Writing Economics
Robert Neugeboren with Mireille Jacobson
@2001 The President and Fellows of Harvard University (minor revisions in Jan. 2005)
Acknowledgments
This guide was proposed and supported by The Harvard Writing Proje ct.
Nancy Sommers, Sosland Director of Expository Writing, and Kerry Walk,
Assistant Director of the Writing Project, read drafts, gave advice, and saw
the project through from inception to completion. Kerry Walk wrote the
section on Formatting and Documentation (chapter 5). Christopher Foote,
Assistant Professor of Economics and Director of Undergraduate Studies,
wrote part of chapter 3 and commented on drafts of the whole work.
Oliver Hart, Michael Murray, Lorenzo Isla, Tuan Min Li, Allison Morantz,
and Stephen Weinberg also gave very helpful comments. Special thanks to
Mireille Jacobson, who compiled the appendices, added examples, and
revised and proofread the text. Thanks also to Anita Mortimer and the
Economics Tutorial Office.
Contents
1 Introduction | The Economic Approach
1 Economics and the Problem of Scarcity
2 The Assumption of Rationality
3 The Theory of Incentives
3 Writing Assignments in Economics 970
4 Plan of This Guide
5 One | Writing Economically
5 Getting Started
6 The Keys to Good Economics Writing
7 An Example from the Literature
8 Achieving Clarity
10 Managing Your Time
11 Two | The Language of Economic Analysis
11 Economic Models
12 Hypothesis Testing
13 Regression: An Example
14 Improving the Fit
14 Applying the Tools
16 Three | Finding and Researching Your Topic
16 Finding a Topic for a Term Paper
18 Finding and Using Sources
19 Doing a Periodical Search
19 Taking and Organizing Notes
21 Four | The Term Paper
21 Outlining Your Paper
22 Writing Your Literature Review
23 Presenting Your Hypothesis
24 Presenting Your Results / by Chris Foote
29 Discussing Your Results
30 Five | Formatting and Documentation / by Kerry Walk
30 Placing Citations in Your Paper
32 Listing Your References
34 Sample References Entries
44 Appendix A | Fields in Economics
47 Appendix B | Standard Statistical Sources
49 Appendix C | Electronic Indices to Periodical Literature
1 | Writing Economics
Introduction | The Economic Approach
Economists study everything from money and prices to child rearing and
the environment. They analyze small-scale decision-making and large-
scale international policy-making. They compile data about the past and
make predictions about the future. Many economic ideas have currency in
everyday life, cropping up in newspapers, magazines, and policy debates.
The amount you pay every month to finance a car or new home purchase
will depend on interest rates. Business people make investment plans
based on expectations of future demand, and policy makers devise
budgets to achieve a desired macroeconomic equilibrium.
Across the broad range of topics that interest economists is a unique
approach to knowledge, something common to the way all economists
see the world. Economists share certain assumptions about how the
economy works, and they use standard methods for analyzing data and
communicating their ideas. The purpose of this guide is to help you to
think and write like an economist.
ECONOMICS AND THE PROBLEM OF SCARCITY
Since its beginnings as “the dismal science,” economics has been
preoccupied with the problem of scarcity. The hours in a day, the money in
one’s pocket, the food the ground can supply are all limited; spending
resources on one activity necessarily comes at the expense of some other,
foregone opportunity. Scarcity provides economics with its central
problem: how to make choices in the context of constraint.
Accordingly, economists ask questions such as: How does a consumer
choose a bundle of commodities, given her income and prices? How does
a country choose to meet its objectives, given its national budget? How do
decision-makers allocate scarce resources among alternative activities
with different uses?
While this central economic problem may be rather narrow, the range
of topics that interest economists is vast. Indeed, insofar as it can be
characterized as choice under constraint, any kind of behavior falls within
2 | Writing Economics
the scope of economic analysis. As Lord Lionel Robbins (1984), one of the
great economists of the twentieth century, put it:
We do not say that the production of potatoes is economic activity and
the production of philosophy is not. We say rather that, in so far as
either kind of activity involves the relinquishment of other desired
alternatives, it has its economic aspect. There are no limitations on the
subject matter of Economic Science save this.
It should come as no surprise that economists are sometimes called
“imperialists” by other social scientists for their encroachment on fields
that traditionally belong to other disciplines. For instance, historians
studying the migration patterns of eighteenth-century European peasants
have explained the movement out of the countryside and into the cities in
terms of broad social and cultural factors: the peasants were subjects of
changing times, swept along by the force of history. By contrast,
economists, such as Samuel L. Popkin (1979), have attributed urban
migration patterns to the trade-offs faced and choices made by individual
actors; from this perspective, the behavior of these peasants was rational.
THE ASSUMPTION OF RATIONALITY
Economists approach a wide range of topics with the assumption that the
behavior under investigation is best understood as if it were rational
(though we know that not all behavior is, in fact, rational) and that the
best explanations, models and theories we construct take rationality as
the norm. Rationality, in the words of Frank Hahn, is the “weak causal
proposition” that sets all economic analyses in motion. “Economics can be
distinguished from other social sciences by the belief that most (all?)
behavior can be explained by assuming that agents have stable, well-
defined preferences and make rational choices consistent with those
preferences” (Colin Camerer and Richard Thaler, 1995).
Rationality, in the standard sense of the economist, means that agents
prefer more of what they want to less. This may seem like a rather strong
proposition, insofar as it seems to imply that human behavior is
necessarily calculated and self-interested. But the assumption of
rationality does not imply anything about the content of agents’ wants, or
preferences; hence to be rational is not necessarily to be selfish. One can
want others to be better off and rationally pursue this objective as well.
Economists assume that whatever their preferences, agents will attempt
to maximize their satisfaction subject to the constraints they face. And
good economics writing will take the assumption of rational behavior as
its starting point.
3 | Writing Economics
THE THEORY OF INCENTIVES
The theory of incentives posits that individual agents, firms, or people,
make decisions by comparing costs and benefits. When costs or benefits
the constraints on choices change, behavior may also change. In other
words, agents respond to incentives.
Many recent developments in economics and public policy are based
on the theory of incentives. For example, recent welfare reforms recognize
that traditional welfare, which guarantees a basic level of income but is
taken away once that level is surpassed, provides incentives for those
below the earnings threshold to stay out of the formal workforce. This and
other criticisms have led to the adoption and expansion of programs such
as the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC). The EITC seeks to rectify this
particular incentive problem by making transfers only to working
individuals. Such policy changes suggest that incentives matter for
behavior. Thus, a thorough analysis of any behavior, and a well-written
account of it, must account for incentive effects.
WRITING ASSIGNMENTS IN ECONOMICS 970
In Sophomore Tutorial (Economics 970), you will receive several writing
assignments including a term paper, an empirical exercise, short essays,
response papers, and possibly a rewrite. Below is a description of these
types:
Term Paper (1015pp.). In all tutorials , you will be required to write a
term paper that addresses a topic in depth and combines skills
developed throughout the semester. It usually builds on earlier short
assignments, including a prospectus, in which you will propose a
thesis or question and detail how the issue will be addressed. This
term paper may require research beyond what has been assigned to
the group. It typically includes a literature review, an empirical
component, a discussion of results, and perhaps a discussion of policy
implications.
Empirical Exercise (56pp.). All tutorials also assign some kind of
empirical exercise in which you will analyze economic data using a
standard statistical software package (such as STATA). The empirical
exercise will give you experience in answering an economic question
with data and/or drawing conclusions from evidence.
Short Essays (46pp.). Short essays may require you to analyze two
articles and compare their policy implications, explain a model,
criticize an argument, present a case study, extend a theory, evaluate
an intellectual debate and so on.
Response Papers (12pp.). Response papers might involve
summarizing the weekly readings or answering a specific question
about the text. These will help get you thinking and stimulate class
4 | Writing Economics
discussion. They can also build the skills needed for writing successful
longer papers.
Make sure you clear up any confusion about the assignment by asking
your tutor specific questions about what he or she is looking for. The
earlier you get clarification, the be tter able you will be to complete the
assignment (and get a good grade). For longer papers, you may want to
hand in rough drafts. Getting feedback may improve your writing
considerably and generally makes for more interesting papers.
PLAN OF THIS GUIDE
Understanding the way economists see the world is a necessary step on
the way to good economics writing. Chapter 1 describes the keys you need
to succeed as a writer of economics and offers an overview of the writing
process from beginning to end. Chapter 2 describes the basic methods
economists use to analyze data and communicate their ideas. Chapter 3
offers suggestions for finding and focusing your topic, including standard
economic sources and techniques for doing economic research. Chapter 4
tells you how to write a term paper. Finally, Chapter 5 provides a guide to
citing sources and creating a bibliography. Three appendices provide
useful information for developing your term papers. Appendix A provides
a roadmap of fields in economics and can help define very broad areas of
interest. Appendix B lists some standard statistical sources that you may
wish to use for your own research and appendix C lists the relevant
electronic indices to periodical literature, invaluable resources for the
initial stages of any paper.
5 | Writing Economics
One | Writing Economically
Pick up any publication of the American Economics Association and you
will discover a few things about writing economics. First, the discourse is
often mathematical, with lots of formulas, lemmas, and proofs. Second,
writing styles vary widely. Some authors are very dry and technical; a few
are rather eloquent.
You don’t have to be a great “writer” to produce good economics
writing. This is because economics writing is different from many other
types of writing. It is essentially technical writing, where the goal is not to
turn a clever phrase, hold the reader in suspense, or create multi-layered
nuance, but rather to achieve clarity. Elegant prose is nice, but clarity is
the only style that is relevant for our purposes. A clear presentation will
allow the strength of your underlying analysis and the quality of your
research to shine through.
If you’ve ever pulled an all-nighter and done reasonably well on the
assignment, you may be tempted to rely on your ability to churn out
pages of prose late at night. This is not a sensible strategy. Good
economics papers just don’t “happen” without time spent on preparation;
you cannot hide a lack of research, planning and revising behind carefully
constructed prose. More time will produce better results, though returns
to effort will be diminishing at some point. Here, too, the principles of
economy apply.
