1
April 16, 2020
Fiscal Stimulus Needed to Fight Recessions
Lessons From the Great Recession
By Chad Stone
The economy was in the longest expansion on record before the COVID-19 pandemic, but a
sharp decline in economic activity is now inevitable, with unemployment insurance claims
skyrocketing and many forecasters saying that the economy has already entered a recession. The last
recession — the Great Recession — was a stark reminder of the need to lessen the human hardship
and economic dislocation associated with a recession. It left key lessons for policymakers, who
should now use a wide array of available policy tools to keep this and future downturns as short and
shallow as possible.
Economists’ thinking about anti-recessionary policies has evolved in the last decade, informed in
part by the limits of conventional monetary policy that fighting the Great Recession revealed. This
experience generated renewed attention among policy economists to the importance of fiscal
stimulus (temporary increases in government spending and reductions in government revenues) in
supporting overall spending and employment when the economy weakens and preventing serious
and long-lasting damage when recessions do occur.
In March, lawmakers enacted three increasingly sizeable pieces of legislation to address the harm
that the pandemic and efforts to contain it are causing.
1
One of the most important lessons from the
Great Recession is that they should be prepared to do more. While the Great Recession measures
were substantial and prevented an even more severe recession, they ended prematurely and were
insufficient to promote a robust recovery. The protracted period of high unemployment and
underemployment after the economy stopped contracting and began to grow again in June 2009
continued to generate human hardship and hurt long-term growth. Because lawmakers did not
include provisions in the recently enacted coronavirus legislation to “trigger” additional stimulus
automatically, based on further deterioration in economic conditions, they must be prepared to
enact additional measures as conditions require and to ensure they remain in place until the recovery
is clearly underway.
The following account describes the importance of keeping recessions as short and shallow as
possible and how both the economy and economists’ views have changed since the Great Recession.
1
The Coronavirus Preparedness and Response Supplemental Appropriations Act, the Families First Coronavirus
Response Act, and the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security (CARES) Act.
1275 First Street NE, Suite 1200
Washington, DC 20002
Tel: 202-408-1080
Fax: 202-408-1056
www.cbpp.org
2
It then provides a set of principles and policies for fiscal stimulus informed by lessons learned in the
Great Recession and its aftermath. (This analysis provides background and general policy principles;
CBPP has also released a number of analyses directly addressing the needs of families hit hard by
COVID-19 and the resulting economic fallout.
2
)
In brief:
Recessions have profound human and economic costs. Prolonged unemployment harms not
only workers’ job prospects and lifetime earnings but also the health and well-being of them
and their families. Workers without a college degree and workers of color are the most
vulnerable to these adverse effects. Moreover, long unemployment spells and diminished
demand for goods and services in a recession erode job skills among unemployed workers and
reduce business investment, which can depress the economy’s productive capacity long past
the end of the recession.
Interest rates are considerably lower now than they were in the two decades leading up to the
Great Recession. The Federal Reserve has already exhausted the room it had for its standard
approach of cutting short-term interest rates to offset an economic downturn and stimulate a
recovery in response to COVID-19. The Fed is proceeding with unconventional measures to
support economic activity similar to those used in the Great Recession and its aftermath, as
well as significant emergency measures to stabilize financial markets in the pandemic. Yet,
fiscal measures are still required.
Fiscal policy has a greater role to play in fighting recessions and stimulating recoveries than
academic economists’ policy advice reflected prior to the Great Recession, especially in light
of the limits to conventional monetary policy. Strengthening the fiscal policy response to a
weakening economy requires more robust “automatic stabilizers” — the features of tax laws
and spending programs like unemployment insurance and the Supplemental Nutrition
Assistance Program (SNAP, formerly the Food Stamp Program) that automatically reduce
income losses and support consumer spending in a downturn — together with a willingness
of policymakers to enact additional temporary discretionary measures when the automatic
stabilizers alone are insufficient, as is the case now with the pandemic.
Fiscal stimulus is most effective if: 1) it is implemented as early as possible in a recession; 2) it
is directed to individuals and entities who will spend any additional resources they receive
quickly; 3) it errs on the side of being larger than ultimately necessary rather than smaller; and
4) its size and duration respond to changing circumstances.
