data for use in identifying to SoundExchange with
greater precision the recordings they use under the statutory licenses.”).
952
Tr. at 217:02-218:16 (June 23, 2014) (Christos P. Badavas, HFA).
193
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
A matching database would represent a huge advance in music licensing, as it would
enable digital services efficiently to identify musical works and their owners based on
the tracks they are using. Undoubtedly it is a significant undertaking, but given an
appropriate level of resources it would seem to be achievable, at least with respect to the
most frequently used songs. As HFA reports, 1-2 million sound recordings account for
almost 95% of usage in a typical digital music service.
953
Happily (and not surprisingly),
it is the most commercially valuable sound recordings and musical works that tend to be
the easiest to identify and associate with one another.
On the licensee side of the equation, whenever an ISWC, ISRC or ISNI (or other
prescribed identifier) appeared in the database, it would be a required element in a
licensee’s report under a section 114 or 115 license. The consistent use of these standards
would undoubtedly facilitate the GMRO’s efforts to match musical works to sound
recordings and distribute royalties to their owners.
Finally, as noted above, the song data and licensing information collected by the GMRO
would be publicly accessiblenot only in the form of individual records through a
“lookup”-style database, but also in bulk form and/or via APIs that would allow
licensees the ability to use it to update their records or perform matching or other
functions relating to their licensing needs.
Default Licensing and Payment b.
Notwithstanding the GMRO database and other available resources, there would still be
works (and shares of works) for which the owners were not identified.
954
The GMRO
would therefore also serve as the default licensing and collection agent for musical
works (or shares of works) that licensees were unable to associate with an MRO or opt-
out publisher. Services relying on blanket performance and/or mechanical licenses for
musical works that had usage-based payment obligations would transmit records of use
for unmatched works, along with associated payments, to the GMRO.
955
The GMRO
953
NMPA & HFA First Notice Comments at 13.
954
This is a particular concern with respect to new releases, as publisher and songwriter
disagreements over their respective ownership shares in songs often delay the finalization of
mechanical licenses for months or even years after the record is released. Tr. at 340:05-341:14
(June 23, 2014) (Andrea Finkelstein, SME).
955
Since royalty obligations might vary among MROs and publishers, the default payments
would need to be made in an amount sufficient to cover the highest potential rate payable to any
entity with which the licensee had a licensing arrangement. In some cases, a blanket license
might require payment of a set amount for the reporting period in question regardless of usage
(for example, a fixed percentage of the service’s revenues, as in the case of ASCAP’s license with
Pandora), with the royalty pool to be allocated by the collecting agent. In such a case, there
would be no need to pay into the GMRO, and any reporting issues would need to be addressed
by the MRO.
194
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
would then attempt to identify the MRO or individual rightsowner itself and, if
successful, pay the royalties out.
956
If unsuccessful in its research efforts, the GMRO
would add the usage record to a public unclaimed royalties list and hold the funds for
some period of timee.g., three years—to see if a claimant came forward. As is the case
with SoundExchange, after that period, the GMRO could use any remaining unclaimed
funds to help offset the costs of its operations. Such a default licensing and payment
option would provide protection for licenseesby reporting unmatched works and
paying the associated royalties to the GMRO, they could avoid liability for infringement
for those uses.
But any such system would require appropriate incentives to ensure that both licensees
and publishers were holding up their respective ends of the bargain. Setting aside any
general funding obligations in relation to the GMRO, which are discussed below, the
Office believes that licensees should be required to pay an administrative fee (perhaps
assessed on a per-title basis) for any unmatched uses reported to the GMRO.
957
In
addition to encouraging due diligence on the part of licensees to locate missing
information before resorting to the default system, such fees would help underwrite the
GMRO’s efforts to locate and pay rightsholders.
At the same time, MROs and their members should also be encouraged to maintain
complete and reliable data with the GMRO. The primary incentive to do so, of course,
would be to facilitate prompt and accurate payments by licensees. In this regard, the
Office believes it could be useful to establish phased-in compliance targets over a period
of several years for the provision of the most critical publisher data, including missing
ISWCs, to the GMRO.
958
If, after an appropriate review of the situation and an
956
Any difference between the royalties paid to the GMRO and the actual rate of a subsequently
identified publisher could be contributed to the GMRO to offset costs. In the case of a publisher
not affiliated with an MRO and hence not subject to any rate agreement, the publisher should
receive the lowest potential rate that the licensee might pay for that use and the GMRO could also
deduct a reasonable administrative fee not greater than any fee currently charged by any of the
MROs. This latter rule would incentivize publishers to affiliate with an MRO of their choice
rather than rely on the much less efficient GMRO claims procedure.
957
A somewhat analogous fee is currently required for the filing of an NOI with the Office under
section 115 in lieu of serving it on a licensee when the licensee cannot be found in the Office’s
records (though no royalty payment is required). See 37 C.F.R. § 201.3(e)(1). As noted above,
large-scale licensees appear to be reluctant to avail themselves of this process due to the filing
fees (which reflect the costs incurred by the Office in administering these notices, as per 17 U.S.C.
§ 708(a)). The level of the administrative fee that would be assessed by the GMROwhich
would receive more general funding from users, as discussed belowwould need to be carefully
assessed in relation to its purpose.
958
By way of illustration, in year one, 20% of works listed by an MRO might be required to
include the ISWC; in year two, 40%; and so on up to near-total compliance.
195
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
opportunity to rectify concerns, an MRO were found to fall short of the mark, any
licensee required to pay the GMRO’s administrative fee for unmatched works to that
MRO would be entitled to recoup some portion of that fee (say half) from its royalty
payments to that MRO pending correction of the problem.
Resources and Funding c.
A question that will inevitably arise in any discussion concerning an overhaul of our
music licensing system is how the new system—more specifically, the startup costs and
various activities of the GMRO—would be funded. The Office has some suggestions to
offer on this point.
First, the Copyright Office believes that both copyright owners and users should bear
the costs of the new system, as both groups will share in its benefits. Traditionally,
publishers and songwriters have underwritten much of the cost of licensing
performance and mechanical rights and distributing royalties through commissions paid
to the PROs and HFA. But record labels and digital services have also borne significant
administrative costs in gathering and compiling the data necessary to obtain and report
under licenses.
As envisioned by the Office, the GMRO would build and maintain a public database of
ownership and licensing information for musical works and sound recordings. As part
of this obligation, it would be responsible for matching sound recording data to musical
works. The GMRO would also be responsible for collecting and distributing royalties
for unclaimed works. These are substantial undertakings. Some licensees have
expressed willingness to help fund a more workable system.
959
The Office believes that
publishers and songwriters will also need to contribute, although much of their
contribution might be in the form of shared data.
As explained above, under the Office’s proposal, every MRO, as well as SoundExchange,
will be required to contribute key elements of data to create and maintain a centralized
music database. MROs will be responsible for allocating and distributing the vast
majority of royalties (and will charge commissions to publishers and songwriters for
those services). In exchange for these contributions on the part of copyright owners, the
Office believes that the primary financial support for the data-related and default
licensing activities of the GMRO should come from fees charged to users of the section
112, 114, and 115 licenses.
959
See, e.g., DiMA Second Notice Comments at 5 (suggesting that the government “designate a
small portion of license fees” paid by licensees to cover costs); RIAA First Notice Comments at 22
(“Record companies are prepared to contribute information concerning new works, and
potentially a share of start-up costs.”).
196
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Although music users would be paying royalties directly to MROs and individual
publishersand to SoundExchange as well—they would have a separate obligation to
pay a licensing surcharge to the GMRO in recognition of the value it would be providing
to the licensee community. The licensing surcharge might, for example, be assessed as a
small percentage of royalties due from the licensee under its section 112, 114, and/or 115
statutory licenses, including any direct deals for equivalent rights. In order to fund
startup costs, licensees could perhaps contribute a lump sum against future surcharge
assessments, to be recouped over time.
The surcharge to be paid by statutory licensees could be determined by the CRB through
a periodic administrative process based on the GMRO’s costs, and would be offset by
other sources of funding. For example, in addition to the generally applicable
surcharge, as explained above, the Office believes that individual licensees should be
charged an administrative fee in connection with reporting and paying unattributed
uses to the GMRO.
960
Publishers not affiliated with an MRO who claimed works from
the unmatched list would also be expected to pay a processing fee, as they would at an
MRO. Nonstatutory licensees could be required to pay the GMRO’s reasonable costs for
the bulk provision of data. Such fees—which would help to offset the costs of the
GMROcould be considered by the CRB in establishing the surcharge.
An additional source of funding would be any royalties that remained unclaimed by
publishers after the prescribed holding period (perhaps three years). Such unattributed
moniesor “black box” funds—would also be available to offset the GMRO’s
administrative costs. As with the GMRO’s other sources of income, these funds, too,
could be considered by the CRB in establishing the licensing surcharge.
961
3. The CRB
New Ratesetting Protocol a.
Under the Office’s proposal, ratesetting by the CRB would shift from a five-year cycle to
a system under which the CRB would step in only as necessary—that is, only when an
MRO or SoundExchange and licensee could not agree on a rate.
The unfortunate reality is that the costs of ratesetting are very high, whether the
proceeding occurs in federal court or before an administrative tribunal. The Office
believes that the current approach under the section 112, 114, and 115 licensesunder
which rates are required to be established for the full spectrum of uses for the upcoming
five years—is probably not the most efficient use of resources. Such an approach
960
As noted above, an MRO that failed to contribute adequate data to the GMRO could be
required to absorb some portion of such administrative fees.
961
If the black box funds were ever to exceed the GMRO’s costs, the excess could be distributed to
publishers by the GMRO based on a market-share-based allocation process.
197
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
presents the nontrivial problem of how to identify, evaluate and price still-nascent
business models. Even if they are identified, some of these uses might be easily settled
outside of the context of a CRB proceeding. In the case of existing models, the extant
rates may be sufficiently satisfactory for both sides to continue in effect. Greater
flexibility in the ratesetting process would allow the ratesetting body to address only
those rates that were worthwhile to litigate.
In support of its proposal, the Office observes that ASCAP and BMI have operated
under such an ad hoc system in the federal rate courts, with only a relatively small
number of their rates actually litigated. A likeminded CRB approach could yield more
voluntary agreements and less litigation. Further, licensees would no longer have to
shoehorn themselves into an existing rate category to take advantage of statutory
licensing, because MRO licenses could be specifically tailored to address the nuances of
the business model at hand.
Last but not least, it is difficult to see how an integrated licensing framework such as
that proposed by the Office could function under two different ratesetting paradigms, as
exist in their separate worlds today. In order to bundle performance and mechanical
licensingor, as discussed below, sound recording and musical work rightsin an
efficient manner, there should be a unified ratesetting process. The CRB would face
enormous administrative challenges if it had to administer both periodic and ad hoc
ratesetting proceedings simultaneously.
962
All-In Rates for Noninteractive Streaming b.
During the study, various commenting parties floated the suggestion of all-in blanket
licensing that would encompass both sound recording and musical work rights.
963
Our
current framework presents seemingly insuperable hurdles to achieving what many
view as a tantalizing goal. Even under the framework proposed by the Officewhich
notwithstanding publisher opt-out rights still contemplates ratesetting for musical
works that has no equivalent on the sound recording sideit would be difficult to
implement all-in rates on a broad basis.
962
In this regard, Congress might also wish to amend the statutory framework for the CRB to
allow for greater flexibility in staffing. Currently, the statute is highly specific, in that it provides
for three full-time staff members: one to be paid no more than the basic rate for level 10 of GS-15
of the General Schedule; one to be paid between the basic rate for GS-13 and level 10 of GS-14;
and one to be paid between the basic rate for GS-8 and level 10 of GS-11. 17 U.S.C. § 802(b), (e)(2).
Especially if its duties were expanded to include additional licensing activities and fee-setting
responsibilities, the CRB would seemingly be better served with a statute that provided more
discretion with respect to the number and seniority of the legal staff that assist the three Judges.
963
See, e.g., RIAA First Notice Comments at 14-17 (proposing a blanket licensing solution for all
rights implicated when using musical works); Tr. at 194:05-18 (June 4, 2014) (Scott Sellwood,
Google/YouTube) (“I certainly like the idea of an all-in valuation of the music copyright.”).
198
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
In one area, however—the licensing of noninteractive streaming uses by internet
services, satellite and terrestrial radio, and others—such a model might be achievable.
Here the Office has suggested that government supervision of the public performance
right be moved from the federal rate courts to the CRB. Accordingly, both sound
recording owners and musical work owners would be subject to CRB ratesetting to the
extent they were unable to negotiate agreements with digital providers. The Office
believes that any such proceedings could potentially be combined.
Taking the suggestion of the RIAA, for example, record labels and music publishers
could agree up front to a split of royalties as between them for the category of use to be
litigated.
964
They could then participate jointly in the ratesetting proceeding vis-à-vis the
licensee. The licensee’s focus before the CRB would thus be on its total royalty
obligation, rather than the particular amounts to be paid to labels or publishers. Even
barring an up-front agreement between the labels and publishers, ratesetting for the
service in question might still proceed on an all-in basis, with the CRB to establish the
split between sound recordings and musical works in a separate phase of the proceeding
that did not include the licensee.