GETTING STARTED
Getting started is often the hardest part of writing. The blank page or
screen can bring on writer’s block, and sustaining an argument through
many pages can seem daunting, particularly when you know your work
will be graded. Don’t let these concerns paralyze you; break the paper
down into smaller parts, and get started on the simpler tasks. Economics
writing usually requires a review of the relevant literature (more on this
later). Especially if you’re stuck, this can be a great way to begin.
6 | Writing Economics
THE KEYS TO GOOD ECONOMICS WRITING
Writing in economics, as in any academic discipline, is never simply a
matter of asserting your opinions. While your ideas are important, your
job includes establishing your credentials as a writer of economics, by
demonstrating your knowledge of economic facts and theories, identify-
ing and interpreting the underlying economic models, understanding
what others have said about the relevant issues, evaluating the available
evidence and presenting a persuasive argument. Even if you don’t write
particularly well, you can produce good economics papers by attending to
three basic tasks:
Research
Economic research often entails pouring over reams of data from any of a
number of standard statistical sources (see appendix B). For some assign-
ments, you will want to begin your paper with a review of the literature
on the topic. For a term paper, this might entail an exhaustive library
search (see appendix C); for other assignments, you may need to reference
only a single paper your instructor has assigned. In general, your writing
will reflect the quality of your research, and good writing will demon-
strate that you understand the findings that are relevant to your topic.
Organization
Once you have found your sources, you will need to organize your ideas
and outline your paper. Economists usually organize their writing by using
simplified models (such as supply and demand, cost/benefit analysis and
comparative advantage). Therefore, a literature review is often followed
by the presentation of a model, usually one of the standard models or, for
the theoretically inclined, one of your own devising. Models are used to
organize data and generate hypotheses about how some aspect of the
economy works.
Analysis
Reducing something complex into simpler parts is an integral part of
economic rigor. Statistical analysis (or econometrics) takes vast piles of
data and returns useful numerical summaries that can be used to test
various economic models and make predictions about the future.
Mathematics is very helpful here because it is a precise language that can
articulate the way basic economic relations are conceptualized, measured
and defined. Nonetheless, even before you have mastered sophisticated
statistical and mathematical techniques, your goals should be writing
clearly, following a line of deductive reasoning to its conclusion and
applying the rules of inference correctly. These are the marks of good
economics writing.
7 | Writing Economics
AN EXAMPLE FROM THE LITERATURE
Generally, in the first few paragraphs of a paper, economists set up their
research question as well as the model and data they use to think about
it. This style can be useful to both writer and reader as it establishes the
structure of the work that follows. Unfortunately, it sometimes means a
stilted or dry presentation. An excerpt from a piece by two of the field’s
most eloquent authors, Claudia Goldin and Lawrence F. Katz (1996),
illustrates a skillful approach to setting up a research question, placing it
in the literature and outlining how the work to follow extends existing
research. Notice, in particular, that these steps need not be completely
independent.
The piece, taken from the authors’ work on the historical relationship
between technology, human capital, and the wage structure, starts by
presenting the facts motivating the question:
Recent technological advances and a widening of the wage structure
have led many to conclude that technology and human capital are
relative complements. The possibility that such a relationship exists
today has prompted a widely held conjecture that technology and skill
have always been relative complements.
Next they explain the existing theories behind this relationship:
According to this view, technological advance always serves to widen
the wage structure, and only large injections of education slow its
relentless course. A related literature demonstrates that capital and
skill are relative complements today and in the recent past (Zvi
Griliches, 1969). Thus capital deepening appears also to have increased
the relative demand for the educated, serving further to stretch the
wage structure.
Then they clearly and simply state their question:
Physical capital and technology are now regarded as the relative
complements of human capital, but have they been so for the past two
centuries?
Next they cite more of the related literature:
Some answers have already been provided. A literature has emerged
on the bias to technological change across history that challenges the
view that physical capital and human capital have always been relative
complements.
Finally they propose how they seek to answer this question:
8 | Writing Economics
We argue that capital-skill complementarity was manifested in the
aggregate economy as particular technologies spread, specifically
batch and continuous process methods of production.
Their paper goes on to establish the empirical evidence that backs up
this assertion. As evide nced by the example above, the clarity of your
prose, the quality of your research, the organization of your argument,
and the rigor of your analysis are the keys to your success as an economics
writer.
ACHIEVING CLARITY
Clear writing is easy to read but hard to write. It rarely occurs without
considerable effort and a willingness to revise and rework. As McCloskey
(1985), the dean of economics writing, tells us: “it is good to be brief in
the whole essay and in the single word, during the midnight fever of
composition and during the morning chill of revision” (McCloskey, 1985).
The rules of clear writing apply to the organization of the entire paper, to
the order of paragraphs, to sentences and to words. Few writers achieve
clarity without continual editing. Once you have your basic ideas down, be
sure to reread and revise your work.
Clarity can be achieved in stages:
Organize your ideas into an argument with the help of an outline.
Define the important terms you will use.
State your hypothesis and proceed deductively to reach your
conclusions.
Avoid excess verbiage.
Edit yourself, remove what is not needed, and keep revising until you
get down to a simple, efficient way of communicating.
This last stage is crucial. Take, for example, the following excerpt from a
student’s short response paper:
In the beginning of the 1980’s, the problem of homelessness in the
United States became apparent (Richard B. Freeman and Brian Hall,
1989). Since then, the number of homeless in this country has
continued to grow. While the problem of homelessness, in itself, is
obviously a problem that is quite relevant to other fields of economic
study, it has also given rise to a phenomenon that is an interesting
topic for the study of behavioral economics: the donation of money to
help the homeless population.
With a little revision, the author could have achieved a more clear and
concise introduction:
9 | Writing Economics
Early in the 1980’s, increasing homelessness in the United States
became apparent (Freeman and Hall, 1989). Since then, the number of
homeless has continued to grow. While homelessness is studied in
many fields of economics, it has given rise to a particular phenomenon
the donation of money directly to the homeless that interests
behavioral economists in particular.
Below are some additional tips to achieving clarity and some examples
that apply them. These and many other useful tips can be found in Strunk
and White (1979).
Use the Active Voice
It turns a weak statement (first one) into a more direct assertion (second
statement):
In this paper, the effect of centralized wage-setting institutions on the
industry distribution of employment is studied.
This paper studies the effect of centralized wage-setting institutions
on the industry distribution of employment.
Put Statements in Positive Form
Many day-traders did not pay attention to the warnings of experts.
This statement is more concisely conveyed as follows:
Many day-traders ignored the warnings of experts.
Omit Needless Words
In spite of the fact that the stock market is down, many experts feel
that financial markets may perform reasonably well this quarter.
A better way to express the same thing is:
Although the stock market is down, financial markets may still
perform reasonably well this quarter.
In Summaries, Generally Stick to One Tense
This study showed that dividend payouts increase when dividend
income was less tax-disadvantaged relative to capital gains.
An improvement uses the present tense throughout:
10 | Writing Economics
This study shows that dividend payouts increase when dividend
income is less tax-disadvantaged relative to capital gains.
MANAGING YOUR TIME
The best laid plans for writing a good paper can be wrecked by poor time
management. Make sure you clear up any confusion about the
assignment right away. Set deadlines for completing each phase of the
project:
Start the project by finding your topic.
Begin your research.
Start an outline.
Write a draft.
Revise and polish.
Divide your time, from the moment you receive your assignment to the
moment it is due, into segments allotted to each task. Hold yourself to the
deadlines you set, and allow yourself time to revise and polish the paper.
The payoff will be a better product, a better grade and less anxiety
throughout.
11 | Writing Economics
Two | The Language of Economic Analysis
The economy is a complex web of interdependent elements, and
understanding any part is a significant accomplishment. The price of tea
in the US is determined by many factors, including individual preferences
(or tastes), labor costs, weather conditions and the price of tea in China,
among others. Preferences, labor costs, weather, etc. are in turn connected
to other factors, including the price of coffee, which in turn can affect the
price of tea. All the parts can be moving simultaneously, making it hard to
see what is causing what.
To write effectively about economics, you have to understand how
economists think about such complicated phenomena. In general, to
make their task easier, economists focus on and try to isolate simple
causal connections, often between two variables ceteris paribus, or “other
things being equal.” “Other things being equal,” what is the effect of a
change in labor costs on the price of tea? “Other things being equal,” how
does a change in the price of coffee affect the price of tea?
This kind of analysis allows economists to say something very precise
about well-defined relationships and to run rigorous tests to measure the
strength and direction of their connections. Of course, focusing on just
one relationship at a time means other relationships are artificially held
constant, so that our analyses necessarily diverge from reality. They are
hypothetical. But simplification and abstraction are necessary ingredients
of any theoretical enterprise, and a good economist knows the real world
is more complex.
ECONOMIC MODELS
Economic analysis is characterized by the use of models, simplified
representations of how economic phenomena work. Supply and demand,
cost/benefit analysis and comparative advantage are examples of basic
economic models. A model is a theory rendered in precise, usually
mathematical, terms. Economists build models the way curious scientists
do: Reduce the phenomenon to its basic elements and recombine these
elements so as to produce a model that resembles the original in relevant
12 | Writing Economics
respects. Take it apart, figure out how it works, then put it back together
and see if it goes.
Economic models specify relationships between two kinds of variables:
exogenous variables and endogenous variables (Gregory N. Mankiw,
1997). Exogenous variable s are inputs to the model, factors that influence
what happens but are themselves determined “outside” the model. They
are givens, fixed values that are assumed not to change over the period of
analysis. Endogenous variables are outputs of the model, determined
“within.” Usually, a mathematical function is used to represent the
relationship between exogenous and endogenous variables. Systems of
relationships, in which changes in one part of the economy have different
consequences in others, are often conveniently represented by systems of
functions. For example, we can model the market for compact discs (CDs)
in terms of three functions:
The quantity of CDs demanded depends (negatively) on the price of
CDs and (positively) on income (Y): Q
d
= D(P
CD
, Y).