Concerns that the United States does not have the “fiscal space— due to high levels of
deficits and debt — to enact robust fiscal stimulus to minimize the human and economic
costs of a recession are misguided. The United States has a long-term fiscal challenge, not an
immediate debt crisis. Deficit and debt concerns should go on the back burner in a recession.
The following are among the most important policies that meet the criteria for effective fiscal
stimulus:
o Providing additional weeks of unemployment insurance and raising the weekly benefit
level;
2
See “COVID-19: Responding to the Health and Economic Crisis,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities,
https://www.cbpp.org/covid-19-responding-to-the-health-and-economic-crisis.
3
o Raising the maximum SNAP benefit level and ensuring that unemployed adults have
access to food assistance;
o Providing state fiscal relief by reducing the percentage of Medicaid spending for which
states are responsible (by increasing the federal matching rate) and giving states, tribes,
and localities temporary block grants or other flexible funding to maintain needed
services such as education;
o Providing cash assistance to people facing economic insecurity through monthly or
one-time cash payments that can help address both emergencies and ongoing basic
needs, as well as through expansions of refundable tax credits;
o Implementing a subsidized jobs program for low-income workers, although the special
circumstances of COVID-19 require waiting until after the health crisis diminishes and
such programs can be undertaken safely; and
o Increasing housing assistance to prevent a sharp rise in evictions and homelessness.
A recession stemming from COVID-19 also requires additional measures to deal with unique
circumstances, but for many of the measures above, policymakers should design them not
only to provide robust immediate stimulus but also to permanently strengthen their function
as automatic stabilizers that trigger on early in future recessions, provide stimulus appropriate
to the magnitude of the downturn, and do not trigger off prematurely. Such trigger
mechanisms can ensure that needed stimulus measures are timely and that they neither end
prematurely nor remain in effect too long.
As noted above, if a recession turns out to be deeper or last longer than initially anticipated,
policymakers should be prepared to increase the size and/or duration of their fiscal policy
response, including, if needed, following up with additional discretionary stimulus.
4
5
Monetary and Fiscal Policy Before the Great Recession
Before the Great Recession, the prevailing view among academic economists was that monetary
policy should bear the primary responsibility for stabilizing economic activity, inflation, and
employment. Fiscal policy’s role was largely confined to the automatic stabilizers built into existing
tax laws and spending programs, such as progressive tax rates, unemployment insurance (UI), and
SNAP.
That view reflected experience during the two-decade-long period prior to the Great Recession in
which business-cycle fluctuations were significantly less volatile than in the previous four decades of
the post-World War II era due to what economists perceived to be better monetary policy.
3
It also
reflected a skepticism about policymakers’ ability to implement discretionary fiscal stimulus
measures in a timely manner, even among economists who believed prompt enactment of well-
designed measures could be effective in fighting recessions. (See box, “The Great Moderation,” for
more about this period.)
Consistent with that view, when signs began to emerge in late 2007 that the expansion following
the 2001 recession was threatened by weakness in the housing market and brewing turmoil in
financial markets stemming from problems in the subprime mortgage market, economists generally
emphasized that monetary policy should be the first line of defense. They argued that the Fed, which
had gradually raised its short-term interest rate target from 1 percent in mid-2004 to 5.25 percent in
June 2006, had ample room to cut interest rates to provide stimulus.
Economists who did not reject out of hand that fiscal policy could be helpful argued that any
discretionary stimulus measures should be timely (i.e., stimulate new spending early in the recession),
targeted (i.e., go to individuals and entities that would quickly spend any new resources they received),
and temporary (i.e., expire when stimulus was no longer needed, so as not to add unnecessarily to
budget deficits and debt without providing effective stimulus — or possibly even lead to
overheating if they provide stimulus for too long).
3
Craig S. Hakkio, “The Great Moderation,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, November 22, 2013,
https://www.federalreservehistory.org/essays/great_moderation.
6
These positions were echoed in early 2008 by then-Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, who testified
that the Fed had responded proactively by cutting its short-term interest rate target by a full
percentage point to 4.25 percent between September and December 2007. Bernanke said that
further cuts could be appropriate, and he agreed that well-designed fiscal measures could be helpful
but poorly designed measures would be counterproductive.