GMRO Surcharge c.
As noted above, under the Office’s proposal, the GMRO would be funded in part by a
licensing surcharge to be paid directly by licensees to the GMRO. The Office believes
that the CRB, with its in-house economic expertise, would be well equipped to
determine the surcharge through a periodic review process. That process would be
conducted separate and apart from any ratesetting activities. Indeed, an important
element of such a proceeding would be to preclude any consideration of royalty rates in
establishing the licensing surcharge (and vice versa). The surcharge would be set
independently, based on licensee data and the GMRO’s costs and capital needs.
965
Procedural Improvements d.
In addition to the substance of the CRB’s ratesetting determinations, a number of
seasoned stakeholders addressed the procedural rules that currently govern the CRB’s
work. The CRB is constrained by procedural mandates set forth in section 803 of the
Copyright Act, which govern the initiation and conduct of ratesetting proceedings,
including such matters as filing rules for participants, the timing and content of direct
cases, the handling of various evidentiary and discovery matters, and settlement
964
RIAA First Notice Comments at 15-17. Any such agreement concerning the royalty split
would presumably need to address the parties’ obligations to each other in relation to a
settlement rather than a litigated outcome.
965
As it does in CRB proceedings today, in considering appropriate fees, the CRB could impose
safeguards to protect against public dissemination of confidential business information.
199
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
negotiations.
966
This sort of procedural detail is unusual in a federal statutory scheme
and is more typically left to regulation or the discretion of the tribunal.
Stakeholders complain that the current CRB system is unduly burdensome and
expensive. Currently, ratesetting participants are required to put in their written direct
statement before they conduct discovery—that is, they are required to construct and
support their rate proposals to the CRB without the benefit of economic information
from the other side.
967
This is completely counterintuitive to anyone familiar with
ordinary litigation practice.
In keeping with this construct, ratesetting proceedings are divided into separate direct
and rebuttal phases, with discovery conducted in the first phase and potentially in the
rebuttal phase as well.
968
Parties may seek to amend their rate proposals in response to
what they learn in discovery.
969
In practical effect, this means there are two trial
proceedings, with overlapping arguments and evidence, instead of one. As might be
expected, stakeholders would prefer to have the issues for trial fully joined and
addressed in single proceeding. The Office is sympathetic to these concerns and
believes the CRB process should be modified so it more closely resembles typical
litigation. As has been suggested by some, this could include greater reliance on the
Federal Rules of Civil Procedure and Federal Rules of Evidence, albeit with appropriate
modifications (such as relaxation of hearsay rules).
970
Multifactor ratesetting standards also contribute to the length and expense of
proceedings, as parties feel compelled to furnish evidence and argument on each
statutorily prescribed factor. A move to a simpler standard such as willing
buyer/willing sellerperhaps unembellished by specific considerations (in contrast to
the standard as currently embodied in section 114
971
)—might also help to streamline the
ratesetting process by permitting each side to focus on the most salient aspects of their
case.
Many CRB participants complained that the existing process does not facilitate early
settlement. In order for a settlement to be the basis for an industrywide rate, it must be
adopted by the CRB.
972
The CRB does not appear always to be comfortable in adopting
settlement agreements that settle less than the entire proceedingfor example, a
settlement among fewer than all participantswhile the rest of the proceeding remains
966
See generally 17 U.S.C. § 803.
967
Id. § 803(b)(6)(C)(ii).
968
Id. § 803(b)(6)(C)(i)-(ii), (iv).
969
Id. § 803(b)(6)(C)(i).
970
See id. § 803(b)(6)(C)(iii) (allowing hearsay to be admitted upon CRB discretion).
971
Id. § 114(f)(2)(B).
972
Id. § 801(b)(7).
200
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
pending.
973
And the record shows that participants feel obligated to continue litigating
until a settlement is adopted.
974
This is not an efficient system. The Office agrees that
this should be rectified by clarifying the statutory provisions governing the CRB to favor
partial settlements at any stage of the proceeding when requested by the settling
participants.
975
Finally, while the Office believes that the high-level procedural concerns described
should be addressed by legislative amendments, Congress may also wish to remove
unnecessary procedural details in the statute that are better left to regulation. The CRB
should have the latitude to develop specific procedural rules—and modify them as
appropriate—within the basic parameters set forth in the statute.
4. Regulatory Implementation
Should Congress decide to restructure the music licensing system, the Office believes
that it might be most productive for any resulting legislation to set out the essential
elements of the updated system and leave the particulars to regulation. Such a construct
would likely be more realistic to enact than an exhaustive statutory prescription
especially in the case of music licensing, where the particulars can be overwhelming. In
addition to whatever legislative advantages it might confer, a more general approach
would have added benefit of flexibility, since regulations can be adjusted over time to
address new developments and unforeseen contingencies.
973
The CRB has occasionally adopted settlements resolving some but not all rate concerns. See,
e.g., Adjustment of Rates and Terms for Preexisting Subscription and Satellite Digital Audio Radio
Services, 72 Fed. Reg. 71,795 (Dec. 19, 2007); Determination of Rates and Terms for Preexisting
Subscription Services and Satellite Digital Audio Radio Services, 73 Fed. Reg. 4080. But adoption
of partial settlements is not the norm.
974
See, e.g., Tr. at 122:15-22 (June 23, 2014) (Colin Rushing, SoundExchange) (“But it was this
group, College Webcasters, Inc. We entered into a settlement with them. We also did a
settlement with NAB. Neither of these settlements were actually adopted by the CRB until the
very end of the proceeding. And so we found ourselves unsure of what, you know, whether the
settlements were, actually, going to be adopted.”); Tr. at 99:16-100:03 (June 16, 2014) (Brad
Prendergast, SoundExchange) (The current system “leaves a lot of parties still in the litigation
proceeding, when they’d rather not be.”); Tr. at 129:17-130:03 (June 23, 2014) (Steven Marks,
RIAA) (“I also think that the CRB, it would be nice to have, maybe, some set times for the CRB to
rule on settlements that are proposed. We had, our last mechanical settlement that was offered, a
delay of almost a year.”).
975
Notably, this problem would also likely be ameliorated by a move to an “as-needed”
ratesetting system as recommended by the Office, where rate determinations would bind only
the participants to the proceeding (notwithstanding their potential influence on other market
actors). Such proceedings would focus on narrower disputes and should therefore be easier to
resolve than proceedings covering a multitude of rates and stakeholders.
201
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Logically, the Copyright Office should have primary regulatory responsibility for the
many issues that would need to be addressed in implementing a new statutory
framework. For example, the Office could establish rules for the provision of data to the
GMRO, licensee reporting requirements, and collective audits. It could also promulgate
technical requirements for the statutory licenses, with the power to update such
specifications as necessary.
The CRB, too, would have regulatory responsibilities. In addition to its periodic review
of the surcharge to be assessed by the GMRO, the CRB would enact rules that would
govern the filing and conduct of the ratesetting proceedings it would oversee. Like the
Copyright Office, the CRB should have the requisite regulatory authority to carry out its
responsibilities.
5. Further Evaluation
Should Congress choose to embark upon a series of changes to our licensing system
such as those described above, the Office recommends that the new system be evaluated
by the Copyright Office after it has been in operation for a period of several years.
Assuming that the new licensing framework includes an opt-out mechanism as
described above, the efficacy of that process would be of particular interest. If the opt-
out system were found to be having adverse effects on the marketplace, Congress could
consider narrowing those rights. If, on the other hand, the opt-out option were working
well, Congress might wish to expand it to other categories.
202
c o p y r i g h t a n d t h e m u s i c m a r k e t p l a c e
appendix a federal register notices
u
. s . c o p y r i g h t o f f i c e
VerDate Mar<15>2010 18:45 Mar 14, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00082 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\17MRN1.SGM 17MRN1
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
14739
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 51 / Monday, March 17, 2014 / Notices
search_cfm under the searchable listing
of determinations or by calling the
Office of Trade Adjustment Assistance
toll free at 888–365–6822.
Signed at Washington DC, this 20th day of
February 2014.
Hope D. Kinglock,
Certifying Officer, Office of Trade Adjustment
Assistance.
[FR Doc. 2014–05760 Filed 3–14–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4510–FN–P
DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
Employment and Training
Administration
Investigations Regarding Eligibility To
Apply For Worker Adjustment
Assistance
Petitions have been filed with the
Secretary of Labor under Section 221(a)
of the Trade Act of 1974 (‘‘the Act’’) and
are identified in the Appendix to this
notice. Upon receipt of these petitions,
the Director of the Office of Trade
Adjustment Assistance, Employment
and Training Administration, has
instituted investigations pursuant to
Section 221(a) of the Act.
The purpose of each of the
investigations is to determine whether
the workers are eligible to apply for
adjustment assistance under Title II,
Chapter 2, of the Act. The investigations
will further relate, as appropriate, to the
determination of the date on which total
or partial separations began or
threatened to begin and the subdivision
of the firm involved.
The petitioners or any other persons
showing a substantial interest in the
subject matter of the investigations may
request a public hearing, provided such
request is filed in writing with the
Director, Office of Trade Adjustment
Assistance, at the address shown below,
not later than March 27, 2014.
Interested persons are invited to
submit written comments regarding the
subject matter of the investigations to
the Director, Office of Trade Adjustment
Assistance, at the address shown below,
not later than March 27, 2014.
The petitions filed in this case are
available for inspection at the Office of
the Director, Office of Trade Adjustment
Assistance, Employment and Training
Administration, U.S. Department of
Labor, Room N–5428, 200 Constitution
Avenue NW., Washington, DC 20210.
Signed at Washington, DC, this 20th day of
February 2014.
Hope D. Kinglock,
Certifying Officer, Office of Trade Adjustment
Assistance.
Appendix—13 TAA Petitions Instituted
Between 2/10/14 and 2/14/14
TA–W Subject firm (petitioners) Location
Date of
institution
Date of
petition
85059 ................ Avery Dennison (Company) ................................................. Clinton, SC ............................ 02/10/14 02/10/14
85060 ................ Fresenius Medical Care NA (Workers) ................................ Livingston, CA ....................... 02/11/14 02/10/14
85061 ................ IBM (State/One-Stop) ........................................................... San Jose, CA ........................ 02/11/14 02/10/14
85062 ................ Computer Sciences Corporation (State/One-Stop) .............. Oakland, CA .......................... 02/11/14 02/10/14
85063 ................ EPIC Technologies, LLC (Company) ................................... El Paso, TX ........................... 02/11/14 02/10/14
85064 ................ Southside Manufacturing (Workers) ..................................... Blairs, VA .............................. 02/11/14 02/04/14
85065 ................ Woodcraft Industries (Company) .......................................... Belletonte, PA ....................... 02/12/14 02/10/14
85066 ................ Sun Edison (previously MEMC) (State/One-Stop) ............... St. Peters, MO ...................... 02/12/14 02/12/14
85067 ................ FLSmidth Spokane Inc (Workers) ........................................ Meridian, ID ........................... 02/12/14 02/11/14
85068 ................ GE Hitachi Nuclear Energy (Company) ............................... Canonsburg, PA .................... 02/12/14 02/11/14
85069 ................ Allstate Insurance Company (Workers) ............................... Roanoke, VA ......................... 02/12/14 01/28/14
85070 ................ Time Machine, Inc. (Company) ............................................ Polk, PA ................................ 02/14/14 02/12/14
85071 ................ General Electric (GE) (Union) .............................................. Ft. Edward, NY ..................... 02/14/14 02/04/14
[FR Doc. 2014–05758 Filed 3–14–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4510–FN–P
LIBRARY OF CONGRESS
Copyright Office
[Docket No. 2014–03]
Music Licensing Study: Notice and
Request for Public Comment
AGENCY
: Copyright Office, Library of
Congress.
ACTION
: Notice of Inquiry.
SUMMARY
: The United States Copyright
Office announces the initiation of a
study to evaluate the effectiveness of
existing methods of licensing music. To
aid this effort, the Office is seeking
public input on this topic. The Office
will use the information it gathers to
report to Congress. Congress is currently
conducting a review of the U.S.
Copyright Act, 17 U.S.C. 101 et seq., to
evaluate potential revisions of the law
in light of technological and other
developments that impact the creation,
dissemination, and use of copyrighted
works.
DATES
: Written comments are due on or
before May 16, 2014. The Office will be
announcing one or more public
meetings to address music licensing
issues, to take place after written
comments are received, by separate
notice in the future.