The quantity of CDs supplied depends (positively) on the price of
plastic (because CDs are made from plastic) and on the price of CDs:
Q
s
= S(P
CD
, P
P
).
In equilibrium, the quantity of CDs supplied equals the quantity
demanded: Q
d
= Q
s
.
In this model, the price of plastic and the level of income are
exogenous variables; the price of CDs and the quantity of CDs exchanged
are endogenous variables. By plugging data (exogenous variables) into the
model, it is possible to predict the behavior of the endogenous variables,
thus generating hypotheses about phenomena that have not yet been
observed.
Applying basic models allows one to make predictions about the real
world economy, both forward-looking predictions about, say, future
interest rates and backward-looking predictions about, say, the savings
rate during the depression. Models also provide guidance about where to
look for and how to look at data, and they provide a structure on which
the rest of the paper can hang.
HYPOTHESIS TESTING
A model’s predictions about the future or the past are essentially
empirical hypotheses: claims, supported by facts, about how some
economic phenomenon works. Most economists, aspiring to be good
social scientists, would like to test their hypotheses under laboratory
conditions. But this is not ordinarily possible. Instead, we take sample
13 | Writing Economics
data from the real world, by looking at census reports, balance sheets and
the like, and we use statistical methods to test the predictive power of our
models and the hypotheses they generate.
Most economic data come in, or can be easily transformed into,
numerical terms. Prices and quantities are numbers, and economists also
attach numerical measurements to factors such as standards of living
that do not usually come in quantified form. But a long list of numbers is
just that until a relationship among them can be specified that imparts
some order. By building and using models, economists are able to focus on
simple, sometimes subtle, relationships in the data and explain the causal
links at work. Finding the pattern in the data allows one to say something
about how the economy works. A set of well-known models can greatly
simplify the task of organizing and communicating your ideas. But the
real test of a model is how well it helps us understand the workings of the
economy.
REGRESSION: AN EXAMPLE
Say, for instance, you are interested in explaining the causes of inflation.
You study the literature and learn about a connection between the level of
economic activity and the level of inflation. You formulate a simple
hypothesis:
Hypothesis: High levels of employment lead to high levels of inflation.
Observations: Monthly employment (X) and inflation rates (Y) in the
US from 19801995. (Two lists of 12x16 = 192 observations)
Regression: Y = a + bX + c. b measures the correlation between X and Y.
If b is positive and statistically significant, the hypothesis cannot be
rejected. (a is a constant; c is an error term.)
In order to run such a regression you will need a fairly large number of
observations. Without enough data you may not be able to decide
between this and the alternative, or null, hypothesis (i.e., high levels of
employment have no relationship to high levels of inflation) by statistical
measures alone. In such cases, there may be better ways to do an
empirical exercise (e.g. case study; experimental methods).
Even with enough data, statistical analyses show correlation, not
causation. A model is needed to explain how things work for instance,
how high levels of employment lead to high levels of inflation.
14 | Writing Economics
IMPROVING THE FIT
The fit between a model and reality is never perfect. When the fit is good,
we can make better predictions about the future and better understand
the past. In the former case, the passage of time will fail to disconfirm the
prediction; in the latter case, historical research will match our
expectations. As in any science, our theories can really only be disproved.
However, when our predictions are correct, the weight we place on our
models increases. When our predictions are wrong, we are left either
looking for more data or perhaps a new or revised model. That model may
be used to generate new predictions, which can then be confronted with
new data, which may again bring disconfirmation of the prediction and
suggest a revision of the current model.
APPLYING THE TOOLS
Most of the writing done in economics involves the application of old
models to new data, with the goal of better understanding some real
world economic phenomenon. This may or may not involve analyzing a
large dataset. This example, taken from an Ec 970 term paper, applies
economic tools namely, game theoretic analysis to one particular
issue, the role of international institutions in the post Cold War era:
The purpose of this paper is to discuss the continuing role of NATO and
the likelihood of lasting cooperation among the organization’s
member states in a post-Cold War world. Game theory and the study
of strategic interactions, although initially devised as a tool for
understanding Cold War motives and actions, nevertheless are
extremely applicable to a post-Cold War environment. I therefore plan
to incorporate several relevant international relations issues into a
game theoretical perspective first to discuss the cooperation that
actually occurred in NATO since the 1940s, and then to explain why
similar cooperation may be unlikely among security-based regimes
after the collapse of the Soviet Union.
Another kind of writing, the theory paper, involves criticizing the
models we use and proposing better ones. The goal of the theory paper is
to improve the conceptual underpinnings of the particular analytical tools
we use to understand the actual economy. This may be a better model of
how firms behave in uncertain market conditions, or a new way to
measure the level of national economic activity, or a synthesis of existing
theories to produce a new, more general theory.
Because all economic models are crude approximations of a complex
world, it is necessary to assess just how crude the approximations are
before we can say which model better fits the data. Interpreting statistics
and determining what can and cannot be reliably inferred given the
15 | Writing Economics
observations available requires knowledge of economic theory as well as a
healthy dose of mathematics. Mathematical logic is also used to build
new models, both to formalize the logical structure of the model and to
test for its coherence and internal consistency. The mathematics of model
building does not involve numbers, but it does specify quantities
(quantifiers) and uses well-defined operators to combine (sets of)
propositions.
Economic theory was not always so mathematical. And the
mathematization of economic theory has had costs as well as benefits.
The benefits are that, in many cases, more can be said quickly and
precisely, because mathematics is a powerful language and convenient
shorthand. The cost is that not all relevant phenomena are easily cast in
mathematical terms or can be only crudely captured mathematically.
Another cost is that economic theory becomes somewhat less accessible
to students and to the world at large, in which public policy debates are
conducted.
16 | Writing Economics
Three | Finding and Researching Your Topic
Economists view the world through the lens of efficiency, starting from
the assumption that individuals behave rationally and focusing on the
problem of allocating scarce resources. From this common analytical
perspective, economists study a wide range of topics, involving the
behavior of individuals, organizations and nations. The economic
approach can be applied so broadly that choosing a topic to write on can
be difficult. Indeed, once you start looking at the world through the eyes
of an economist, almost anything can be analyzed in terms of choice
under constraint.
Your own research has to meet the terms of the assignment as well as
the time and other constraints you face. You may need to read books and
journal articles in the library or pore over data sets on a computer. In
either case, you will need a topic before you can begin. If your instructor
gives you a list of topics, a review of related research may help you choose
among them. If the research question is entirely up to you, a literature
search is often not the best way to begin. Immersing yourself in the
literature before you have found a topic may convince you that all the
interesting questions have already been tackled. At the very least,
literature searches should be guided by very general topic ideas.
FINDING A TOPIC FOR A TERM PAPER
Though there is no one way to find a topic, thinking of the issues that
interest you is a great place to begin. While the range of possible topics is
large, there are some well-defined fields in economics, and your own
interests are likely to fit into one of these (see Appendix A for an
annotated list of fields). Course materials, textbooks, handouts, and so on
are obvious and convenient places to look, especially since your topic will
most likely have to pertain to the course subject. But reading the
newspaper and keeping an eye on current events can be even more
helpful. Once you have a general idea, you should go to the literature and
see how economists have tried thinking about it.
17 | Writing Economics
For example, say your interest is piqued by recent shootings in both
schools and workplaces. What role has the availability of guns played in
these events? What are the effects of banning guns? Implementing
tougher gun control laws? Though this might initially strike you as a
government or law project, many of the underlying issues are
fundamentally economic gun control measures explicitly place limits on
supply and attempt to put guns in disfavor or reduce demand. Once you
have identified guns and gun control as an area of interest, do your
literature search (more on this later). Pick out the relevant articles and
scour them for content as well as for additional sources. Try to narrow
down your topic. Have the authors pointed out any future research areas?
Are there any issues that you think have not been fully addressed?
In addition to finding something that interests you, you will also need
a project that can be done within the parameters of the assignment (for
example, length, due date, access to research materials). If the topic
doesn’t interest you, you probably won’t put in the effort needed to do a
good job or ask the right questions along the way. On the other hand, a
profoundly interesting topic may not be manageable given the time and
other constraints that you face.
As another example say you are interested in the stock market and
want to know what determines stock prices. From basic economic theory,
you know that prices are determined by supply and demand, but what
specific relationships do you need to study and what data do you need to
gather? You think about it for a while and realize there are many parts to
your question. What determines the price of a particular company’s stock
is a different question from what determines the level of stock prices in
general (as measured by Dow Jones or another index), though the two
may be related. And what determined stock prices yesterday might be
different from what explains changes in stock prices in the future. Each of
these questions could be the subject of an interesting paper. Your original
topic was overly broad; you should focus on a single, manageable
question.
Get started on your research even if you don’t have a precise topic; it
will evolve along the way. The question you begin with may become less
interesting, and something new may draw your attention. You may be
persuaded by an argument you encounter or find data that pose a
problem you hadn’t considered. You may find no data on one topic and a
goldmine on another. Shaping your topic in this way is perfectly fine, but
don’t get trapped in an endless maze of new, or just slightly revised,
topics. You want your search to converge on a manageable topic in a
reasonable amount of time. Find a question you can answer and begin
your work.
18 | Writing Economics
FINDING AND USING SOURCES
All academic writing involves the use of source materials. Archaeologists
look in the ground for artifacts, about which volumes of research may
subsequently appear. Biologists look through microscopes and write up
the laboratory experiments they perform. Historians study documents;
sociologists interview subjects . . .
Economic research typically begins with a (large) set of numerical data
say, a list of per capita incomes for every country in the UN or the history
of daily closing prices for shares of XYZ Corporation over the last year. In
these long lists of numbers, economists look for patterns, or regularities,
that reveal some underlying relationship between economic variables and
help explain how some part of the economy works. A data set could
include hundreds or thousands of entries; thus, statistical tools are used
to summarize this information and ease your job of communicating with
your audience. The mean of a large set of numbers conveys important
information in a compact form. Knowing the standard deviation and
other statistical measures can also be helpful when describing the
population under investigation and presenting the results of your
research.