4
Economists Jason Furman and Douglas
Elmendorf similarly endorsed the priority of monetary policy and cautioned about the dangers of
fiscal measures that were poorly timed, badly targeted, or permanently increased the deficit. They
observed, however, that “if a sharp economic downturn appears imminent, and well-designed tax or
spending changes could be implemented quickly, such fiscal stimulus could boost economic activity
more quickly than monetary stimulus.”
5
A CBPP analysis added the recommendation that, to avoid
the costs of not being ready if the economy did fall into a recession, policymakers should
4
Ben S. Bernanke, “The economic outlook,” testimony before the House Budget Committee, January 17, 2008,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20080117a.htm.
5
Douglas W. Elmendorf and Jason Furman, “If, When, How: A Primer on Fiscal Stimulus,” Hamilton Project, January
2008, https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/06/0110_fiscal_stimulus_elmendorf_furman.pdf.
7
immediately assemble a stimulus package but wait for it to be triggered on by a specific indicator of
further deterioration in economic conditions.
6
Federal policymakers took reasonably timely steps early that year in response to evidence of a
rising risk of recession.
7
In February 2008, President Bush and the Democratic Congress enacted a
$152 billion package of individual income tax rebates, incentives to stimulate business investment,
and steps to address the subprime mortgage crisis. In a series of steps from January to May, the Fed
cut its interest rate target to 2 percent and adopted measures to contain the turmoil in financial
markets. In July, with unemployment about a percentage point higher than a year earlier, the
President and Congress enacted additional weeks of UI benefits.
In the second half of 2008, however, a meltdown in financial markets turned what might have
been only a mild downturn into the Great Recession.
Fiscal Policy Played a Prominent Role in the Great Recession
Unsustainable increases in bond and housing prices and excessive borrowing to purchase risky
assets led to the financial market meltdown in the summer and fall of 2008, which in turn further
weakened economic activity. As former Fed chair Janet Yellen, then President of the Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, explained in early 2009:
Once this massive credit crunch hit, it didn’t take long before we were in a recession. The
recession, in turn, deepened the credit crunch as demand and employment fell, and credit
losses of financial institutions surged. . . . Consumers [pulled] back on purchases, especially
on durable goods, to build their savings. Businesses [canceled] planned investments and
[laid] off workers to preserve cash. And, financial institutions [shrank] assets to bolster
capital and improve their chances of weathering the current storm.
8
The first step of re-establishing financial market stability fell largely to the Fed and the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corp., which acted to restore liquidity that had evaporated in the crisis due to
falling asset prices and the failure or near-failure of major financial institutions. Most notably,
Congress eventually agreed to the controversial Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP), which
established a $700 billion fund to give banks the capital they needed to continue to make loans.
To address the faltering economy, the Federal Reserve cut its target interest rate essentially to zero
between October and December 2008, when it adopted a target range of 0 to 0.25 percent, which it
6
Chad Stone and Kris Cox, “Economic Policy in a Weakening Economy,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities,
January 11, 2008, https://www.cbpp.org/research/principles-for-fiscal-stimulus-economic-policy-in-a-weakening-
economy.
7
The Business Cycle Dating Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research, a private organization, is the
recognized arbiter of business-cycle dating. In December 2008, the committee identified December 2007 as the starting
month of the recession, determining that the subsequent decline in economic activity was large enough to qualify as a
recession. National Bureau of Economic Research, “Determination of the December 2007 Peak in Economic Activity,
December 11, 2008, https://www.nber.org/cycles/dec2008.html.
8
Janet L. Yellen, “A Minsky Meltdown: Lessons for Central Bankers,” presentation at the 18
th
Annual Hyman P. Minsky
Conference on the State of the U.S. and World Economies, April 16, 2009, https://www.frbsf.org/our-
district/press/presidents-speeches/yellen-speeches/2009/april/yellen-minsky-meltdown-central-bankers/.
8
maintained for the next five years. With no room for further conventional monetary stimulus via
cuts in short-term interest rates, the Fed turned to unconventional measures, notably what would
eventually be three rounds of large-scale purchases of longer-term assets — a policy known as
quantitative easing — to try to lower longer-term interest rates and continue to provide needed
stimulus.