ADDRESSES
: All comments shall be
submitted electronically. A comment
page containing a comment form is
posted on the Office Web site at
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/
musiclicensingstudy. The Web site
interface requires commenting parties to
complete a form specifying their name
and organization, as applicable, and to
upload comments as an attachment via
a browser button. To meet accessibility
standards, commenting parties must
upload comments in a single file not to
exceed six megabytes (MB) in one of the
following formats: The Portable
Document File (PDF) format that
contains searchable, accessible text (not
an image); Microsoft Word;
WordPerfect; Rich Text Format (RTF); or
ASCII text file format (not a scanned
document). The form and face of the
comments must include both the name
of the submitter and organization. The
Office will post the comments publicly
on the Office’s Web site in the form that
they are received, along with associated
names and organizations. If electronic
submission of comments is not feasible,
please contact the Office at 202–707–
8350 for special instructions.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT
:
Jacqueline C. Charlesworth, General
Counsel and Associate Register of
Copyrights, by email at jcharlesworth@
loc.gov or by telephone at 202–707–
8350; or Sarang V. Damle, Special
Advisor to the General Counsel, by
email at [email protected] or by telephone
at 202–707–8350.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
:
VerDate Mar<15>2010 18:45 Mar 14, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00083 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\17MRN1.SGM 17MRN1
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
14740
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 51 / Monday, March 17, 2014 / Notices
I. Background
Congress is currently engaged in a
comprehensive review of the U.S.
Copyright Act, 17 U.S.C. 101 et seq., to
evaluate potential revisions to the law
in light of technological and other
developments that impact the creation,
dissemination, and use of copyrighted
works. The last general revision of the
Copyright Act took place in 1976
(‘‘Copyright Act’’ or ‘‘Act’’) following a
lengthy and comprehensive review
process carried out by Congress, the
Copyright Office, and interested parties.
In 1998, Congress significantly amended
the Act with the passage of the Digital
Millennium Copyright Act (‘‘DMCA’’) to
address emerging issues of the digital
age. Public Law 105–304, 112 Stat. 2860
(1998). While the Copyright Act reflects
many sound and enduring principles,
and has enabled the internet to flourish,
Congress could not have foreseen all of
today’s technologies and the myriad
ways consumers and others engage with
creative works in the digital
environment. Perhaps nowhere has the
landscape been as significantly altered
as in the realm of music.
Music is more available now than it
has ever been. Today, music is delivered
to consumers not only in physical
formats, such as compact discs and
vinyl records, but is available on
demand, both by download and
streaming, as well as through
smartphones, computers, and other
devices. At the same time, the public
continues to consume music through
terrestrial and satellite radio, and more
recently, internet-based radio. Music
continues to enhance films, television,
and advertising, and is a key component
of many apps and video games.
Such uses of music require licenses
from copyright owners. The
mechanisms for obtaining such licenses
are largely shaped by our copyright law,
including the statutory licenses under
Sections 112, 114, and 115 of the
Copyright Act, which provide
government-regulated licensing regimes
for certain uses of sound recordings and
musical works.
A musical recording encompasses two
distinct works of authorship: The
musical work, which is the underlying
composition created by the songwriter
or composer, along with any
accompanying lyrics; and the sound
recording, that is, the particular
performance of the musical work that
has been fixed in a recording medium
such as CD or digital file. The methods
for obtaining licenses differ with respect
to these two types of works, which can
be—and frequently are—owned or
managed by different entities.
Songwriters and composers often assign
rights in their musical works to music
publishers and, in addition, affiliate
themselves with performing rights
organizations (‘‘PROs’’). These
intermediaries, in turn, assume
responsibility for licensing the works.
By contrast, the licensing of sound
recordings is typically handled directly
by record labels, except in the case of
certain types of digital uses, as
described below.
Musical Works—Reproduction and
Distribution. Under the Copyright Act,
the owner of a musical work has the
exclusive right to make and distribute
phonorecords of the work (i.e., copies in
which the work is embodied, such as
CDs or digital files), as well as the
exclusive right to perform the work
publicly. 17 U.S.C. 106(1), (3). The
copyright owner can also authorize
others to engage in these acts. Id. These
rights, however, are typically licensed
in different ways.
The right to make and distribute
phonorecords of musical works (often
referred to as the ‘‘mechanical’’ right) is
subject to a compulsory statutory
license under Section 115 of the Act.
See generally 17 U.S.C. 115. That
license—instituted by Congress over a
century ago with the passage of the 1909
Copyright Act—provides that, once a
phonorecord of a musical work has been
distributed to the public in the United
States under the authority of the
copyright owner, any person can obtain
a license to make and distribute
phonorecords of that work by serving a
statutorily compliant notice and paying
the applicable royalties. Id.
In 1995, Congress confirmed that a
copyright owner’s exclusive right to
reproduce and distribute phonorecords
of a musical work, and the Section 115
license, extend to the making of ‘‘digital
phonorecord deliveries’’ (‘‘DPDs’’)—that
is, the transmission of digital files
embodying musical works. See Digital
Performance Right in Sound Recordings
Act of 1995 (‘‘DPRSRA’’), Public Law
104–39, sec. 4, 109 Stat. 336, 344–48; 17
U.S.C. 115(c)(3)(A).
1
The Copyright
Office has thus interpreted the Section
115 license to cover music downloads
(including ringtones), as well as the
server and other reproductions
necessary to engage in streaming
activities. See In the Matter of
Mechanical and Digital Phonorecord
1
Under the terms of Section 115, a record
company or other entity that obtains a statutory
license for a musical work can, in turn, authorize
third parties to make DPDs of that work. See 17
U.S.C. 115(c)(3). In such a ‘‘pass-through’’ situation,
the statutory licensee is then responsible for
reporting and paying royalties for such third-party
uses to the musical work owner.
Delivery Rate Adjustment Proceeding,
Docket No. RF 2006–1 (Oct. 16, 2006),
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/
ringtone-decision.pdf; Compulsory
License for Making and Distributing
Phonorecords, Including Digital
Phonorecord Deliveries, 73 FR 66173
(Nov. 7, 2008).
Licenses under Section 115 are
obtained on a song-by-song basis.
Because a typical online music service
needs to offer access to millions of songs
to compete in the marketplace,
obtaining the licenses on an individual
basis can present administrative
challenges.
2
Many music publishers
have designated the Harry Fox Agency,
Inc. as an agent to handle such song-by-
song mechanical licensing on their
behalf.
The royalty rates and terms for the
Section 115 license are established by
an administrative tribunal—the
Copyright Royalty Board (‘‘CRB’’)
3
which applies a standard set forth in
Section 801(b) of the Act that considers
four different factors. These include:
The availability of creative works to the
public; economic return to the owners
and users of musical works; the
respective contributions of owners and
users in making works available; and
the industry impact of the rates.
4
The Section 115 license applies to
audio-only reproductions that are
primarily made and distributed for
private use. See 17 U.S.C. 101, 115.
Reproductions and distribution of
musical works that fall outside of the
Section 115 license—including ‘‘synch’’
uses in audiovisual media like
2
Concerns about the efficiency of the Section 115
licensing process are not new. For instance, in
2005, then-Register of Copyrights Marybeth Peters
testified before Congress that Section 115 had
become ‘‘outdated,’’ and made several proposals to
reform the license. See Copyright Office Views on
Music Licensing Reform: Hearing Before the
Subcomm. on Courts, the Internet, and Intellectual
Property of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 109th
Cong. 4–9 (2005). In 2006, the House Judiciary
Committee’s Subcommittee on Courts, the Internet,
and Intellectual Property forwarded the Section 115
Reform Act (‘‘SIRA’’) to the full Judiciary
Committee by unanimous voice vote. See H.R. 5553,
109th Cong. (2006). This bill would have updated
Section 115 to create a blanket-style license. The
proposed legislation was not reported out by the
full Judiciary Committee, however.
3
The Copyright Royalty Board (‘‘CRB’’) is the
latest in a series of administrative bodies Congress
has created to adjust the rates and terms for the
statutory licenses. The first, the Copyright Royalty
Tribunal (‘‘CRT’’), was created in 1976. See Public
Law 94–553, sec. 801, 90 Stat. 2541, 2594–96
(1976). In 1993, Congress replaced the CRT with a
system of ad-hoc copyright arbitration royalty
panels (‘‘CARPs’’). See Copyright Royalty Tribunal
Reform Act of 1993, Public Law 103–198, sec. 2,
107 Stat. 2304, 2304–2308. Congress replaced the
CARP system with the CRB in 2004. See Copyright
Royalty and Distribution Reform Act of 2004, Public
Law 108–419, 118 Stat. 2341.
4
See 17 U.S.C. 801(b)(1).
VerDate Mar<15>2010 18:45 Mar 14, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00084 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\17MRN1.SGM 17MRN1
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
14741
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 51 / Monday, March 17, 2014 / Notices
television, film, and videos; advertising
and other types of commercial uses; and
derivative uses such as ‘‘sampling’’—are
licensed directly from the copyright
owner according to negotiated rates and
terms.
Musical Works—Public Performance.
The method for licensing public
performances of musical works differs
significantly from the statutory
mechanical license provided under
Section 115. Licensing fees for such
performances are generally collected on
behalf of music publishers, songwriters,
and composers by the three major PROs:
the American Society of Composers,
Authors and Publishers (‘‘ASCAP’’),
Broadcast Music, Inc. (‘‘BMI’’), and
SESAC. Songwriters and composers, as
well as their publishers, commonly
affiliate with one of the three for
purposes of receiving public
performance income. Rather than song-
by-song licenses, the PROs typically
offer ‘‘blanket’’ licenses for the full
range of music in their repertories.
These licenses are available for a wide
variety of uses, including terrestrial,
satellite, and internet radio, on-demand
music streaming services, Web site and
television uses, and performance of
music in bars, restaurants, and other
commercial establishments. The PROs
monitor the use of musical works by
these various entities and apportion and
distribute collected royalties to their
publisher, songwriter, and composer
members.
Unlike the mechanical right, the
public performance of musical works is
not subject to compulsory licensing
under the Copyright Act. Since 1941,
however, ASCAP and BMI’s licensing
practices have been subject to antitrust
consent decrees overseen by the
Department of Justice.
5
These consent
decrees were designed to protect
licensees from price discrimination or
other anti-competitive behavior by the
two PROs. Under the decrees, ASCAP
and BMI administer the public
performance right for their members’
musical works on a non-exclusive basis.
They are required to provide a license
to any person who seeks to perform
copyrighted musical works publicly,
and must offer the same terms to
similarly situated licensees. In addition,
ASCAP’s consent decree expressly bars
5
See generally United States v. Broadcast Music,
Inc., 275 F.3d 168, 171–72 (2d Cir. 2001)
(describing the history). SESAC, a smaller
performing rights organization created in 1930 to
serve European publishers, is not subject to a
similar consent decree, although it has been
involved recently in private antitrust litigation. See
Meredith Corp. v. SESAC LLC, No. 09–cv–9177,
2014 WL 812795 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 3, 2014).
it from offering mechanical licenses.
6
Since 1950, prospective licensees that
are unable to agree to a royalty rate with
ASCAP or BMI have been able to seek
a determination of a reasonable license
fee in the federal district court for the
Southern District of New York.
7
The two PRO consent decrees were
last amended well before the
proliferation of digital music: The BMI
decree in 1994,
8
and the ASCAP decree
in 2001.
9
The consent decrees have been
the subject of much litigation over the
years, including, most recently, suits
over whether music publishers can
withdraw digital licensing rights from
the PROs and negotiate public
performance licenses directly with
digital music services.
10
Sound Recordings—Reproduction
and Distribution. Congress extended
federal copyright protection to sound
recordings in 1972. That law, however,
did not provide retroactive protection
for sound recordings fixed prior to
February 15, 1972, and such works
therefore have no federal copyright
status.
11
They are, however, subject to
the protection of applicable state laws
until 2067. See 17 U.S.C. 301(c).
12
6
United States v. ASCAP, No. 41–cv–1395, 2001–
2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 73,474, 2001 WL 1589999, *3
(S.D.N.Y. June 11, 2001). Although BMI has taken
the position that a strict reading of its consent
decree does not bar it from offering mechanical
licenses, it generally has not done so. See Broadcast
Music, Inc., Comments on Department of Commerce
Green Paper 4–5 (Nov. 13, 2013), available at http://
www.ntia.doc.gov/files/ntia/bmi_comments.pdf.
7
Significantly, musical work owners are
precluded from offering evidence concerning the
licensing fees paid for digital performances of
sound recordings as a point of comparison in the
district court ratesetting proceedings. Section 114 of
the Copyright Act provides that license fees payable
for the public performance of sound recordings may
not be taken into account ‘‘in any administrative,
judicial, or other governmental proceeding to set or
adjust the rates payable to’’ musical work copyright
owners. 17 U.S.C. 114(i).
8
United States v. Broadcast Music, Inc., No. 64–
cv–3787, 1966 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 71,941 (S.D.N.Y.
1966), as amended, 1996 Trade Cases (CCH) ¶
71,378, 1994 WL 901652 (S.D.N.Y. Nov. 18, 1994).
9
United States v. ASCAP, No. 41–cv–1395, 2001–
2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 73,474, 2001 WL 1589999
(S.D.N.Y. June 11, 2001).
10
See In re Pandora Media, Inc., Nos. 12–cv–
8035, 41–cv–1395, 2013 WL 5211927 (S.D.N.Y.
Sept. 17, 2013); Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Pandora
Media, Inc., Nos. 13–cv–4037, 64–cv–3787, 2013
WL 6697788 (S.D.N.Y. Dec. 19, 2013).