Economic sources come in two types. The first is empirical data: facts
about the real world that come in, or can be easily converted into,
numerical form (for example, prices, quantities, income levels). The second
is academic literature: books or articles that you read in the library that
can help you organize your ideas and make sense of the heaps of data you
have accumulated.
In general you will not have the time or resources to go into the field
and compile your own data administer questionnaires, study individual
balance sheets, budgets, etc. Instead, you will rely on others to collect
your data, including other economists as well as demographers, auditors
and “official” statisticians. These data are compiled in a number of
standard secondary sources, such as the Economic Report of the President
and the Statistical Abstract of the United States. These volumes and
others (see Appendix B) contain detailed information on public and
private spending, wage and tax rates, and work force size and education
levels, as well as other information grouped by states, industries and
nations. Economists frequently begin their research with these sources;
they will either point you to the proper primary source or contain the
precise data you need for your paper.
You will also want to look at academic journals and other scholarly
literature on your topic. Using scholarly sources will allow you to invoke
the authority of experts in the field to sanction your ana lysis or to
establish the point of departure for your own original contribution. You
need to become familiar with what others have thought and written so
that you can communicate your findings in terms your audience will
recognize. Perhaps you will apply a standard model found in the literature
19 | Writing Economics
to new evidence or compare two models and see which does a better job
explaining the data you have found.
These works will also point you to additional sources. Bibliographies,
citations and footnotes may reveal a single, seminal forerunner. Read it. If
you come across a “review” or “survey” article, you have hit the jackpot. It
will contain an authoritatively complete summary of the literature in the
field.
DOING A PERIODICAL SEARCH
Periodical literature was once indexed in cumbersome hardbound
volumes. Nowadays, there are a number of very useful electronic indices
available on-line and updated frequently. Most are publicly available on
the internet, although some reside on the college’s proprietary system.
Appendix C describes those sources that are used most frequently by
economists.
Depending on the service you’re using, your search can be very deep,
including title, author and subject as well as abstracts, tables of contents
and related topic fields. This makes electronic searching far more
powerful than anything that could be done just a few years ago. Once you
find a relevant article, look at the abstract. Check a few more items and
retrieve from the shelves whatever looks interesting and useful.
TAKING AND ORGANIZING NOTES
The books, articles charts and tables strewn before you are the objects of
your research, the evidence you will marshal to support your argument.
Your first encounter with your sources should be carefully recorded: you
should document your findings and give proper credit to the sources you
use.
First, take down the complete bibliographic record:
Author(s) or Editor (s)
Title
Journal Volume Number
Date Pages
For the Goldin and Katz (1996) example used in chapter 1, your notes
would look as follows:
Goldin, Claudia and Katz, Lawrence F.
“Technology, Skill and the Wage Structure: Insights from the Past
American Economic Review, 86 (2)
May 1996. pp. 252–257
20 | Writing Economics
Keep a file of notes on each article you read. This should include the
main points of the article and any important results. Make sure to clearly
set off direct quotations by using quotation marks. Avoid paraphrasing,
because it will be difficult to separate the original wording from your own
later on. You can add your own comments afterwards, but it is important
to keep an accurate record of your first encounter with the source.
Taking good notes will accomplish several things. First, you will have
all your references at hand when you are writing the paper, so you won’t
have to go searching for a quote or chart when you’re in your dorm room
and the article you need is in the library. Second, you will leave a clear
record for your readers to follow, so that they can go to the originals for
more information or to see the facts for themselves. Finally, you will leave
signposts for yourself so that you can know where you have been and
separate your own ideas and results from those you found in your sources.
This will help you avoid plagiarizing, which can happen inadvertently as
your own ideas blur into what you have “learned” from others. The
unacknowledged use of another writer’s words or ideas is plagiarism,
whether intended or not. Poor note taking and sloppy documentation
mechanics can lead to plagiarism, but such mistakes are easy to correct
and avoid.
Start taking notes right away. A word processor can make things
easier, but even if you use pen and paper, try to develop good note-taking
habits from the outset. Create a note file for each source you find. Group
your notes by topic, alphabetically, chronologically or otherwise. As you
organize them, add comments and summaries, pick out important
themes and focus on issues for further research. These notes should help
motivate your project by shaping the analytical model used and, through
your summaries, form the beginnings of a good literature review.
21 | Writing Economics
Four | The Term Paper
You have chosen your topic, done your research, and settled on your ideas,
and now you have to write the paper. If you have done your job properly
up to now, you should have a topic, some data and plenty of notes on
things you have read. Now your task is to decide how to focus your
question and ideas, assemble the pieces into a structure that hangs
together and present an argument others will find persuasive.
Remember: writing is a process. Start with a few lines, perhaps just
section headings, and then build up detail and flesh out your analysis. The
key to the process is not to become too rigid too soon. While you want
enough structure to get started, you also want to allow the overall shape
of your paper to evolve somewhat along the way.
OUTLINING YOUR PAPER
The outline for your term paper is the agenda you set for the things you
want to accomplish. A good term paper will ask an interesting question
and offer a plausible answer. It should be plausible in that it is (probably)
true, but also not obviously or patently true; and it should be supportable
in that it is subject to factual observation or logical demonstration
(Gordon Harvey, Harvard Writing Program).
No matter what your field or topic, there is a fairly standard set of
things you want to accomplish in the paper:
Introduction: Pose an interesting question or problem
Literature Review: Survey the literature on your topic
Methods/Data: Formulate your hypothesis and describe your data
Results: Present your results with the help of graphs and charts
Discussion: Critique your method and/or discuss any policy
implications
Conclusions: Summarize what you have done; pose questions for
further research
22 | Writing Economics
Not every assignment will require all of these parts, but your term paper
will impress your reader if you have done a good job on most of them. You
might want to write the introduction and conclusions after you have
completed the body of the paper. Few points are given for subtlety or
surprise. You should prepare your audience for what you are going to do,
then do it, then summarize what you have done.
WRITING YOUR LITERATURE REVIEW
Depending on your assignment, preparing a literature review might entail
an exhaustive library search or referencing the single paper your
instructor has assigned. You should have notes, either on index cards or in
files on your computer, on the books and articles you have read. Read over
your summaries and comments and begin to look for common themes
that can organize your review. What is the main point of the article, and
how does it relate to your topic? Do other authors offer a similar position?
An opposing one?
As you think through these questions, keep in mind that the literature
review has two functions. The first is simply to demonstrate your
familiarity with scholarly work on your topic to provide a survey of what
you have read, trace the development of important themes and draw out
any tensions in prior research. The second function is to lay the founda-
tions for your paper, to provide motivation. The particular issues you
intend to raise, the terms you will employ and the approach you will take
should be defined with reference to previous scholarly works. By drawing
on such sources, you can find sanction for your own approach and invoke
the authority of those who have written on the topic before you.
In some instances, these two functions will pull in opposite directions:
the first toward including as many sources as possible, the second toward
selecting only those that are useful for your argument. In any case, more
research is better than less, and a summary is always selective, insofar as
only some things can be included and others left out. The selections you
make will necessarily reflect your own interests and, hopefully, lead the
reader to take an interest in the argument you will present.
For example, Martin Feldstein begins his article “Social Security,
Induced Retirement and Aggregate Capital Accumulation” (1974) with a
discussion of the development of economists’ thinking on lifetime savings
patterns. He starts with a famous early work in the field:
Ever since Harrod’s (1948) discussion of “hump savings,” economists
have recognized the importance of saving during working years for
consumption during retirement (p. 906).
“Hump-savings” refers to the shape of an individual’s savings curve over
time: low at the beginning, higher in the middle, lower at the end. This
23 | Writing Economics
basic model is used throughout the paper and holds together all that
follows. Feldstein cites a number of authors who have observed this
regularity in empirical data on personal savings patterns as confirmation
of the model. He goes on to argue that while the “hump-savings” model
works well to explain most of the observed data, the effect of certain
government policies on individual savings has never been measured em-
pirically. In particular, he poses the question: What is the effect of social
security on individuals’ lifetime savings? He then cites the work of three
other authors as well as his own earlier work as examples of this neglect.
In this way, Feldstein presents his current research as a necessary
development out of well established research program, the next question
to ask on a line stemming from important ancestors to contemporary
scholarly research. The reader is thus prepared for the empirical analysis
that follows, which shows that “social security depresses personal savings
by 3050 percent” (Martin Feldstein, 1974).
PRESENTING YOUR HYPOTHESIS
The literature review sets out the issues that motivate your paper and
demonstrates your familiarity with what others have written on the topic.
The next step is to formulate a specific question, problem, or conjecture,
and to describe the approach you will take to answer, solve, or test it.
Often, this will take the form of an empirical hypothesis: “social security
depresses personal savings;” “high levels of employment are related to
high levels of inflation,” etc. An empirical hypothesis makes a claim about
how some part of the economy works, and can be assessed by analyzing
the relevant data.
In presenting your hypothesis, you need to discuss the data set you are
using and, in most cases, the type of regression you will run. You should
say where you found the data, and use a table, graph, or simple statistics
to summarize them. You should explain how the data relate to your
hypothesis and note any problems they pose. If you have only a small set
of observations, or have to use proxies for data you cannot directly
observe, you should explicitly acknowledge this.
For example, in “Employment -based Health Insurance and Job
Mobility: Is There Evidence of Job-lock?,” Brigitte Madrian (1994) writes:
To study the phenomenon of job-lock, one would like information on
individual and family health status, worker mobility, and the health
insurance plans of both the firm for which and individual works and to
which one could move. Unfortunately, information on health status
and health insurance is not widely available in labor force surveys,
information on worker mobility is not typically available in health
surveys, and information on insurance plans of companies for which
an individual could have worked is nonexistent.
24 | Writing Economics
Madrian goes on to offer an alternative method to study job-lock by
looking at two groups of workers who are similar in all respects but one:
one group has employer provided health insurance and the other does
not. She then measures the number of times the workers change jobs and
observes a significant negative relationship between employment-based
health insurance and job turnover.