11
In 2009, Congress asked the Copyright Office to
study the ‘‘desirability and means’’ of extending
federal copyright protection to pre-February 15,
1972 sound recordings. Public Law 111–8, 123 Stat.
524 (2010) (explanatory statement). In 2011, the
Office completed that study, issuing a report
recommending that federal copyright protection be
so extended. United States Copyright Office,
Federal Copyright Protection for Pre-1972 Sound
Recordings (2011), available at http://
www.copyright.gov/docs/sound/pre-72-report.pdf.
12
Thus, a person wishing to digitally perform a
pre-1972 sound recording cannot rely on the
Section 112 and 114 statutory licenses and must
The owner of a copyright in a sound
recording fixed on or after February 15,
1972, like the owner of a musical work
copyright, enjoys the exclusive right to
reproduce and distribute phonorecords
embodying the sound recording,
including by means of digital
transmission, and to authorize others to
do the same. 17 U.S.C. 106(1), (3),
301(c). Except in the limited
circumstances where statutory licensing
applies, as described below, licenses to
reproduce and distribute sound
recordings—such as those necessary to
make and distribute CDs, transmit
DPDs, and operate online music
services, as well as to use sound
recordings in a television shows, films,
video games, etc.—are negotiated
directly between the licensee and sound
recording owner (typically a record
label). Thus, while in the case of
musical works, the royalty rates and
terms applicable to the making and
distribution of CDs, DPDs, and the
operation of interactive music services
are subject to government oversight,
with respect to sound recordings,
licensing for those same uses takes place
without government supervision.
Sound Recordings—Public
Performance. Unlike musical works, a
sound recording owner’s public
performance right does not extend to all
manner of public performances.
Traditionally, the public performance of
sound recordings was not subject to
protection at all under the Copyright
Act. In 1995, however, Congress enacted
the DPRSRA, which provided for a
limited right when sound recordings are
publicly performed ‘‘by means of a
digital audio transmission.’’ Public Law
104–39, 109 Stat. 336; 17 U.S.C. 106(6),
114(a). This right extends, for example,
to satellite radio and internet-based
music services.
13
Significantly,
however, the public performance of
sound recordings by broadcast radio
stations remains exempt under the Act.
17 U.S.C. 114(d)(1).
14
instead obtain a license directly from the owner of
the sound recording copyright. See Determination
of Rates and Terms for Preexisting Subscription
Services and Satellite Digital Audio Radio Services,
78 FR 23054, 23073 (Apr. 17, 2013) (determination
of the CRB finding that ‘‘[t]he performance right
granted by the copyright laws for sound recordings
applies only to those recordings created on or after
February 15, 1972’’ and adopting provisions
allowing exclusion of performances of pre-1972
sound recordings from certain statutory royalties).
13
In 1998, as part of the DMCA, Congress
amended Sections 112 and 114 of the Copyright Act
to clarify that the digital sound recording
performance right applies to services like
webcasting. See Public Law 105–304, secs. 402,
405, 112 Stat. 2860, 2888, 2890.
14
The Copyright Office has long supported the
extension of the public performance right in sound
Continued
VerDate Mar<15>2010 18:45 Mar 14, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00085 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\17MRN1.SGM 17MRN1
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
14742
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 51 / Monday, March 17, 2014 / Notices
For certain uses, including those by
satellite and internet radio, the digital
public performance right for sound
recordings is subject to statutory
licensing in accordance with Sections
112 and 114 of the Act. Section 112
provides for a license to reproduce the
phonorecords (sometimes referred to as
‘‘ephemeral recordings’’) necessary to
facilitate a service’s transmissions to
subscribers, while Section 114 licenses
the public performances of sound
recordings resulting from those
transmissions. This statutory licensing
framework applies only to
noninteractive (i.e., radio-style) services
as defined under Section 114;
interactive (or on-demand services) are
not covered. See 17 U.S.C. 112(e); 17
U.S.C. 114(d)(2), (f). For interactive
services, sound recording owners
negotiate licenses directly with users.
The rates and terms applicable to the
public performance of sound recordings
under the Section 112 and 114 licenses
are established by the CRB. See 17
U.S.C. 801 et seq. The royalties due
under these licenses are paid to an
entity designated by the CRB—currently
SoundExchange, Inc.—which collects,
processes, and distributes payments on
behalf of rights holders.
15
Notably, under Section 114, the rate
standard applicable to those satellite
radio and music subscription services
that existed as of July 31, 1998 (i.e.,
‘‘preexisting’’ services
16
) differs from
recordings to broadcast radio. See Internet
Streaming of Radio Broadcasts: Balancing the
Interests of Sound Recording Copyright Owners
With Those of Broadcasters: Hearing Before the
Subcomm. on Courts, the Internet, and Intellectual
Property of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 108th
Cong. 6–7 (2004) (statement of David Carson,
General Counsel, U.S. Copyright Office), available
at http://www.copyright.gov/docs/
carson071504.pdf. Only a handful of countries lack
such a right; in addition to the United States, the
list includes China, North Korea, and Iran. This gap
in copyright protection has the effect of depriving
American performers and labels of foreign royalties
to which they would otherwise be entitled, because
even countries that recognize a public performance
right in sound recordings impose a reciprocity
requirement. According to one estimate, U.S. rights
holders lose approximately $70 million each year
in royalties for performances in foreign broadcasts.
See generally Mary LaFrance, From Whether to
How: The Challenge of Implementing a Full Public
Performance Right in Sound Recordings, 2 Harv. J.
of Sports & Ent. L 221, 226 (2011).
15
The Act requires that receipts under the
Section 114 statutory license be divided in the
following manner: 50 percent to the owner of the
digital public performance right in the sound
recording, 2
1
2
percent to nonfeatured musicians,
2
1
2
percent to nonfeatured vocalists, and 45 percent
to the featured recording artists. 17 U.S.C. 114(g)(2).
16
17 U.S.C. 114(j)(10), (11). Today, Sirius/XM is
the only preexisting satellite service that seeks
statutory licenses under Section 114. See
Determination of Rates and Terms for Preexisting
Subscription Services and Satellite Digital Audio
Radio Services, 78 FR 23054, 23055 (Apr. 17, 2013).
There are two preexisting subscription services,
Music Choice and Muzak. Id.
that for other services such as internet
radio.
17
Royalty rates for pre-existing
satellite radio and subscription services
are governed by the four-factor standard
in Section 801(b) of the Act—that is, the
standard that applies to the Section 115
license for musical works.
18
By contrast,
under the terms of Section 114, rates
and terms for noninteractive public
performances via internet radio and
other newer digital music services are to
be determined by the CRB based on
what a ‘‘willing buyer’’ and ‘‘willing
seller’’ would have agreed to in the
marketplace.
19
Subjects of Inquiry
The Copyright Office seeks public
input on the effectiveness of the current
methods for licensing musical works
and sound recordings. Accordingly, the
Office invites written comments on the
specific subjects above. A party
choosing to respond to this Notice of
Inquiry need not address every subject,
but the Office requests that responding
parties clearly identify and separately
address each subject for which a
response is submitted.
Musical Works
1. Please assess the current need for
and effectiveness of the Section 115
statutory license for the reproduction
and distribution of musical works.
2. Please assess the effectiveness of
the royalty ratesetting process and
standards under Section 115.
3. Would the music marketplace
benefit if the Section 115 license were
updated to permit licensing of musical
works on a blanket basis by one or more
collective licensing entities, rather than
17
18
See 17 U.S.C. 114(f)(1), 801(b)(1).
19
17 U.S.C. 114(f)(2)(B) instructs the CRB to
‘‘establish rates and terms that most clearly
represent the rates and terms that would have been
negotiated in the marketplace between a willing
buyer and willing seller.’’ The provision further
requires the CRB to consider ‘‘whether use of the
service may substitute for or may promote the sales
of phonorecords or otherwise may interfere with or
may enhance the sound recording copyright
owner’s other streams of revenue from its sound
recordings,’’ and ‘‘the relative roles of the copyright
owner and the transmitting entity in the
copyrighted work and the service made available to
the public with respect to relative creative
contribution, technological contribution, capital
investment, cost, and risk.’’ Id.
For all types of services eligible for a Section 114
statutory license, the rates for the phonorecords
(ephemeral recordings) used to operate the service
are to be established by the CRB under Section 112
according to a ‘‘willing buyer/willing seller’’
standard. 17 U.S.C. 112(e). In general, the Section
112 rates have been a relatively insignificant part
of the CRB’s ratesetting proceedings, and have been
established as a subset of the 114 rate. See, e.g.,
Determination of Rates and Terms for Preexisting
Subscription Services and Satellite Digital Audio
Radio Services, 78 FR 23054, 23055–56 (Apr. 17,
2013).
on a song-by-song basis? If so, what
would be the key elements of any such
system?
4. For uses under the Section 115
statutory license that also require a
public performance license, could the
licensing process be facilitated by
enabling the licensing of performance
rights along with reproduction and
distribution rights in a unified manner?
How might such a unified process be
effectuated?
5. Please assess the effectiveness of
the current process for licensing the
public performances of musical works.
6. Please assess the effectiveness of
the royalty ratesetting process and
standards applicable under the consent
decrees governing ASCAP and BMI, as
well as the impact, if any, of 17 U.S.C.
114(i), which provides that ‘‘[l]icense
fees payable for the public performance
of sound recordings under Section
106(6) shall not be taken into account in
any administrative, judicial, or other
governmental proceeding to set or adjust
the royalties payable to copyright
owners of musical works for the public
performance of their works.’’
7. Are the consent decrees serving
their intended purpose? Are the
concerns that motivated the entry of
these decrees still present given modern
market conditions and legal
developments? Are there alternatives
that might be adopted?
Sound Recordings
8. Please assess the current need for
and effectiveness of the Section 112 and
Section 114 statutory licensing process.
9. Please assess the effectiveness of
the royalty ratesetting process and
standards applicable to the various
types of services subject to statutory
licensing under Section 114.
10. Do any recent developments
suggest that the music marketplace
might benefit by extending federal
copyright protection to pre-1972 sound
recordings? Are there reasons to
continue to withhold such protection?
Should pre-1972 sound recordings be
included within the Section 112 and
114 statutory licenses?
11. Is the distinction between
interactive and noninteractive services
adequately defined for purposes of
eligibility for the Section 114 license?
Platform Parity
12. What is the impact of the varying
ratesetting standards applicable to the
Section 112, 114, and 115 statutory
licenses, including across different
music delivery platforms. Do these
differences make sense?
13. How do differences in the
applicability of the sound recording
VerDate Mar<15>2010 18:45 Mar 14, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00086 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\17MRN1.SGM 17MRN1
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
14743
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 51 / Monday, March 17, 2014 / Notices
public performance right impact music
licensing?
Changes in Music Licensing Practices
14. How prevalent is direct licensing
by musical work owners in lieu of
licensing through a common agent or
PRO? How does direct licensing impact
the music marketplace, including the
major record labels and music
publishers, smaller entities, individual
creators, and licensees?
15. Could the government play a role
in encouraging the development of
alternative licensing models, such as
micro-licensing platforms? If so, how
and for what types of uses?
16. In general, what innovations have
been or are being developed by
copyright owners and users to make the
process of music licensing more
effective?
17. Would the music marketplace
benefit from modifying the scope of the
existing statutory licenses?
Revenues and Investment
18. How have developments in the
music marketplace affected the income
of songwriters, composers, and
recording artists?
19. Are revenues attributable to the
performance and sale of music fairly
divided between creators and
distributors of musical works and sound
recordings?
20. In what ways are investment
decisions by creators, music publishers,
and record labels, including the
investment in the development of new
projects and talent, impacted by music
licensing issues?
21. How do licensing concerns impact
the ability to invest in new distribution
models?
Data Standards
22. Are there ways the federal
government could encourage the
adoption of universal standards for the
identification of musical works and
sound recordings to facilitate the music
licensing process?
Other Issues
23. Please supply or identify data or
economic studies that measure or
quantify the effect of technological or
other developments on the music
licensing marketplace, including the
revenues attributable to the
consumption of music in different
formats and through different
distribution channels, and the income
earned by copyright owners.
24. Please identify any pertinent
issues not referenced above that the
Copyright Office should consider in
conducting its study.
Dated: March 11, 2014.
Jacqueline C. Charlesworth,
General Counsel and Associate, Register of
Copyrights.
[FR Doc. 2014–05711 Filed 3–14–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 1410–30–P
NATIONAL ARCHIVES AND RECORDS
ADMINISTRATION
[NARA–2014–020]
Records Schedules; Availability and
Request for Comments
AGENCY
: National Archives and Records
Administration (NARA).
ACTION
: Notice of availability of
proposed records schedules; request for
comments.
SUMMARY
: The National Archives and
Records Administration (NARA)
publishes notice at least once monthly
of certain Federal agency requests for
records disposition authority (records
schedules). Once approved by NARA,
records schedules provide mandatory
instructions on what happens to records
when no longer needed for current
Government business. They authorize
the preservation of records of
continuing value in the National
Archives of the United States and the
destruction, after a specified period, of
records lacking administrative, legal,
research, or other value. Notice is
published for records schedules in
which agencies propose to destroy
records not previously authorized for
disposal or reduce the retention period
of records already authorized for
disposal. NARA invites public
comments on such records schedules, as
required by 44 U.S.C. 3303a(a).
DATES
: Requests for copies must be
received in writing on or before April
16, 2014. Once the appraisal of the
records is completed, NARA will send
a copy of the schedule. NARA staff
usually prepares appraisal memoranda
that contain additional information
concerning the records covered by a
proposed schedule. These, too, may be
requested and will be provided once the
appraisal is completed. Requesters will
be given 30 days to submit comments on
the schedule.
ADDRESSES
: You may request a copy of
any records schedule identified in this
notice by contacting Records
Management Services (ACNR) using one
of the following means:
Mail: NARA (ACNR), 8601 Adelphi
Road, College Park, MD 20740–6001
FAX: 301–837–3698
Requesters must cite the control
number, which appears in parentheses
after the name of the agency which
submitted the schedule, and must
provide a mailing address. Those who
desire appraisal reports should so
indicate in their request.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT
:
Margaret Hawkins, Director, Records
Management Services (ACNR), National
Archives and Records Administration,
8601 Adelphi Road, College Park, MD
20740–6001. Telephone: 301–837–1799.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
: Each year
Federal agencies create billions of
records on paper, film, magnetic tape,
and other media. To control this
accumulation, agency records managers
prepare schedules proposing retention
periods for records and submit these
schedules for NARA’s approval. These
schedules provide for the timely transfer
into the National Archives of
historically valuable records and
authorize the disposal of all other
records after the agency no longer needs
them to conduct its business. Some
schedules are comprehensive and cover
all the records of an agency or one of its
major subdivisions. Most schedules,
however, cover records of only one
office or program or a few series of
records. Many of these update
previously approved schedules, and
some include records proposed as
permanent.
The schedules listed in this notice are
media-neutral unless specified
otherwise. An item in a schedule is
media-neutral when the disposition
instructions may be applied to records
regardless of the medium in which the
records are created and maintained.
Items included in schedules submitted
to NARA on or after December 17, 2007,
are media-neutral unless the item is
specifically limited to a specific
medium. (See 36 CFR 1225.12(e).)
No Federal records are authorized for
destruction without the approval of the
Archivist of the United States. This
approval is granted only after a
thorough consideration of their
administrative use by the agency of
origin, the rights of the Government and
of private persons directly affected by
the Government’s activities, and
whether or not they have historical or
other value.
Besides identifying the Federal
agencies and any subdivisions
requesting disposition authority, this
public notice lists the organizational
unit(s) accumulating the records or
indicates agency-wide applicability in
the case of schedules that cover records
that may be accumulated throughout an
VerDate Mar<15>2010 17:56 May 02, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00066 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\05MYN1.SGM 05MYN1
emcdonald on DSK67QTVN1PROD with NOTICES
25626
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 86 / Monday, May 5, 2014 / Notices
imports) and (a)(2)(B)(II.B.) (shift in
production to a foreign country) have
not been met.
85,099, Harrington Tool Company,
Ludington, Michigan.
The workers’ firm does not produce
an article as required for certification
under Section 222 of the Trade Act of
1974.
85,046, AIG Claims, Houston, Texas.
85,097, SuperMedia Services, LLC.,
Middleton, Massachusetts.
85,122, Bimbo Bakaries USA, Inc.,
Wichita, Kansas.
85,144, IP & Science (Patent Payments),
Bingham Farms, Michigan.
85,145, AXA Equitable Life Insurance
Company, Charlotte, North Carolina.
Determinations Terminating
Investigations of Petitions for Worker
Adjustment Assistance
After notice of the petitions was
published in the Federal Register and
on the Department’s Web site, as
required by Section 221 of the Act (19
USC 2271), the Department initiated
investigations of these petitions.
None.
I hereby certify that the
aforementioned determinations were
issued during the period of March 31,
2014 through April 4, 2014. These
determinations are available on the
Department’s Web site tradeact/taa/taa_
search_form.cfm under the searchable
listing of determinations or by calling
the Office of Trade Adjustment
Assistance toll free at 888–365–6822.
Signed at Washington, DC this 10th day of
April 2014.
Del Min Amy Chen,
Certifying Officer, Office of Trade Adjustment
Assistance.
[FR Doc. 2014–10166 Filed 5–2–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4510–FN–P
LIBRARY OF CONGRESS
U.S. Copyright Office
[Docket No. 2014–03]
Music Licensing Study
AGENCY
: U.S. Copyright Office, Library
of Congress.
ACTION
: Notice of public roundtables.
SUMMARY
: The U.S. Copyright Office is
undertaking a study to evaluate the
effectiveness of current methods for
licensing musical works and sound
recordings. The study will assess
whether and how existing methods
serve the music marketplace, including
new and emerging digital distribution
platforms. In addition to soliciting
written comments, the Office is
conducting three two-day public
roundtables on music licensing issues.
A Notice of Inquiry soliciting written
comments in response to a number of
subjects was issued on March 17, 2014,
and written comments are due on or
before May 16, 2014. See 78 FR 14739
(Mar. 17, 2014). At this time, the
Copyright Office announces three public
roundtables to be held in June 2014 in
Nashville, Los Angeles, and New York.
DATES
: The two-day public roundtable
in Nashville will be held on June 4 and
5, 2014, on both days from 9:00 a.m. to
5:00 p.m. The two-day public
roundtable in Los Angeles will be held
on June 16 and 17, 2014, on both days
from 9:00 a.m. to 5:00 p.m. The two-day
public roundtable in New York will be
held on June 23 and 24, 2014, from 9:00
a.m. to 5:00 p.m. on June 23, and from
8:30 a.m. to 4:00 p.m. on June 24.
Requests to participate in the
roundtables must be received by the
Copyright Office by May 20, 2014.
ADDRESSES
: The Nashville roundtable
will take place at Belmont University’s
Mike Curb College of Entertainment and
Music Business, 34 Music Square East,
Nashville, Tennessee 37203. The Los
Angeles roundtable will take place at
the UCLA School of Law, 385 Charles E.
Young Drive East, Los Angeles,
California 90095. The New York
roundtable will take place at the New
York University School of Law, 40
Washington Square South, New York,
New York 10012. Requests to participate
in the roundtables should be submitted
using the form available on the Office’s
Web site at http://www.copyright.gov/
docs/musiclicensingstudy. If electronic
submission is not feasible, please
contact the Office at 202–707–8350 for
special instructions.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT
:
Jacqueline C. Charlesworth, General
Counsel and Associate Register of
Copyrights, by email at jcharlesworth@
loc.gov or by telephone at 202–707–
8350; or Sarang V. Damle, Special
Advisor to the General Counsel, by
email at [email protected] or by telephone
at 202–707–8350.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
: Congress
is currently engaged in a comprehensive
review of the U.S. Copyright Act, 17
U.S.C. 101 et seq., to evaluate potential
revisions to the law in light of
technological and other developments
that impact the creation, dissemination,
and use of copyrighted works. In light
of Congress’s review and significant
changes to the music industry in recent
years, the U.S. Copyright Office is
conducting a study to assess the
effectiveness of current methods for
licensing sound recordings and musical
works. The Office published a Notice of
Inquiry on March 17, 2014, seeking
written comments on twenty-four
subjects concerning the current
environment in which music is
licensed. See 78 FR 14739 (Mar. 17,
2014).
At this time, the Copyright Office is
providing notice of its intention to seek
further input for its study through three
two-day public roundtables to be held
in Nashville, Los Angeles, and New
York. The public roundtables will offer
an opportunity for interested parties to
comment on pertinent music licensing
issues. The roundtables will address
topics set forth in the Notice of Inquiry,
including: The current music licensing
landscape; licensing of sound
recordings, including under the Section
112 and 114 statutory licenses and the
treatment of pre-1972 recordings;
licensing of musical works, including
under the Section 115 statutory license
and through the performing rights
organizations (‘‘PROs’’); fair royalty
rates and platform parity; industry data
standards; industry incentives and
investment; and potential future
developments in music licensing.
Following discussion of the various
agenda topics by roundtable
participants, observers at the
roundtables will be provided a limited
opportunity to offer additional
comments.
The roundtable hearing rooms will
have a limited number of seats for
participants and observers. Those who
seek to participate should complete and
submit the form available on the Office’s
Web site at http://www.copyright.gov/
docs/musiclicensingstudy so it is
received by the Office no later than May
20, 2014. For individuals who wish to
observe a roundtable, the Office will
provide public seating on a first-come,
first-serve basis on the days of the
roundtable.
Dated: April 30, 2014.
Jacqueline C. Charlesworth,
General Counsel and Associate Register of
Copyrights.
[FR Doc. 2014–10242 Filed 5–2–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 1410–30–P
NATIONAL ARCHIVES AND RECORDS
ADMINISTRATION
[NARA 2014–026]
Creation of Freedom of Information Act
Advisory Committee
AGENCY
: National Archives and Records
Administration.
VerDate Mar<15>2010 17:33 Jul 22, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00079 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\23JYN1.SGM 23JYN1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
42833
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 141 / Wednesday, July 23, 2014 / Notices
U.S.C. § 300j–9(i), 33 U.S.C. § 1367, 15
U.S.C. § 2622, 42 U.S.C. § 6971, 42
U.S.C. § 7622, 42 U.S.C. § 9610, 42
U.S.C. § 5851, 49 U.S.C. § 42121, 18
U.S.C. § 1514A, 49 U.S.C. § 60129, 49
U.S.C. § 20109, 6 U.S.C. § 1142, 15
U.S.C. § 2087, 29 U.S.C. § 218c, 12
U.S.C. § 5567, 46 U.S.C. § 2114, 21
U.S.C. § 399d, and 49 U.S.C. § 30171.
Signed at Washington, DC on July 18, 2014.
David Michaels,
Assistant Secretary of Labor for Occupational
Safety and Health.
[FR Doc. 2014–17342 Filed 7–22–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4510–26–P
LIBRARY OF CONGRESS
Copyright Office
[Docket No. 2014–03]
Music Licensing Study: Second
Request for Comments
AGENCY
: U.S. Copyright Office, Library
of Congress.
ACTION
: Notice of inquiry.
SUMMARY
: The U.S. Copyright Office has
undertaken a study to evaluate the
effectiveness of current methods for
licensing musical works and sound
recordings. At this time, the Office seeks
additional comments on whether and
how existing music licensing methods
serve the music marketplace, including
new and emerging digital distribution
platforms.
DATES
: Written comments are due on or
before August 22, 2014.
ADDRESSES
: All comments shall be
submitted electronically. A comment
page containing a comment form is
posted on the Office Web site at
http://www.copyright.gov/200B;docs/
200B;musiclicensingstudy. The Web site
interface requires commenting parties to
complete a form specifying their name
and organization, as applicable, and to
upload comments as an attachment via
a browser button. To meet accessibility
standards, commenting parties must
upload comments in a single file not to
exceed six megabytes (MB) in one of the
following formats: The Portable
Document File (PDF) format that
contains searchable, accessible text (not
an image); Microsoft Word;
WordPerfect; Rich Text Format (RTF); or
ASCII text file format (not a scanned
document). The form and face of the
comments must include both the name
of the submitter and organization. The
Office will post the comments publicly
on its Web site in the form that they are
received, along with associated names
and organizations. If electronic
submission of comments is not feasible,
please contact the Office at 202–707–
8350 for special instructions.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT
:
Jacqueline C. Charlesworth, General
Counsel and Associate Register of
Copyrights, by email at jcharlesworth@
loc.gov or by telephone at 202–707–
8350; or Sarang V. Damle, Special
Advisor to the General Counsel, by
email at [email protected] or by telephone
at 202–707–8350.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
:
I. Background
The U.S. Copyright Office is
conducting a study to assess the
effectiveness of the current methods for
licensing musical works and sound
recordings. To aid with this study, the
Office published an initial Notice of
Inquiry on March 17, 2014 (‘‘First
Notice’’) seeking written comments on
twenty-four subjects concerning the
current environment in which music is
licensed. 78 FR 14739 (Mar. 17, 2014).
The eighty-five written submissions
received in response to this initial
notice can be found on the Copyright
Office Web site at http://
www.copyright.gov/docs/musiclicensing
study/200B;comments/Docket2014_3/.
In June 2014, the Office conducted three
two-day public roundtables in
Nashville, Los Angeles, and New York
City. The three roundtables provided
participants with the opportunity to
share their views on the topics
identified in the First Notice and other
issues relating to music licensing. See
79 FR 25626 (May 5, 2014). Transcripts
of the proceedings at each of the three
roundtables will be made available on
the Copyright Office Web site at
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/
200B;musiclicensingstudy/.
In the initial round of written
comments and during the roundtable
sessions, a number of significant issues
were discussed that the Office believes
merit additional consideration.