Madrian is careful not to jump to a hasty conclusion, noting that this
correlation is not itself conclusive evidence of job-lock. Employers that
provide health insurance often provide other benefits that will affect
mobility. In addition, unobserved characteristics of workers’ health status
may independently affect job sorting and mobility because workers with
preexisting conditions may have a harder time getting new health
insurance. Still, Madrian’s careful analysis controls for as many factors as
possible and allows her to conclude: “that there is substantial health
insurance-related job-lock.”
In a term paper, it may not be possible to reach conclusive empirical
results. You may have incomplete data, or your regression coefficients may
not be significant, or you may not have controlled for significantly all the
factors involved. It is better to acknowledge these shortcomings than to
make overly broad and unsupported statements.
PRESENTING YOUR RESULTS / by Chris Foote
One of the more common mistakes made by authors of economic papers
is to forget that their results need to be written up as carefully and clearly
as any other part of the paper. There are essentially two decisions to
make. First, how many empirical results should be presented? Second,
how should these results be described in the text?
How Many Results Should I Report?
Less is usually more. A common mistake made by virtually all novice
researchers (including graduate students) is to include every parameter
estimate from every regression specification that was run. Such a “kitchen
sink” approach is usually taken to show the world that the researcher has
been careful and done a lot of work and that the main results of the paper
are not sensitive to the choice of sample period, minor changes in the list
of regressors, etc. However, pages of parameter estimates usually muddy
the message of the paper. The reader will get either lost or bored. A good
general rule is to present only those parameter estimates that speak
directly to your topic.
For example, suppose you are writing about the effect of education on
wages. Your main regression places an individual’s wage on the left-hand
side and regressors such as education, race, gender, seniority at the
individual’s job, labor market experience, and state of residence on the
right hand side. You believe that the regressor of interest (education) is
25 | Writing Economics
correlated with the error term of the wage equation more “able” people
earn more at their jobs, i.e. have a high residual in the wage equation, and
also obtain more education. Because of this correlation between the error
term and education, the measured effect of education in the regression
will reflect not only the true causal effect of education on wages but also
some of the effect of ability on wages. To circumvent this “ability bias” you
use a separate measure as a proxy for ability. Though such a proxy is
probably not available, assume for the sake of exposition that a special
dataset contains an individual’s evaluation by his or her second grade
teacher. When presenting your results you want to focus only on the
estima tes of the education effect and the ability effect. Your table might
look something like this:
TABLE I OLS Estimates of the Effect of Education on Wages
Dependent variable: Log of Yearly Earnings 19851995
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Years of Education .091 .031 .086 .027
(.001) (.003) (.002) (.005)
Ability Dummy .251 .301
(.010) (.010)
State Dummies No No Yes Yes
Included?
No. of Obs. 35,001 35,001 19,505 19,505
No. of Persons 5,505 5,505 4,590 4,590
Adj. R
2
.50 .55 .76 .79
TABLE I.
Notes to Table I. Standard errors are in parentheses. Data are from the Tennessee
Second Grade Ability Survey and Wage Follow-up, and include individuals
evaluated between 1962 and 1971. The “ability dummy” equals one if the
individual’s second grade teacher classified the individual as “able,” zero other-
wise. Each regression also includes yearly dummies, 10 one-digit industry and 20
Census defined occupation dummies, labor market experience (defined as age 6),
experience squared, seniority on the current job, seniority squared, Census region
of current residence, marital status, race, gender, and a dummy variable denoting
whether the individual lives in a city of more than 100,000 persons. Columns (3)
and (4) have fewer observations because state of residence is not available for
some individuals.
Note that Table I does not present the parameter estimates of your
control variables, regressors such as marital status and seniority, but
presents any detail that helps interpret the parameters of interest
(including the identification of the dependent variable, which is
annoyingly left off of many tables). For example, explain how you define
labor market experience as well as why the third and fourth regressions
have fewer observations than the first and second regressions. The notes
26 | Writing Economics
to your table should be extensive enough so that the reader does not have
to look back at the text to understand what is being presented. The
cardinal sin, to be avoided at all costs, is to report your estimates in terms
of “a” or “b” (the actual Greek letters from your equations) without stating
what these coefficients mean. Using eight-letter abbreviations from your
Stata or SAS program (YEDUCT1 or ABIL25A) is not much better.
Don’t worry about repeating yourself in the text and the notes this
will often be necessary so the reader can understand your table without
looking back at the text. You should present enough information in total
so that a researcher could replicate your results. For very detailed projects,
this may require a data appendix. Finally, the notes to the table should
indicate whether you are reporting standard errors or t-statistics in the
parentheses underneath the coefficients. Both are seen in the literature,
so you must be clear which you are using. As a general rule, it is better to
report standard errors. That way, your readers can more easily choose the
statistical method they would like to use in evaluating your numbers.
After presenting these results you may want to discuss any additional
robustness checks that you performed. The third and fourth columns of
Table I are robustness checks of sorts; they show that the effect of
including ability in the regression is the same whether or not we include
state level dummy variables. We may also have checked whether the
estimate of the education effect is lower when ability is included, if we
subset only on male household heads or if we restrict the sample to the
1990s. Sometimes all that is necessary is to let the reader know in the text
that you performed these tests and that the main results were
unaffected. For a single robustness check, this information can even
appear in a footnote keyed to the relevant portion of the text. If there are
many robustness checks however, you may want to present these results
in another, more parsimonious table.
How Should I Describe My Empirical Results in the Text?
After you decide how to make your tables, graphs, and figures, you should
clearly and precisely describe them in the text. Establish the main point of
the table in the topic sentence of a paragraph. For example, you can
describe the above table like this:
Table I shows that including a measure of ability in the wage equation
dramatically lowers the predicted effect of education on earnings.
Column 1 does not include an ability measure and indicates that a
year of education raises wages by 9.1 percent. Column 2 adds the
ability measure and the education effect drops to 3.1 percent.
Columns 3 and 4 show that this general pattern is repeated even when
state level dummy variables are included. The estimates in Table I are
therefore consistent with the hypothesis that the OLS estimates suffer
from an upward ability bias.
27 | Writing Economics
Note that the first and last sentences in this paragraph are “big picture”
statements, describing how the results in this table fit into the overall
theme of the paper.
Too often, authors do not pay close attention to the paragraphs that
describe their results. The results are already in the table. What difference
does it make how they are described in the text? The reason to craft these
descriptive paragraphs carefully is that any well-designed empirical
project is complex; a lot of factors must be considered in order for any
single factor to be precisely estimated. You want to guide the reader and
focus his or her attention on the important parts of the table, and in the
right order. Moreover, no empirical paper turns out perfectly. Usually the
data do not resoundingly support each and every idea. In these cases, it is
crucial to discuss your results as honestly and carefully as possible.
For example, assume that you are studying the effect of the
population share of lawyers in a city on the subsequent growth rate of
that city. Your theory says that cities with lots of lawyers will grow more
slowly than other cities, but the same is not true of cities with lots of
other highly education professionals, such as doctors. You get data on the
population percentage of both doctors and lawyers in 25 cities in 1950
and on the growth rates of these cities as well as the Census region for
each city (Mountain, Pacific, Mid-Atlantic, etc.) from 1950 to 1990. Your
regression places the 1950-1990 growth rate of the city on the left hand
side; the regressor of interest is the “lawyer share” of population. The
results are presented in the table below:
TABLE II Estimates of the Effect of Lawyers on City Growth
Dependent variable: City’s Population Growth Rate, 1950-1990
(1) (2) (3)
Share of Lawyers -.09 -.08 -.07
in Population, 1950 (.01) (.03) (.05)
Share of Doctors .05 .05
In Population, 1950 (.03) (.05)
Region Dummies No No Yes
Included?
No. of Obs. 25 25 25
Adj. R
2
.10 .12 .50
TABLE II
Notes to Table II. Standard errors are in parentheses. The shares of doctors and
lawyers are taken from the Five Percent Public Use Micro Sample of the 1950 U.S.
Census and are defined as the share of each profession among employed persons
in the population aged 2564. A “city” is defined as Standard Metropolitan
Statistical Area; constant SMSA definitions are used from 1950 to 1990. Region
dummies correspond to the 10 “major regions” as defined by the Census Bureau.
28 | Writing Economics
A bad way to write up this table is:
The first column of Table II shows the main effect predicted by theory.
The second column shows that doctors do not have the same effect on
city growth. Finally, the inclusion of regional dummy variables does
not significantly affect the main point estimates, though statistical
precision is lost.
A better way to write up the table is like this:
Table II shows that a high share of lawyers in a city’s population
appears to lead to slower growth. Yet, when all the determinants of
city growth (such as Census Region growth) are accounted for, the
estimate of this effect becomes less precise. The first column shows
that a 10 percentage -point increase in the lawyer share of population
decreases the future city growth by about .9 percentage points.
Column 2 shows that, by contrast, a high doctor share does not lead to
lower growth. In fact, the point estimate for the doctor share is
positive, though not statistically significant. Note however that the
estimates in Column 2 are less precise than those in Table 1, as the
standard error for the lawyer effect rises from .01 to .03. Since the
doctor and lawyer share are strongly (positively) correlated,
multicollinearity reduces the precision of the regression. Statistical
precision becomes even more of a concern in Column 3, when we add
dummy variables for Census region. The size of the lawyer effect
remains about the same (-.07 compared with -.09 and -.08), but
adding so many new regressors causes the standard errors to rise to
the point that the lawyer effect is statistically indistinguishable from
zero. The implication is that lawyers do have a negative effect on city
growth but that although the point estimate is robust to the inclusion
of other relevant variables it is not precisely estimated because of the
small sample size.
The Bottom Line
When writing up your empirical results focus only on what is important
and be as clear as possible. You may feel that you are repeating yourself
and that the reader may be offended at how closely you are leading him
or her through your tables and graphs but, to paraphrase John Kenneth
Galbraith, both smart and dumb readers will appreciate your pointing
things out directly and clearly. The dumb readers need the help, and the
smart ones will take silent pleasure in the knowledge that they didn’t
need your assistance!