First, as explained in the First Notice,
in 2013, the two federal district courts
overseeing the antitrust consent decrees
governing the largest performance rights
organizations (‘‘PROs’’), American
Society of Composers, Authors and
Publishers (‘‘ASCAP’’) and Broadcast
Music, Inc. (‘‘BMI’’), held in separate
opinions that under those decrees,
music publishers could not withdraw
selected rights—such as ‘‘new media’’
rights—to be directly licensed outside of
the PROs; rather, a particular
publisher’s song catalog must either be
‘‘all in’’ or ‘‘all out.’’
1
Following these
1
In re Pandora Media, Inc., Nos. 12–cv–8035, 41–
cv–1395, 2013 WL 5211927 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 17,
rulings, both in public statements and at
the recent roundtables, certain major
music publishers have indicated that, if
the consent decrees remain in place
without modification, they intend to
withdraw their entire catalogs from the
two PROs and directly license public
performances.
2
Such a move would
affect not only online services, but more
traditional areas of public performance
such as radio, television, restaurants,
and bars.
Stakeholders at the roundtables
expressed significant concerns regarding
the impact of major publishers’
complete withdrawal from the PROs.
Notably, traditional songwriter contracts
typically include provisions that assume
that a songwriter’s performance
royalties will be collected by and paid
directly to the songwriter through a
PRO, without contemplating alternative
arrangements. Songwriters and
composers raised questions as to how
withdrawing publishers would fulfill
this responsibility in the future,
including whether they would be in a
position to track and provide adequate
usage and payment data under a direct
licensing system. Another concern is
how such withdrawals would affect the
PROs’ cost structures and the
commission rates for smaller entities
and individual creators who continued
to rely upon these organizations to
license and administer their public
performance rights. At the same time,
some stakeholders questioned the
existing distribution methodologies of
the PROs, suggesting that the PROs
should rely more on census-based
reporting (as is typically supplied by
digital services) and less on sampling or
non-census-based approaches to allocate
royalty fees among members.
Next, many stakeholders appear to be
of the view that the Section 115
statutory license for the reproduction
and distribution of musical works
should either be eliminated or
significantly modified to reflect the
realities of the digital marketplace.
While music owners and music users
have expressed a range of views as to
the particulars of how this might be
accomplished, much of the commentary
and discussion has centered on two
2013); Broadcast Music, Inc., v. Pandora Media,
Inc., Nos. 12–cv–4037, 64–cv–3787, 2013 WL
6697788 (S.D.N.Y. Dec. 19, 2013).
2
See Ed Christman, Universal Music Publishing
Plots Exit From ASCAP, BMI, Billboard (Feb. 1,
2013), http://www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/
publishing/1537554/universal-music-publishing-
plots-exit-from-ascap-bmi; see also Ed Christman,
Sony/ATV’s Martin Bandier Repeats Warning to
ASCAP, BMI, Billboard (July 11, 2014), http://
www.billboard.com/biz/articles/news/publishing/
6157469/sonyatvs-martin-bandier-repeats-warning-
to-ascap-bmi.
VerDate Mar<15>2010 17:33 Jul 22, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00080 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\23JYN1.SGM 23JYN1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
42834
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 141 / Wednesday, July 23, 2014 / Notices
possible approaches. The first would be
to sunset the Section 115 license with
the goal of enabling musical work
owners to negotiate licenses directly
with music users at unregulated,
marketplace rates (as the
synchronization market for musical
works currently operates). Some
stakeholders have acknowledged,
however, that such a market-based
system might still have to allow for the
possibility of collective licensing to
accommodate individuals and smaller
copyright owners who might lack the
capacity or leverage to negotiate directly
with online service providers and
others.
A second model, advocated by the
record labels, would be to eliminate
Section 115 and instead allow music
publishers and sound recording owners
collectively to negotiate an
industrywide revenue-sharing
arrangement as between them. For the
uses falling under this approach, a fixed
percentage of licensing fees for use of a
recorded song would be allocated to the
musical work and the remainder would
go to the sound recording owner. Record
labels would be permitted to bundle
musical work licenses with their sound
recording licenses, with third-party
licensees to pay the overall license fees
to publishers and labels according to the
agreed industry percentages. While
musical work owners would retain
control over the first recordings of their
works, such an arrangement would
cover not only audio-only uses but
would extend to certain audiovisual
uses not currently covered by the
Section 115 license, such as music
videos and lyric display.
Another theme that emerged from the
first round of written comments and the
public roundtables relates to the Section
112 and 114 statutory licenses for the
digital performance of sound
recordings.
3
Although there appeared to
3
Based upon written comments and discussion at
the roundtables, it appears that certain language in
the First Notice concerning the lack of availability
of licenses for pre-1972 recordings under Sections
112 and 114 may have been misinterpreted by
some. In a footnote, the First Notice observed that
‘‘a person wishing to digitally perform a pre-1972
sound recording cannot rely on the Section 112 and
114 statutory licenses and must instead obtain a
license directly from the owner of the sound
recording copyright.’’ 78 FR 14739, 14741 n.12. In
making this statement, the Office was not opining
on the necessity of obtaining such a license under
state law, but merely observing that licenses for the
digital performance of pre-1972 sound recordings,
and for the reproductions to enable such
performances, are not available under Section 112
or 114. A licensee seeking such a license would
thus need to obtain it directly from the sound
recording owner (as the Office understands to be
the current practice of some licensees with respect
to performances of pre-1972 recordings).
be substantial agreement that these
licenses are largely effective, there was
also a general consensus that
improvements could be made to the
Copyright Royalty Judges’ (‘‘CRJs’’)
statutorily mandated ratesetting
procedures. For instance, under 17
U.S.C. 803(b)(6), parties in proceedings
before the CRJs must submit written
direct statements before any discovery is
conducted. A number of commenters
believed that the ratesetting process
could be significantly streamlined by
allowing for discovery before
presentation of the parties’ direct cases,
as in ordinary civil litigation.
Stakeholders were also of the view that
it would be more efficient to combine
what are now two separate direct and
rebuttal phases of ratesetting hearings,
as contemplated by 17 U.S.C.
803(b)(6)(C), into a single integrated
trial—again as is more typical of civil
litigation. There was also general
agreement that more could be done to
encourage settlement of rate disputes,
such as adoption of settlements earlier
in the process and allowing such
settlements to be treated as non-
precedential with respect to non-settling
participants.
Finally, many commenting parties
pointed to the lack of standardized and
reliable data related to the identity and
ownership of musical works and sound
recordings as a significant obstacle to
more efficient music licensing
mechanisms. Stakeholders observed that
digital music files are often distributed
to online providers without identifiers
such as the International Standard
Recording Code (‘‘ISRC’’) and/or
International Standard Musical Work
Code (‘‘ISWC’’), and that the lack of
these identifiers (or other unique or
universal identifiers) makes it difficult
for licensees or others to link particular
music files with the copyrighted works
they embody. In addition to problems
identifying the musical works and
sound recordings themselves,
commenters noted the difficulties of
ascertaining ownership information,
On the other side of the coin, it appears that
others have misread the Office’s observation in its
report on pre-1972 sound recordings that ‘‘[i]n
general, state law does not appear to recognize a
performance right in sound recordings’’ as an
official statement that no such protection is (or
should be) available under state law. See U.S.
Copyright Office, Federal Copyright Protection for
Pre-1972 Sound Recordings 44 (2011). This, too, is
a misinterpretation. While, as a factual matter, a
state may not have affirmatively acknowledged a
public performance right in pre-1972 recordings as
of the Office’s 2011 report, the language in the
report should not be read to suggest that a state
could not properly interpret its law to recognize
such a right. As the Office explained, ‘‘common law
protection is amorphous, and courts often perceive
themselves to have broad discretion.’’ Id. at 48.
especially in the case of musical works,
which frequently have multiple owners
representing varying percentages of
particular songs. These issues, in turn,
relate to a more general ‘‘transparency’’
concern of music creators that usage and
payment information—including
information about advances and equity
provided by licensees to publishers and
labels—may not be fully and readily
accessible to songwriters, composers
and artists.
At this time, the Office is soliciting
additional comments on these subjects,
as set forth in the specific questions
below. Parties may also take this
opportunity to respond to the positions
taken by others in the first round of
comments and/or at the roundtables.
Those who plan to submit additional
comments should be aware that the
Office has studied and will take into
consideration the comments already
received, so there is no need to restate
previously submitted material. While a
party choosing to respond to this Notice
of Inquiry need not address every
subject below, the Office requests that
responding parties clearly identify and
separately address each subject for
which a response is submitted.
Subjects of Inquiry
Data and Transparency
1. Please address possible methods for
ensuring the development and
dissemination of comprehensive and
authoritative public data related to the
identity and ownership of musical
works and sound recordings, including
how best to incentivize private actors to
gather, assimilate and share reliable
data.
2. What are the most widely embraced
identifiers used in connection with
musical works, sound recordings,
songwriters, composers, and artists?
How and by whom are they issued and
managed? How might the government
incentivize more universal availability
and adoption?
3. Please address possible methods for
enhancing transparency in the reporting
of usage, payment, and distribution data
by licensees, record labels, music
publishers, and collective licensing
entities, including disclosure of non-
usage-based forms of compensation
(e.g., advances against future royalty
payments and equity shares).
Musical Works
4. Please provide your views on the
logistics and consequences of potential
publisher withdrawals from ASCAP
and/or BMI, including how such
withdrawals would be governed by the
PROs; whether such withdrawals are
VerDate Mar<15>2010 17:33 Jul 22, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00081 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 E:\FR\FM\23JYN1.SGM 23JYN1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
42835
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 141 / Wednesday, July 23, 2014 / Notices
compatible with existing publisher
agreements with songwriters and
composers; whether the PROs might
still play a role in administering
licenses issued directly by the
publishers, and if so, how; the effect of
any such withdrawals on PRO cost
structures and commissions; licensees’
access to definitive data concerning
individual works subject to withdrawal;
and related issues.
5. Are there ways in which the
current PRO distribution methodologies
could or should be improved?
6. In recent years, PROs have
announced record-high revenues and
distributions. At the same time, many
songwriters report significant declines
in income. What marketplace
developments have led to this result,
and what implications does it have for
the music licensing system?
7. If the Section 115 license were to
be eliminated, how would the transition
work? In the absence of a statutory
regime, how would digital service
providers obtain licenses for the
millions of songs they seem to believe
are required to meet consumer
expectations? What percentage of these
works could be directly licensed
without undue transaction costs and
would some type of collective licensing
remain necessary to facilitate licensing
of the remainder? If so, would such
collective(s) require government
oversight? How might uses now outside
of Section 115, such as music videos
and lyric displays, be accommodated?
Sound Recordings
8. Are there ways in which Section
112 and 114 (or other) CRB ratesetting
proceedings could be streamlined or
otherwise improved from a procedural
standpoint?
International Music Licensing Models
9. International licensing models for
the reproduction, distribution, and
public performance of musical works
differ from the current regimes for
licensing musical works in the United
States. Are there international music
licensing models the Office should look
to as it continues to review the U.S.
system?
Other Issues
10. Please identify any other pertinent
issues that the Copyright Office may
wish to consider in evaluating the music
licensing landscape.
Dated: July 18, 2014.
Jacqueline C. Charlesworth,
General Counsel and Associate, Register of
Copyrights.
[FR Doc. 2014–17354 Filed 7–22–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 1410–30–P
NATIONAL ARCHIVES AND RECORDS
ADMINISTRATION
[NARA–2014–044]
Records Schedules; Availability and
Request for Comments
AGENCY
: National Archives and Records
Administration (NARA).
ACTION
: Notice of availability of
proposed records schedules; request for
comments.
SUMMARY
: The National Archives and
Records Administration (NARA)
publishes notice at least once monthly
of certain Federal agency requests for
records disposition authority (records
schedules). Once approved by NARA,
records schedules provide mandatory
instructions on what happens to records
when no longer needed for current
Government business. They authorize
the preservation of records of
continuing value in the National
Archives of the United States and the
destruction, after a specified period, of
records lacking administrative, legal,
research, or other value. Notice is
published for records schedules in
which agencies propose to destroy
records not previously authorized for
disposal or reduce the retention period
of records already authorized for
disposal. NARA invites public
comments on such records schedules, as
required by 44 U.S.C. 3303a(a).
DATES
: Requests for copies must be
received in writing on or before August
22, 2014. Once the appraisal of the
records is completed, NARA will send
a copy of the schedule. NARA staff
usually prepare appraisal
memorandums that contain additional
information concerning the records
covered by a proposed schedule. These,
too, may be requested and will be
provided once the appraisal is
completed. Requesters will be given 30
days to submit comments.
ADDRESSES
: You may request a copy of
any records schedule identified in this
notice by contacting Records
Management Services (ACNR) using one
of the following means:
Mail: NARA (ACNR), 8601 Adelphi
Road, College Park, MD 20740–6001.
Fax: 301–837–3698.
Requesters must cite the control
number, which appears in parentheses
after the name of the agency which
submitted the schedule, and must
provide a mailing address. Those who
desire appraisal reports should so
indicate in their request.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT
:
Margaret Hawkins, Director, Records
Management Services (ACNR), National
Archives and Records Administration,
8601 Adelphi Road, College Park, MD
20740–6001. Telephone: 301–837–1799.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
: Each year
Federal agencies create billions of
records on paper, film, magnetic tape,
and other media. To control this
accumulation, agency records managers
prepare schedules proposing retention
periods for records and submit these
schedules for NARA’s approval. These
schedules provide for the timely transfer
into the National Archives of
historically valuable records and
authorize the disposal of all other
records after the agency no longer needs
them to conduct its business. Some
schedules are comprehensive and cover
all the records of an agency or one of its
major subdivisions. Most schedules,
however, cover records of only one
office or program or a few series of
records. Many of these update
previously approved schedules, and
some include records proposed as
permanent.
The schedules listed in this notice are
media neutral unless specified
otherwise. An item in a schedule is
media neutral when the disposition
instructions may be applied to records
regardless of the medium in which the
records are created and maintained.
Items included in schedules submitted
to NARA on or after December 17, 2007,
are media neutral unless the item is
limited to a specific medium. (See 36
CFR 1225.12(e).)
No Federal records are authorized for
destruction without the approval of the
Archivist of the United States. This
approval is granted only after a
thorough consideration of their
administrative use by the agency of
origin, the rights of the Government and
of private persons directly affected by
the Government’s activities, and
whether or not they have historical or
other value.
Besides identifying the Federal
agencies and any subdivisions
requesting disposition authority, this
public notice lists the organizational
unit(s) accumulating the records or
indicates agency-wide applicability in
the case of schedules that cover records
that may be accumulated throughout an
agency. This notice provides the control
number assigned to each schedule, the
total number of schedule items, and the
number of temporary items (the records
proposed for destruction). It also
includes a brief description of the
temporary records. The records
schedule itself contains a full
description of the records at the file unit
VerDate Mar<15>2010 22:09 Jul 31, 2014 Jkt 232001 PO 00000 Frm 00134 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 9990 E:\FR\FM\01AUN1.SGM 01AUN1
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
44871
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 148 / Friday, August 1, 2014 / Notices
Total Responses: 1,643.
Average Time per Response: 60
minutes.
Estimated Total Burden Hours: 1,643
hours.
Total Other Burden Cost: $0.
Comments submitted in response to
this request will be summarized and/or
included in the request for Office of
Management and Budget approval; they
will also become a matter of public
record.
James H. Moore, Jr.,
Deputy Assistant Secretary for Policy, U.S.
Department of Labor.
[FR Doc. 2014–18184 Filed 7–31–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4510–23–P
LIBRARY OF CONGRESS
Copyright Office
[Docket No. 2014–03]
Music Licensing Study
AGENCY
: U.S. Copyright Office, Library
of Congress.
ACTION
: Notice of extension of comment
period.
SUMMARY
: The United States Copyright
Office is extending the deadline for
public comments regarding the
effectiveness of existing methods of
licensing music that were solicited in a
July 23, 2014 Notice of Inquiry. See 79
FR 42833 (July 23, 2014).
DATES
: Written comments are now due
on or before September 12, 2014.
ADDRESSES
: All comments shall be
submitted electronically. A comment
page containing a comment form is
posted on the Office Web site at
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/
musiclicensingstudy. The Web site
interface requires commenting parties to
complete a form specifying their name
and organization, as applicable, and to
upload comments as an attachment via
a browser button. To meet accessibility
standards, commenting parties must
upload comments in a single file not to
exceed six megabytes (MB) in one of the
following formats: The Portable
Document File (PDF) format that
contains searchable, accessible text (not
an image); Microsoft Word;
WordPerfect; Rich Text Format (RTF); or
ASCII text file format (not a scanned
document). The form and face of the
comments must include both the name
of the submitter and organization. The
Office will post the comments publicly
on the Office’s Web site in the form that
they are received, along with associated
names and organizations. If electronic
submission of comments is not feasible,
please contact the Office at 202–707–
8350 for special instructions.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT
:
Jacqueline C. Charlesworth, General
Counsel and Associate Register of
Copyrights, by email at jcharlesworth@
loc.gov or by telephone at 202–707–
8350; or Sarang V. Damle, Special
Advisor to the General Counsel, by
email at [email protected] or by telephone
at 202–707–8350.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
:
I. Background
The U.S. Copyright Office is
conducting a study to assess the
effectiveness of current methods for
licensing sound recordings and musical
works. The Office received written
comments responding to an initial
Notice of Inquiry, and held three public
roundtables in Nashville, Los Angeles
and New York. See 78 FR 13739 (Mar.
17, 2014); 79 FR 25626 (May 5, 2014).
On July 23, 2014, the Office published
a second Notice of Inquiry, seeking
additional written comments on ten
subjects concerning the music licensing
environment. 79 FR 42833. To ensure
commenters have sufficient time to
address the topics set forth in the July
2014 Notice of Inquiry, the Office is
extending the time for filing written
comments from August 22, 2014 to
September 12, 2014.
Dated: July 28, 2014.
Maria A. Pallante,
Register of Copyrights.
[FR Doc. 2014–18096 Filed 7–31–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 1410–30–P
LIBRARY OF CONGRESS
U.S. Copyright Office
[Docket No. 2014–02]
Extension of Comment Period; Study
on the Right of Making Available;
Request for Additional Comments
AGENCY
: U.S. Copyright Office, Library
of Congress.
ACTION
: Extension of comment period.
SUMMARY
: The U.S. Copyright Office is
extending the deadline for public
comments that address topics listed in
the Office’s July 15, 2014 Request for
Additional Comments.
DATES
: Comments are now due no later
than 5:00 p.m. EDT on September 15,
2014.
ADDRESSES
: All comments should be
submitted electronically. To submit
comments, please visit http://
www.copyright.gov/docs/making_
available/. The Web site interface
requires submitters to complete a form
specifying name and organization, as
applicable, and to upload comments as
an attachment via a browser button. To
meet accessibility standards,
commenting parties must upload
comments in a single file not to exceed
six megabytes (‘‘MB’’) in one of the
following formats: a Portable Document
File (‘‘PDF’’) format that contains
searchable, accessible text (not an
image); Microsoft Word; WordPerfect;
Rich Text Format (‘‘RTF’’); or ASCII text
file format (not a scanned document).
The form and face of the comments
must include both the name of the
submitter and organization. The Office
will post all comments publicly on the
Office’s Web site exactly as they are
received, along with names and
organizations. If electronic submission
of comments is not feasible, please
contact the Office at 202–707–1027 for
special instructions.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT
:
Maria Strong, Senior Counsel for Policy
and International Affairs, by telephone
at 202–707–1027 or by email at
[email protected], or Kevin Amer,
Counsel for Policy and International
Affairs, by telephone at 202–707–1027
or by email at [email protected].
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
: On July
15, 2014, the Copyright Office issued a
Request for Additional Comments on
the state of U.S. law recognizing and
protecting ‘‘making available’’ and
‘‘communication to the public’’ rights
for copyright holders.
1
The Request
listed several questions for interested
members of the public to address in the
context of U.S. implementation of the
WIPO Copyright Treaty (WCT) and the
WIPO Performances and Phonograms
Treaty (WPPT) rights of ‘‘making
available’’ and ‘‘communication to the
public,’’ and also invited views on
specific issues raised during the public
roundtable held in Washington, DC on
May 5, 2014. To provide sufficient time
for commenters to respond, the Office is
extending the time for filing additional
comments from August 14, 2014 to
September 15, 2014.
Dated: July 28, 2014.
Karyn A. Temple Claggett,
Associate Register of Copyrights.
[FR Doc. 2014–18097 Filed 7–31–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 1410–30–P
1
Study on the Right of Making Available; Request
for Additional Comments, 79 FR 41309 (July 15,
2014).
c o p y r i g h t a n d t h e m u s i c m a r k e t p l a c e
appendix b commenting parties and
roundtable participants
u
. s . c o p y r i g h t o f f i c e
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Parties Who Responded to First Notice of Inquiry
1. ABKCO Music & Records, Inc. (ABKCO)
2. American Association of Independent Music (A2IM)
3. American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers (ASCAP)
4. Audiosocket
5. Barnett III, William
6. Brigham Young University Copyright Licensing Office
7. Broadcast Music, Inc. (BMI)
8. Camp, Ben
9. Center for Copyright Integrity
10. Castle, Christian L.
11. Cate, John
12. Consumer Federation of America (CFA) and Public Knowledge
13. Content Creators Coalition
14. Continental Entertainment Group
15. Copyright Alliance
16. Council of Music Creators
17. CTIA The Wireless Association (CTIA)
18. Digital Data Exchange, LLC (DDEX)
19. Digital Media Association (DiMA)
20. DotMusic
21. Educational Media Foundation (EMF)
22. Ferrick, Melissa
23. Future of Music Coalition (FMC)
1
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
24. Gear Publishing Company and Lisa Thomas Music Services, LLC
25. Geo Music Group & George Johnson Music Publishing
26. Global Image Works
27. Greco, Melanie Holland
28. Harris, Jim
29. Hayes, Bonnie
30. Henderson, Linda S.
31. Herstand, Ari
32. Indiana University, Archives of African American Music and Culture
33. Interested Parties Advancing Copyright (IPAC)
34. Jessop, Paul
35. Kohn, Bob
36. LaPolt, Dina
37. Library of Congress
38. Lincoff, Bennett
39. Lowery, David
40. McAuliffe Esq., Emmett
41. Menell, Peter S.
42. Mitchell, John T.
43. Modern Works Music Publishing
44. Music Choice
45. Music Library Association
46. Music Reports, Inc. (MRI)
47. National Academy of Recording Arts & Sciences (NARAS)
2
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
48. National Association of Broadcasters (NAB)
49. National Music Publishers' Association (NMPA) and Harry Fox Agency, Inc.
(HFA)
50. National Public Radio, Inc. (NPR)
51. National Religious Broadcasters Music License Committee (NRBMLC)
52. National Religious Broadcasters Noncommercial Music License Committee
(NRBNMLC)
53. National Restaurant Association
54. Nauman, Vickie
55. Newman Esq., Deborah
56. Netflix, Inc.
57. Novak, Adam
58. Pagnani, Aidan
59. Pala Rez Radio
60. Pattison, Pat
61. Public Knowledge and Consumer Federation of America (CFA)
62. Public Television Coalition (PTC)
63. Radio Music License Committee, Inc. (RMLC)
64. Recording Industry Association of America, Inc. (RIAA)
65. Robin Green, Lynne
66. Rys, Jason
67. Schlieman, Derek S.
68. Screen Actors Guild American Federation of Television and Radio Artists
(SAG-AFTRA) and American Federation of Musicians of the United States and
Canada (AFM)
69. SESAC, Inc. (SESAC)
3
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
70. Shocked, Michelle
71. Simpson, Jerrod
72. Sirius XM Radio Inc.
73. Society of Composers & Lyricists (SCL)
74. Songwriters Guild of America, Inc. (SGA)
75. SoundExchange, Inc.
76. Spotify USA Inc.
77. SRN Broadcasting
78. St. James, Charles
79. Television Music License Committee, LLC (TMLC)
80. Traugh, David
81. United States Marine Band
82. Willey, Robert
83. Wixen Music Publishing, Inc.
84. Yates, James M.
4
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Participants in Nashville Hearings
1. Barker, John (ClearBox Rights and IPAC)
2. Buresh, Heather (Music Row Administrators Group)
3. Chertkof, Susan (RIAA)
4. Coleman, Dan (Modern Music Works Publishing)
5. Driskill, Marc (Sea Gayle Music and AIMP, Nashville Chapter)
6. Earls, Kent (UMPG)
7. Gervais, Daniel (Vanderbilt University Law School)
8. Gottlieb, Tony (Get Songs Direct, LLC)
9. Herbison, Barton (NSAI)
10. Johnson, George (Geo Music Group and George Johnson Music Publishing)
11. Kass, Fritz (Intercollegiate Broadcasting System, Inc.)
12. Kimes, Royal Wade (Wonderment Records)
13. Knife, Lee (DiMA)
14. Marks, Steven (RIAA)
15. McIntosh, Bruce (Codigo Music and Fania Records)
16. Meitus, Robert (Meitus Gelbert Rose LLP)
17. Mosenkis, Sam (ASCAP)
18. Oxenford, David (Wilkinson Barker Knauer LLP)
19. Schaffer, Brittany (NMPA and Loeb & Loeb LLP)
20. Sellwood, Scott (Google and YouTube)
21. Soled, Janice (My Music Screen)
22. Stollman, Marc (Stollman Law, PA)
23. Turley-Trejo, Ty (Brigham Young University Copyright Licensing Office)
24. Waltz, Reid Alan (SESAC)
5
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Participants in Los Angeles Hearings