29 | Writing Economics
DISCUSSING YOUR RESULTS
Many of the topics that interest economists have real world policy
implications. Your own research may present strong findings about the
effects of existing or proposed policies. While this is fine, you should not
conclude that “this should be done” or “this should not be done.” You
should avoid making value judgments and rely instead on economic facts
and analyses. Even when you have reached your own conclusions about
which policy is desirable, your reader should be able to consider the facts
and make the policy decision for himself or herself.
For example, you may find that substituting policy X for current policy
Y would raise GDP by 2 percent. That is an appropriate conclusion in a
term paper. Be careful, however, not to simply assert that policy X should
be substituted for policy Y. For one thing, it can be very difficult to
measure the welfare consequences of a given set of policies. Dollars and
cents may be easy to measure, but individuals’ well being is not. In addi-
tion, your own research may not have accounted for certain distributional
issues, legal issues, matters of national sovereignty or any number of
other things that ultimately affect the desirability of a given policy.
In the discussion of your result, you should also point out the
limitations of your research, say the relatively small number of observa-
tions you have or the simplicity of the functional form you have tested. In
an undergraduate term paper such limitations are expected. In general, it
is better to show your instructor that you understand the limits of your
method than make broad claims you do not support. You can also suggest
questions or alternative approaches for further research.
Once you have completed the discussion of your results, you can add a
short conclusion summarizing what you have done. Then go back and
write an introduction that provides a roadmap for the reader. If you have
budgeted your time, you should have a chance to revise the paper, with
the goal of achieving greater clarity. Finally, ask a friend to proofread your
work. Make necessary corrections and then submit.
30 | Writing Economics
Five | Formatting and Documentation / by Kerry Walk
Citing the sources you use when you write a paper in economics is a
matter of honesty, credibility, and courtesy. When you indicate to your
reader that a fact or theory derives from a source, you are being honest by
giving credit where it is due, i.e., not falsely claiming to have originated
the fact or theory yourself. You are gaining credibility by showing your
readers that you’ve done your research. And you are behaving courteously
by letting your readers know where they can find the same information,
in case they want to do further reading on the topic.
There is no standard style of acknowledging sources in economics
papers, but a good model to emulate is the style used in one of the field’s
most influential journals: The American Economic Review. We will call this
the AER documentation style. Use this style when you write an economics
paper in which you have cited one or more sources.
In the AER style, writers briefly indicate sources in the text of the
paper and provide fuller bibliographical information in a REFERENCES
section at the end of the paper. Footnotes are reserved for such
substantive matters as suggestions for further reading, an elaboration of
a point, an interesting but not germane rebuttal of a source’s opinion, and
so on.
PLACING CITATIONS IN YOUR PAPER
When deriving a theory or fact from a source, cite the source in the text of
your paper. Your in-text citation will contain the name of the author(s)
and the year of publication. The way this information is formatted
depends on (1) whether you wish to draw attention to the source and (2)
whether you have referred to the author(s) previously in your paper.
Loud Reference
If you wish to acknowledge the source of an idea explicitly, cite the name
of the author(s) in the body of your sentence and place the publication
date in parentheses. The first time you cite the name of the author(s),
provide both first and last names:
31 | Writing Economics
Vincent P. Crawford and Hans Haller (1990).
Thereafter, refer to the author(s) by last name only:
Crawford (1998)
Thus, a first-time reference:
Sender-receiver games, introduced by Jerry Green and Nancy Stokey
(1980) and Vincent P. Crawford and Joel Sobel (1982), provide the
simplest stylized environment in which communication is essential.
A reference to authors previously mentioned:
These theories come in two guises: explicit dynamic theories, i.e.,
Canning (1992) and Nöldeke and Samuelson (1992), and static
solution concepts, i.e., Blume et al. (1993) and Wärneryd (1993).
Use “et al.” (et alias = and others) when authors number three or more.
Place punctuation, if any is called for, after the parenthetical date.
Soft Reference
To evoke a source that substantiates a claim you make, cite the name of
the author(s), as well as the date, in parentheses. As above, the first time
you cite the author(s), provide both first and last names:
(Vincent P. Crawford and Hans Haller, 1990; Matthew Rabin and Joel
Sobel, 1996)
Thereafter, refer to the author(s) by last name only:
(Crawford and Sobel, 1982; Crawford, 1998)
Authors are listed in order of publication date.
Separate sources with a semi-colon.
Thus, in an article that has already cited Andreas Blume:
Such “babbling equilibria” are proper (Roger B. Myerson, 1978; Blume,
1994), and even strategic stability (Elon Kohlberg and Jean-Francois
Mertens, 1986) does not rule out uninformative equilibria in general.
32 | Writing Economics
LISTING YOUR REFERENCES
When readers want to know more about a source what its title is, where
it was published, when it appeared they will look at your list of
REFERENCES at the end of your paper. The bibliographical information
there makes it possible for readers themselves to track down the source.
Note that the word REFERENCES is capitalized because AER Style
demands that it be so. Indentation, capitalization, punctuation, and the
ordering of information in REFERENCES define a particular documentation
style and should be scrupulously followed. Even boldface, italics, and
spacing count.
Three Types of Sources
The information contained in a REFERENCES entry and the way in which
this information is formatted depend largely on the type of source it is. Is
the source an article in a journal? a reference work? a book by a single
author? an essay in a collection? a working paper? an unpublished
doctoral dissertation? In order to format the entry correctly, you need to
know.
There are three main types of sources: journal articles, books, and
unpublished sources.
Journal articles appear in publications that are issued at regular
intervals, or periods; hence “periodical,” the synonym for “journal.” A
telltale sign of the journal is the publication date: month (or season)
and year. Another sign is the absence of a publisher’s name (such as
“Cambridge University Press”).
The opening pages of a book will give such information as author (if
there is one), title, name of the publisher, and place and year of
publication. A book that is a collection of essays (also known as an
“anthology”) will give the name(s) of its editor(s) and will feature a
Table of Contents listing the essays in the collection. Such a collection
should not be confused with a periodical.
Unpublished sources, which are available from the individuals who
wrote them or the institution that sponsored them, are of various
kinds: the mimeograph (a photocopied paper or report), the
unpublished doctoral dissertation, the working paper, and so on. Other
unpublished sources include course lectures, websites, and e-mail
messages.
See below for sample entries according to these three types of sources.
Basic Guidelines
Whether a source is a journal article, a book, or an unpublished source,
you should follow these basic guidelines when formatting it for your
REFERENCES.
33 | Writing Economics
Alphabetical listing. Sources are listed in alphabetical order, according
to the last name of the author (or the last name of the primary author,
if there’s more than one). If the source has no author for example,
U.S. Bureau of the Census it should be listed alphabetically according
to its initial letter.
Formatting author(s)’ names. Authors’ last names are always listed
before their first names. The punctuation separating individual
authors’ names changes depending on the number of authors.
One author:
Davis, Donald R.
Two authors:
Kohlberg, Elon and Mertens, Jean-Francois.
Three authors:
Kandori, Michihiro; Mailath, George J. and Rob, Rafael.
Four authors:
Berg, Joyce E.; Daley, Lane; Dickhaut, John and O’Brien, John.
Note the semicolon (;) used to divide some, but not all, of the names in
the three- and four -author examples.
Repeat authors. Sometimes your REFERENCES will contain more than
one source by the same author or authors. In this case, do not spell out
the author’s or authors’ name(s) after the first entry; instead, use an
underscore (___) to signify the name(s). List sources by the same
author(s) in order of publication date.
Krugman, Paul R. and Venables, Anthony J. “Integration and the
Competitiveness of Peripheral Industry,” in Christopher Bliss and
Jorge Braga de Macedo, eds., Unity with diversity in the European
economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990, pp. 56
77.
___. “Globalization and the Inequality of Nations.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, November 1995, 110 (4), pp. 85780.
Note that the second source above was written by exactly the same
authors as the first source. If the second source had been written by
Krugman and, say, Young, their names would have to have been
spelled out.
If the second source had been a book written during the same year
(1990) as the first source, the first source would be listed as 1990a, the
second as 1990b.
34 | Writing Economics
Inclusive page numbers. Page numbers are inclusive that is, they
refer to the pages on which the entire source may be found, not just
the page or two from which you drew a fact or theory. If the first and
last page numbers share an initial numeral, drop the initial numeral of
the last page number: for example, pp. 36798 (and not pp. 367398).
SAMPLE REFERENCES ENTRIES
When formatting your REFERENCES section, use the following sample
entries as models. If you don’t find the type of source you’re looking for,
pick up a copy of the American Economic Review in the Lamont Reference
Room and try to find a model there, or emulate the closest approximation
you can find.
Article Published in a Journal
An entry for a journal article will contain the following information,
formatted as you see:
Author. “Title of the Article.” Name of the Journal, Month Year, Issue
Numeral (Issue Number), pp. XZ.
Note the boldfaced author name and the italicized journal name and issue
numeral. The “pp.” stands for “page numbers.” The second line is indented,
as are all lines after the first one.
No author:
Economist. “The Economist Survey of China.” November 28, 1992, 325
(7787), pp. 122.
One author:
Davis, Donald R. “Intra-Industry Trade: A Heckscher-Ohlin-Ricardo
Approach.” Journal of International Economics, November 1995, 39
(34), pp. 20126.
Two authors:
Kohlberg, Elon and Mertens, Jean-Francois. “On the Strategic Stability
of Equilibrium.” Econometrica, September 1986, 54 (5), pp. 1003
37.
Three authors:
35 | Writing Economics
Kandori, Michihiro; Mailath, George J. and Rob, Rafael. “Learning,
Mutation, and Long-Run Equilibria in Games.” Econometrica,
January 1993, 61 (1), pp. 2956.
Four authors:
Berg, Joyce E.; Daley, Lane; Dickhaut, John and O’Brien, John.
“Controlling Preferences for Lotteries on Units of Experimental
Exchange.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1986, 101 (2), pp.
281–306.
Books
In its most basic form, a book will contain the following information,
formatted as you see:
Author. The title of the book. City of Publication: Name of the Press,
Year of Publication.
Note the boldfaced author name and the italicized title. Only the initial
letter of the title is capitalized. The second line is indented, as are all lines
after the first one.
Reference works:
U.S. Bureau of the Census, Department of Commerce. U.S. census of
manufactures. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office,
1992.
National Science Foundation/Division of Science Resource Studies.
Research and development in industry. Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office, 1992.
Even the period after Studies is in boldface.
By a single author:
Rosenberg, Nathan. Perspectives on technology. New York: Cambridge
University Press, 1976.
Helpman, Elhanan and Krugman, Paul R. Market structure and foreign
trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1985.
MA, the abbreviation for “Massachusetts,” is used with “Cambridge” to
avoid confusion with the first Cambridge Cambridge, England.
An essay in an edited collection:
36 | Writing Economics
Whinnom, Keith. “Linguistic Hybridization and the Special Case’ of
Pidgins and Creoles,” in Dell Hymes, ed., Pidginization and
creolization of languages. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1971, pp. 91116.
Krugman, Paul R. and Venables, Anthony J. “Integration and the
Competitiveness of Peripheral Industry,” in Christopher Bliss and
Jorge Braga de Macedo, eds., Unity with diversity in the European
economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990, pp. 56
77.
Maskus, Keith. “Comparing International Trade Data and Product and
National Characteristics Data for the Analysis of Trade Models,” in
Peter Hooper and J. David Richardson, eds., International economic
transactions: Issues in measurement and empirical research. NBER
Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 55. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1991, pp. 1756.
The name of the essay is in quotation marks. Note the capitalization
scheme. An editor is “ed.,” editors are “eds.” Inclusive page numbers
help the reader easily locate the essay.
Unpublished Sources
Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation:
Clausing, Kimberly A. “Essays in International Economic Integration.”
Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University, 1996.
Working paper or discussion paper:
Kramarz, Francis. “When Repeated Cheap Talk Generates a Common
Language.” Working paper, Institut National de la Statistique et
des Etudes Economiques (INSEE), 1992.
Sopher, Barry and Zapater, Iñigo. “Communication and Coordination in
Signalling Games: An Experimental Study.” Working paper, Rutgers
University, 1994.
Wei, Shang-Jin. “How Reluctant Are Nations in Global Integration?”
National Bureau of Economic Research (Cambridge, MA) Working
Paper No. 5531, April 1996.
Green, Jerry and Stokey, Nancy. “A Two-Person Game of Information
Transmission.” Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion
Paper No. 751, Harvard University, 1980.
Mimeograph (i.e., photocopied material)
37 | Writing Economics
Fujita, Masahisa; Krugman, Paul R. and Venables, Anthony J.
“Agricultural Transport Costs.” Mimeo, MIT, December 14, 1996.
Class lecture or speech:
Foote, Christopher L. “Introduction to Economic Theory.” Lecture in
Economics 970, Harvard University, 12 February 1999.
Website:
U.S. Census Bureau. <http://www.census.gov/> cited 21 February
1999.
E-mail message:
Neugeboren, Robert. [email protected] “Economic Models.”
Personal e-mail, 16 January 1999.
A Sample AER REFERENCES page is on the next page
38 | Writing Economics
A Sample AER REFERENCES page:
39 | Writing Economics
Appendix A | Fields in Economics
The economic approach is applicable to a wide range of social
interactions, which can make finding a topic for your paper particularly
difficult. Perhaps your instructor has provided a list of potential topics.
Which should you choose? Perhaps the assignment leaves the choice of a
topic entirely up to you. How should you get started? Below you will find a
list of fields in economics that should help narrow the scope of your
choices.
COMPARATIVE/REFORM ECONOMICS
Now that the cold war is over, interest in reform economics is on the rise.
Today, many nations around the world are trying to shift from economic
systems based on hierarchical principles of command and control to
market systems based on the principles of free exchange and competition.
Comparative economic systems attempt to explore, using pertinent
theoretical models where possible, how “socialist” economic life has been
organized in practice. Particular attention is paid to the development
strategies pursued and the actual functioning of economic arrangements,
as well as the balance between plans, bureaucracies, and informal sectors.
Why did “planned” economies appear to function effectively for so long?
Why did so many suddenly conclude at the end of the 1980s that they had
failed? What, precisely, is wrong with trying to organize economic life on
the hierarchical principles of command and control? How can these
countries make the transition to market-based systems without
undermining the political stability needed to implement reforms?
DEVELOPMENT
Annual per capita income in the United States today is $24,000, while half
the world’s population subsists on less than $1,500 a year. Economists and
others have long tried to understand the factors contributing to this
enormous gap between rich and poor nations and have long sought
effective ways to accelerate growth in developing economies. Over the
40 | Writing Economics
past thirty years, development economics as a field has dealt with the
specific economic problems of relatively poor countries. Understanding
development means understanding the political and social conditions
that impel and constrain it. For instance, fear of Western imperialism led
the rulers of Meji Japan to overthrow the Tokugama Shogunate and
embark on an ambitious economic program that turned medieval Japan
into a nineteenth-century industrial power in two generations. In Africa,
perhaps most acutely, it is difficult to understand cycles of growth
without an appreciation of political patterns and customs. Today, most
development economists apply the standard analytical tools of economics
to the specific problems confronting developing countries, modifying
those tools where necessary.
ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS
Few areas of economics have grown so rapidly in recent years as
environmental economics. As people have more fully realized that
important natural resources are in finite supply, attempts to conserve and
to recycle have steadily gained momentum. Since very few questions of
environmental policy can be cast purely in terms of black and white,
economists, with their long tradition of analyzing trade -offs, have played
important roles in designing environmental regulations. Questions asked
include: Does it make most sense to reduce pollution by setting emission
standards or through using tax policy to create incentives for emissions
reductions? How can we decide which species have the greatest priority
for protection? What does "sustainability" consist of?
ECONOMIC HISTORY
It is hard to gain a coherent picture of what the economy is without
understanding how it evolved and what history teaches us about how
different economies function. It is important to learn about qualitative
and quantitative consequences of the industrial revolution for levels of
wealth, the sectoral distribution of production, the distribution of income,
the state of technology, the role of government, and the development of
commerce. It is important to learn which of current economic institutions
and behavioral relationships have persisted over long stretches of time
and which are relatively new. It is also important to be exposed to the
wide range of past economic problems, so they can know how standard
micro and macro techniques apply, and where they fail. Things change,
but it can look as if the institutions and practices of today have existed
forever. A historical perspective can help bring the issues of today into
better focus, just as it can help explain events in the past and offer a
trajectory toward the future.
41 | Writing Economics
FINANCE
Robert Merton and Myron Scholes won the 1997 Nobel Prize in Economics
for their options pricing model, a relatively simple equation that spawned
the field of financial economics. Financial economics studies the behavior
and structure of financial markets and institutions, including commercial
banks, insurance companies, investment banks, mutual funds players in
the stock and bond markets. Some research focuses on corporate finance
and the capital structure of firms, the kinds of analyses that go on inside a
corporate finance department of a Wall Street investment bank. Others
look at portfolio management and the analysis of risk, arbitrage, and time
discounting applied to the valuation of various financial assets. Financial
economics has taken on an increasingly international perspective,
comparing the financial systems of the US, Germany, and Japan, for
instance, or analyzing the links between the development of local capital
markets and the real economy.
GAME THEORY
In the last twenty-five or so years, theorists have made great advances in
characterizing the behavior of households, workers, and firms. Among the
most active areas of current research are considerations of the roles of
imperfect information, uncertainty, and strategic behavior in shaping the
way that many economic interactions take place. Game theory is often
used for such analyses. These lines of research have been helpful in
explaining situations in which for example, involuntary unemployment is
persistent or people cannot get loans despite being willing to pay the
going interest rate.
INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZAT ION
Industrial organization seeks to apply economic theories of markets to
actual industries and firms in the United States and other developed
industrial economies. The inquiry starts by comparing the motives and
organizations of actual enterprises to those that economic models as-
sume the firm possesses. The industrial organization field is built around a
structure-conduct-performance framework. The constraints imposed on
firms by their environments and their competitors lead them to certain
strategic choices and activities, which have impacts on the performance
of markets as social allocation devices. Research in industrial organization
proceeds along two lines: statistical investigations (to make sure that the
cases cited are representative) and case studies (to make sure that
statistical investigations are really asking the right questions and
producing meaningful answers). It is less business-oriented than policy-
and theory-oriented although the analyses of industrial organization
hold considerable relevance for those planning business careers.
42 | Writing Economics
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS
Both historically and today the field of international economics has been
and is policy-oriented: What should governments do? How should they
regulate the cross-border economic relationships that their citizens enter
into? As world trade and finance becomes more salient, international
economics threatens to become coterminous with the study of economic
policy in general. Today, even in such a large economy as the United
States, it is very difficult to examine issues in public finance,
macroeconomics, industrial organization, or labor economics without
paying very close attention to the international context.
LABOR ECONOMICS
Labor economics applies basic tools of microeconomics to the analysis of
labor markets and the determination of the wage rate. What are the
arguments for and against a minimum wage? What factors explain wage
differentials? It distinguishes itself by two features. First, it is an intensely
empirical sub-field, in which students are expected to analyze data
often from very large computerized data sets as part of their study.
Second, it is one of the few subfields where actual empirical fieldwork
visits to companies and unions is encouraged. Labor economics requires
a good knowledge of price theory and a sound grasp of statistics.
MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY
The two principal ways that public policy affects the course of the
economy in the United States are the government's monetary policy
implemented in financial markets by the country's central bank, the
Federal Reserve and fiscal policy, implemented through the taxing and
spending decisions that Congress and the President make (or fail to
make). Politicians assume, and economists believe, that such monetary
and fiscal policies can exert very strong influences on such determinants
of economic welfare as the rate of inflation, the rate of the economy's
growth, the level of employment, and ultimately the standard of living.