1. Anthony, Paul (Rumblefish)
2. Arrow, Ed (UMPG)
3. Barker, John (ClearBox Rights and IPAC)
4. Bernstein, Keith (Crunch Digital)
5. Blake, Lawrence J. (Concord Music Group, Inc.)
6. Bull, Eric D. (Create Law)
7. Cate, John (American Music Partners)
8. Cohan, Timothy A. (PeerMusic)
9. Goldberg, Ilene (IMG Consulting)
10. Greaves, Deborah (Label Law, Inc.)
11. Greenstein, Gary R. (Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati)
12. Harbeson, Eric (Music Library Association)
13. Hauth, Russell (Salem Communications and NRBMLC)
14. Irwin, Ashley (SCL)
15. Kokakis, David (UMPG)
16. Kossowicz, Tegan (UMG)
17. LaPolt, Dina (Dina LaPolt P.C.)
18. Lemone, Shawn (ASCAP)
19. Lipsztein, Leonardo (Google and YouTube)
20. Lord, Dennis (SESAC)
21. Marks, Steven (RIAA)
22. Menell, Peter (UC Berkeley School of Law)
23. Miller, Jennifer (Audiosocket)
24. Muddiman, Hélène (Hollywood Elite Composers)
6
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
25. Nauman, Vickie (CrossBorderWorks)
26. Prendergast, Brad (SoundExchange, Inc.)
27. Rudolph, John (Music Analytics)
28. Rys, Jason (Wixen Music Publishing, Inc.)
29. Sanders, Charles J. (SGA)
30. Schyman, Garry (SCL)
31. Watkins, Les (MRI)
7
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Participants in New York Hearings
1. Albert, Eric (Stingray Digital Group)
2. Badavas, Christos P. (HFA)
3. Barker, John (ClearBox Rights and IPAC)
4. Barron, Gregg (BMG Rights Management)
5. Bengloff, Richard (A2IM)
6. Bennett, Jeffrey (SAG-AFTRA)
7. Besek, June (Columbia Law School, Kernochan Center for Law, Media and the
Arts)
8. Carapella, Cathy (Global Image Works)
9. Carnes, Rick (SGA)
10. Coleman, Alisa (ABKCO)
11. Conyers III, Joe (Downtown Music Publishing)
12. DeFilippis, Matthew (ASCAP)
13. Diab, Waleed (Google and YouTube)
14. Donnelley, Patrick (Sirius XM Radio Inc.)
15. Duffett-Smith, James (Spotify USA Inc.)
16. Dupler, Todd (NARAS)
17. Fakler, Paul (NAB and Music Choice)
18. Finkelstein, Andrea (SME.)
19. Gibbs, Melvin (Content Creators Coalition)
20. Greer, Cynthia (Sirius XM Radio Inc.)
21. Griffin, Jodie (Public Knowledge)
22. Hoyt, Willard (TMLC)
23. Huey, Dick (Toolshed Inc.)
8
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
24. Kass, Fritz (Intercollegiate Broadcasting System, Inc.)
25. Knife, Lee (DiMA)
26. Kohn, Bob (Kohn on Music Licensing)
27. Lee, Bill (SESAC)
28. Lummel, Lynn (ASCAP)
29. Mahoney, Jim (A2IM)
30. Malone, William (Intercollegiate Broadcasting System, Inc.)
31. Marin, Aldo (Cutting Records, Inc.)
32. Marks, Steven (RIAA)
33. Merrill, Tommy (The Press House and #IRespectMusic)
34. Morgan, Blake (ECR Music Group and #IRespectMusic)
35. Potts, Cheryl (Crystal Clear Music & CleerKut)
36. Rae, Casey (FMC)
37. Raff, Andrew (Shutterstock, Inc.)
38. Raffel, Colin (Prometheus Radio Project)
39. Reimer, Richard (ASCAP)
40. Resnick, Perry (RZO, LLC)
41. Rich, Bruce (RMLC)
42. Rinkerman, Gary (Drinker, Biddle & Reath LLP)
43. Rosen, Stuart (BMI)
44. Rosenthal, Jay (NMPA)
45. Rushing, Colin (SoundExchange, Inc.)
46. Steinberg, Michael G. (BMI)
47. Wood, Doug (National Council of Music Creator Organizations)
9
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
Parties Who Responded to Second Notice of Inquiry
1. ABKCO Music & Records, Inc. (ABKCO)
2. American Association of Independent Music (A2IM)
3. American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers (ASCAP)
4. Bean, David
5. Broadcast Music, Inc. (BMI)
6. Buckley, William Jr.
7. Carapetyan, Gregory
8. Castle, Christian L.
9. Columbia Law School, Kernochan Center for Law, Media and the Arts
10. Computer & Communications Industry Association (CCIA)
11. Concord Music Group, Inc.
12. Content Creators Coalition
13. Deutsch, L. Peter
14. Digital Media Association (DiMA)
15. Future of Music Coalition (FMC)
16. Geo Music Group & George Johnson Music Publishing
17. Guyon, Cindy
18. Guyon, Rich
19. Interested Parties Advancing Copyright (IPAC)
20. LaPolt, Dina
21. Modern Works Music Publishing
22. Music Choice
23. Music Managers’ Forum (MMF) and Featured Artists' Coalition (FAC)
24. Music Reports, Inc. (MRI)
10
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
25. Nashville Songwriters Association International (NSAI)
26. National Academy of Recording Arts & Sciences (NARAS)
27. National Association of Broadcasters (NAB)
28. National Music Publishers' Association (NMPA) and Harry Fox Agency, Inc.
(HFA)
29. National Public Radio, Inc. (NPR)
30. Office of the County Attorney, Montgomery County, Maryland
31. Pangasa, Maneesh
32. Parker, Brad
33. Pilot Music Business Services, LLC
34. Pipeline Project 2014, Belmont University's Mike Curb College of Music Business
and Entertainment
35. Production Music Association (PMA)
36. Public Knowledge
37. Radio Music License Committee, Inc. (RMLC)
38. Recording Industry Association of America, Inc. (RIAA)
39. Resnick, Perry (RZO, LLC)
40. Righeimer, Carolyn
41. Rinkerman, Gary (Drinker, Biddle & Reath LLP)
42. Samuels, Jon M.
43. Screen Actors Guild American Federation of Television and Radio Artists
(SAG-AFTRA) and American Federation of Musicians of the United States and
Canada (AFM)
44. Sirius XM Radio Inc.
45. Songwriters Guild of America, Inc. (SGA)
46. SoundExchange, Inc.
47. Stone, Bob
11
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
48. Szajner, Robert
49. Television Music License Committee, LLC (TMLC)
50. U.S. Chamber of Commerce, Global Intellectual Property Center (GIPC)
51. Wager, Gregg
12
c o p y r i g h t a n d t h e m u s i c m a r k e t p l a c e
appendix c abbreviations
u
. s . c o p y r i g h t o f f i c e
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
ABBREVIATIONS
A2IM American Association of Independent Musicians
ABKCO ABKCO Music & Records, Inc.
AFM American Federation of Musicians of the United States and Canada
AHRA Audio Home Recording Act
AIMP Association of Independent Music Publishers
ASCAP American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers
BMI Broadcast Music, Inc.
BYU Brigham Young University Copyright Licensing Office
CARP Copyright Arbitration Royalty Panel
CCIA Computer & Communications Industry Association
CFA Consumer Federation of America
CISAC International Confederation of Societies of Authors and Composers
CRB Copyright Royalty Board
CRT Copyright Royalty Tribunal
CTIA CTIAThe Wireless Association
DDEX Digital Data Exchange, LLC
DiMA Digital Media Association
DMCA Digital Millenium Copyright Act
DOJ United States Department of Justice
DPD Digital phonorecord delivery
DPRSRA Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings Act
EMF Educational Media Foundation
EMI EMI Music Publishing Ltd.
FAC Featured ArtistsCoalition
FMC Future of Music Coalition
FTC United States Federal Trade Commission
1
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
GMR Global Music Rights
GMRO General music rights organization
GIPC U.S. Chamber of Commerce, Global Intellectual Property Center
GRD Global Repertoire Database
HFA Harry Fox Agency, Inc.
IFPI International Federation of the Phonographic Industry
IMR International Music Registry
ISNI International Standard Name Identifier
IPAC Interested Parties Advancing Copyright
IPI Interested Parties Information
ISO International Organization for Standardization
ISRC International Standard Recording Code
ISWC International Standard Musical Work Code
MMF Music ManagersForum
MRI Music Reports, Inc.
MRO Music rights organization
Music Biz Music Business Association
NAB National Association of Broadcasters
NARAS National Academy of Recording Arts & Sciences
NCTA National Cable & Telecommunications Association
NDMA New digital media agreement
NMPA National Music PublishersAssociation
NOI Notice of Intent
NPR National Public Radio, Inc.
NRBMLC National Religious Broadcasters Music License Committee
NRBNMLC National Religious Broadcasters Noncommercial Music License
Committee
2
U.S. Copyright Office Copyright and the Music Marketplace
NSAI Nashville Songwriters Association International
NTIA National Telecommunications and Information Administration
PPL Phonographic Performance Ltd.
PRO Performing rights organization
PTC Public Television Coalition
RESPECT Act Respecting Senior Performers as Essential Cultural Treasures Act
RMLC Radio Music License Committee, Inc.
RIAA Recording Industry Association of America, Inc.
SAG-AFTRA Screen Actors Guild-American Federation of Television and Radio Artists
SCL Society of Composers & Lyricists
SEA Songwriters Equity Act
SGA Songwriters Guild of America, Inc.
SIRA Section 115 Reform Act of 2006
SME Sony Music Entertainment, Inc.
Sony/ATV Sony/ATV Music Publishing LLC
SOCAN Society of Composers, Authors and Music Publishers of Canada
TMLC Television Music License Committee, LLC
UMG Universal Music Group
UMPG Universal Music Publishing Group
UPC Universal Product Code
USPTO U.S. Patent and Trademark Office
WIPO World Intellectual Property Organization
WMG Warner Music Group
3
c o p y r i g h t a n d t h e m u s i c m a r k e t p l a c e
appendix d licensing and ratesetting charts
u
. s . c o p y r i g h t o f f i c e
Sound recordings
record labels/artists
Reproduction and distribution
(mechanical) rights
Synch
rights,
etc.
Musical Work
Synch
rights,
etc.
Public
performance
rights for
digital
noninteractive
Publishers
directly or
through
labels
Statutory
notice
Copyright and the Music Marketplace:
Existing Licensing Framework
Public
performance
rights for
terrestrial
(AM/FM)
radio
No federal
performance
right
Labels
directly
Musical works
publishers/songwriters
Reproduction and
distribution rights,
and public
performance
rights for digital
interactive
Labels
directly
Public performance rights
Publishers
directly
Live
Traditional media
Traditional media
Downloads,
(TV, film, etc.)
(radio, TV, etc.)
interactive streaming,
and new media
and new media
CDs, etc.
(internet, etc.)
(internet, etc.)
Traditional
media
(TV, film, etc.)
and new media
(internet, etc.)
Downloads,
Internet and
interactive
satellite
streaming,
radio, etc.
CDs, etc.
Publishers
directly
Reproduction and distribution
(mechanical) and
public performance rights
Mechanical and
public performance
rights subject
to withdrawal
Synch
rights,
etc.
Public
performance
rights for digital
noninteractive
and terrestrial
Downloads
and interactive
streaming
Downloads,
interactive streaming,
CDs, etc.
Traditional media
(radio, TV, etc.)
and new media
(internet, etc.)
Traditional media
(TV, film, etc.)
and new media
(internet, etc.)
Live
Internet, satellite
and terrestrial
(AM/FM)
radio, etc.
MROs and GMRO
Labels
directly
Synch
rights,
etc.
Publishers
directly
Traditional media
(TV, film, etc.)
and new media
(internet, etc.)
Physical
products
(CDs, etc.)
Labels
directly
Reproduction and
distribution rights, and
public performance
rights for
digital interactive
Sound recordings
record labels/artists
Musical works
publishers/songwriters
Copyright and the Music Marketplace:
Proposed Licensing Framework
Sound recordings
record labels/artists
Works
subject to
ASCAP/BMI
consent
decrees
Reproduction and distribution
rights, public performance
rights for digital interactive,
synch rights, etc.
Public
performance
rights
Public performance
rights for digital
noninteractive
Satellite radio
and preexisting
subscription
services
Copyright Royalty Board
801(b)(1) factors
Willing buyer/
willing seller
Synch
rights, etc.
Reproduction and
distribution
(mechanical) rights
Works not
subject to
ASCAP/BMI
consent
decrees
Musical works
publishers/songwriters
Copyright and the Music Marketplace:
Existing Ratesetting Framework
Internet radio
and new
subscription
services
“Reasonable”
rate
Rates negotiated in the
free market
Federal district court
(rate courts)
Marketoriented standard
(e.g., willing buyer/willing seller)
Mechanical and public
performance rights
subject to withdrawal,
synch rights, etc.
Reproduction and
distribution rights,
public performance rights
for digital interactive,
synch rights, etc.
Sound recordings
record labels/artists
Musical works
publishers/songwriters
Copyright and the Music Marketplace:
Proposed Ratesetting Framework
Public performance rights for
noninteractive (internet,
satellite, and terrestrial
(AM/FM) radio, etc.)
Rates negotiated in the
free market
Reproduction and
distribution (mechanical)
and public performance
rights (MRO- and GMRO-
administered)
Copyright Royalty Board
(as needed)
u.s. copyright office · library of congress · 101 independence avenue se · washington, dc 20559-6000 · www.copyright.gov