PUBLIC FINANCE
Topics stressed in this field include efficiency and equity arguments for
government "interference" in market economies, what it means for the
government to provide a level playing field on which private economic
activity can take place, theories advanced to explain actual choices by
representative governments, the effects of government tax and
expenditure decisions on the allocation of resources, and the distribution
of well-being. Special attention is given to the fiscal institutions of the
United States.
43 | Writing Economics
URBAN ECONOMICS
The phrase "urban crisis" is again found on the pages of major
newspapers, often linked to issues of poverty, crime, and the breakdown
of the family. Detroit has lost more than half its population in the past
thirty years. Poverty, crime in inner-city neighborhoods, infrastructure,
racial discrimination, friction between immigrant and other ethnic
groups; and the gap between the desires for public services and the
willingness to pay for them play an even more important role in the
American drama today than they did in the late 1960's when studying
urban problems was at a fore. Many urban problems have their roots in
market processes. Space or location plays a central role in urban markets
both in creating value and in generating positive and negative
externalities. Ease of transportation is a good, but nearness to high-crime
areas is a bad. Open space is a good, but long commutes are a bad. And so
forth. You get what you pay for. But you rarely pay for what you(r actions
lead other people to) get.
44 | Writing Economics
Appendix B | Standard Statistical Sources
SECONDARY SOURCES
The Economic Report of the President
Published annually, The Economic Report of the President includes:
(1) current and foreseeable trends in and annual goals for employment,
production, real income, and Federal budget outlays; (2) employment
objectives for significant groups of the labor force; and (3) a program for
carrying out these objectives. Reports from 19961999 are available on
the web at w3.access.gpo.gov/eop/.
Statistical Abstract of the United States
Published annually, the Statistical Abstract is a collection of statistics on
social and economic conditions in the United States. Selected
international data are also included. It is your best source of information
on relevant primary data sources available from the Census Bureau, other
Federal agencies, and private organizations. The 1998 Statistical Abstract
is available on the web at
www.census.gov/prod/3/98pubs/98statab/cc98stab.htm
World Tables
Published annually by the World Bank, the World Tables provide
standardized data on GDP, population, government deficits, trade, social
indicators, etc. for numerous individual countries (161 in the 1994 edition)
and are thus a key reference for international comparisons. A Supplement
containing revised data is published approximately six months after the
main volume. Data are presented as annual times series covering multiple
years (19721992, 1994 edition), as well as by topics and country.
45 | Writing Economics
PRIMARY SOURCES
Census
Conducted every ten years, the census serves as a vital statistical
database. It collects information on an individual’s place of birth,
ethnicity, native language, family history, annual income, etc., and thus
gives a picture of who is living in the United States.
Consumer Expenditure Survey (CES)
Conducted since 1889, the CES obtains data on frequently purchased
items, such as food or housekeeping supplies, as well as on major items of
expense, such as property or vehicle purchases. This is a key source of
consumption data.
Current Population Survey (CPS)
A monthly survey of about 50,000 households, the CPS has been
conducted since 1968. It is the primary source of information on the
characteristics of the US labor force. In addition to providing estimates of
employment, unemployment, earnings, and hours of work by occupation,
industry, and class of worker, it also sheds light on a variety of
demographic characteristics including age, sex, race, marital status, and
educational attainment of the labor force. Supplemental questions
provide information on a variety of topics, including school enrollment,
income, previous work experience, health, employee benefits, and work
schedules.
National Longitudinal Survey (NLS)
The NLS currently provides 6 panels of information about the labor
market experiences and other aspects of the interviewees. The surveys
also include data about a wide range of events such as schooling and
career transitions, marriage and fertility, training investments, child-care
usage, and drug and alcohol use. The breadth of these surveys allows for
analysis of a variety of topics such as the transition from school to work,
job mobility, youth unemployment, educational attainment, and the
returns to education, welfare recipiency, the impact of training, and
retirement decisions.
THE INTERNET
The internet is increasingly a source for economic data. There are a
number of sites that provide a wealth of information. These include the
following:
The Bureau of Labor Statistics, stats.bls.gov, reports on a diverse set of
indicators including unemployment, the consumer price index as well
46 | Writing Economics
as lesser known data on work stoppage, collective bargaining,
occupational injury, and illness rates, etc.
Bureau of Economic Analysis, www.bea.doc.gov, an agency of the
Department of Commerce, provides data on GDP, industrial output
and investment as well as international trade.
Fedstats, www.fedstats.gov, makes public data from over 70 different
federal agencies. Data cover such diverse issues as natural resources
and the environment, motor vehicle accidents, and wages and weekly
earnings.
FRED, or the Federal Reserve Economic Database,
www.stls.frb.org/fred/, provides historical US economic and financial
data, including daily U.S. interest rates, monetary and business
indicators, exchange rates, balance of payments, and regional
economic data for Arkansas, Illinois, Indiana, Kentucky, Mississippi,
Missouri, and Tennessee.
Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research (ICPSR),
www.icpsr.umich.edu. ICPSR culls a wide variety of data on topics as
diverse as education, aging, mental health, criminal justice, etc. It is an
invaluable source of on-line data.
National Bureau of Economic Research,
www.nber.org/data_index.html, provides a wide variety of both
current and historical macro, industry-level, and individual data. Their
listings include the CPS and extracts from the CES.
The Harvard MIT Data Center, hdc-www.harvard.edu/hdc/, the
universities' official representative to ICPSR, the Roper Center for Public
Opinion Research, and the National Center for Health Statistics
(NCHS), provides access to Murray Center and Social Sciences Program
Data and is a central contact point for many other archives and data
suppliers.
The Harvard Economics Department’s website
www.economics.harvard.edu/links.html, provides links to some of the
most widely used data available on the web. See the section entitled
“Data Sources and Information.”
Bill Goffe’s Resources for Economists on the Internet,
rfe.wustl.edu/EconFAW.html, categorizes data by research topics,
making it extremely useful for finding data that is relevant to a new
research project.
47 | Writing Economics
Appendix C | Electronic Indices to Periodical Literature
EconLit
The primary index to economic periodical articles, EconLit is an indexed
bibliography with selected abstracts of the economics literature produced
by the American Economic Association. It covers over 400 major journals
as well as articles in collected volumes, books, book reviews, dissertations,
and working papers licensed from the Cambridge University Press
Abstracts of Working Papers in Economics. It is available through Hollis
Plus at lib.harvard.edu/e -resources/details/e/econlitx.html; a valid
Harvard ID is required.
NBER Working Papers Database
The NBER’s website indexes the working papers of affiliated faculty. This is
an excellent source for empirical work in progress. Full copies of working
papers are available free to subscribers and for a small fee to others from
the website or through the mail. They are also available in many academic
libraries. Searches are possible at papers.nber.org.
Social Science Research Network (SSRN)
The SSRN Electronic Library has an Abstract Database containing abstracts
on over 25,700 scholarly working papers and forthcoming papers and an
Electronic Paper Collection currently containing over 11,600
downloadable full text documents. It includes working papers from the
NBER as well as economics departments around the country. Searches can
be made at papers.ssrn.com/sol3/search.taf.
Statistical Universe
A bibliographic database that indexes and abstracts the statistical content
of selected United States federal and state government publications, state
as well as business and association publications. The abstracts include a
detailed description of a publication’s statistical contents and primary
bibliographic information. This database is available through Hollis Plus at
lib.harvard.edu/e -resources/details/s/statuniv.html and requires a valid
Harvard ID.
48 | Writing Economics
JSTOR (Journal Storage)
Many of the articles you will need are available on-line through JSTOR.
JSTOR holds 13 of the top economics journals as well as numerous others
in political science, demography, history and statistics. Unfortunately,
JSTOR contains only those articles that were published prior to or during
1993 (or 1995 in some cases). This resource is also available through Hollis
Plus at lib.harvard.edu/e -resources/details/j/jstorage.html and requires a
valid Harvard ID.
RePEC (Research Papers in Economics)
This website calls itself a “decentralized database of working papers,
journal articles and software components.” Searches can be made at
www.repec.org.
Individual Economics Departments Websites
Many economics departments make faculty working papers available on
their websites. They can be particularly good sources for theoretical work
in progress or for empirical work done by researchers not affiliated with
the NBER. For links to economics departments around the world, see
ideas.uqam.ca/EDIRC/index.html.
49 | Writing Economics
REFERENCES
Camerer, Colin F. and Thaler, Richard H. “Ultimatums, Dictators and
Manners.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Spring 1995, 9 (2), pp.
209–20.
Feldstein, Martin. “Social Security, Induced Retirement, and Aggregate
Capital Accumulation.” Journal of Political Economy, September-
October 1974, 82 (5), pp. 90526.
Freeman, Richard B. and Hall, Brian. “Permanent Homelessness in
America?” in R. B. Freeman, ed., Labor markets in action: Essays in
empirical economics. Cambridge and London: Harvard University
Press, 1989, pp. 13456.
Goldin, Claudia and Katz, Lawrence F. “Technology, Skill, and the Wage
Structure: Insights from the Past.” American Economic Review, May
1996, 86 (2), pp. 25257.
Griliches, Zvi. “Capital-Skill Complementarity.” Review of Economics and
Statistics, November 1969, 51 (4), pp. 46568.
Madrian, Brigitte C. “Employment -Based Health Insurance and Job
Mobility: Is There Evidence of Job-Lock?” The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, February 1994, 109 (1), pp. 2754.
Mankiw, Gregory N. Principles of economics. New York: The Dryden Press,
1997.
McCloskey, Donald. “Economical Writing.” Economic Inquiry, April 1985, 23
(2), pp. 187222.
Popkin, Samuel L. The rational peasant: the political economy of rural
society in Vietnam. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1979.
Robbins, Lionel. The nature and significance of economic science. London:
Macmillan Press, 1984.
Strunk, William Jr. and White, E. B. The elements of style. New York:
Macmillan Press, 1979.