On the fiscal policy front, President Obama and Congress enacted the American Recovery and
Reinvestment Act (ARRA) in February 2009. ARRA’s roughly $830 billion of tax cuts and spending
measures were at the time by far the largest package of “Keynesian stimulus” in the post-World War
II era. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO), in its 2015 assessment of the impact of ARRA on
employment and output, grouped the various provisions into the following four broad categories:
9
Providing funds to states and localities — for example, by raising the federal government’s
share of Medicaid costs, providing funding for education costs, and increasing financial
support for some transportation projects;
Supporting people in need — such as by extending and expanding unemployment benefits
and increasing benefits under SNAP;
Purchasing goods and services — for instance, by funding construction and other investment
activities that could take several years to complete; and
Providing temporary tax relief for individuals and businesses — ranging from expansions of
the Earned Income and Child Tax Credits and a new Making Work Pay tax credit to creating
enhanced deductions for depreciation of business equipment and raising exemption amounts
for the alternative minimum tax (AMT).
Success of the Fiscal Response to the Great Recession
Economists Alan Blinder and Mark Zandi describe policymakers’ response to these developments
as a major reason why the Great Recession did not become the United States’ “Great Depression
2.0,” and why the United States fared much better than many other countries in the global economic
and financial crisis:
The policy responses to the financial crisis and the Great Recession were massive and
multifaceted. . . . Not only did they include the aggressive use of standard monetary and
fiscal policy tools, but new tools were invented and implemented on the fly in late 2008 and
early 2009. Some aspects of the response worked splendidly, while others fell far short of
hopes, and many were controversial — both in real time and even in retrospect. In total,
however, we firmly believe that the policies must be judged a success.
10
Neither TARP nor ARRA was successful politically, and not all of ARRA’s provisions — such as
AMT relief — satisfied the criteria for sound stimulus. But their positive effect on financial markets
9
Congressional Budget Office, “Estimated Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act on Employment
and Economic Output in 2014,” February 2015, https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/114th-congress-2015-
2016/reports/49958-ARRA.pdf.
10
Alan S. Blinder and Mark Zandi, “The Financial Crisis: Lessons for the Next One,” Center on Budget and Policy
Priorities, October 15, 2015, https://www.cbpp.org/research/economy/the-financial-crisis-lessons-for-the-next-one.
9
and the economy was crucial to turning the economy around in 2009. Output and employment
would have been significantly lower in the recession and early stages of the recovery without ARRA,
according to CBO’s analysis.
Economic activity as measured by real (inflation-adjusted) gross domestic product (GDP) was
contracting sharply when policymakers enacted TARP and ARRA (see Figure 1). The economy
stopped shrinking and began growing in mid-2009, and the expansion lasted more than a decade.
Job losses, which reached over three-quarters of a million a month in late 2008, began to shrink in
the spring of 2009, and private-sector job growth began an unbroken string of monthly job gains
from March 2010 through February 2020.
FIGURE 1
ARRA was designed to boost the demand for goods and services in order to stimulate growth and
preserve jobs in the recession and to create them in the early stages of the recovery. (See box, “How
ARRA Increased Output and Employment.”) GDP was higher and the unemployment rate lower
each year between 2009 and 2012 than they would have been without ARRA, with the largest impact
in 2010, CBO found.
GDP was between 0.7 and 4.1 percent higher in 2010 than it otherwise would have been, CBO
estimated (see Figure 2). The impact faded after 2010, as ARRA stimulus wound down, but CBO
estimated that even at the end of 2012, GDP was between 0.1 and 0.6 percent larger than it would
have been without ARRA.
10
FIGURE 2
Similarly, while CBO estimated that ARRA had the greatest effect on the unemployment rate in
2010 (see Figure 3), even in the fourth quarter of 2012, the unemployment rate was 0.1 to 0.4
percentage points lower than it otherwise would have been, and employment was between roughly
100,000 and 800,000 jobs greater than it otherwise would have been.
FIGURE 3
11
As discussed in the box “Keeping Recessions as Short and Shallow as Possible: Why It Matters,”
the human, social, and economic costs of recessions go well beyond the value of the goods and
services not produced and the income not earned, though these immediate economic losses were
quite large in the Great Recession. The cumulative gap between actual GDP and CBO’s high
estimate of how much lower GDP would have been without ARRA (the cumulative gap between
the blue line and the red dotted line in Figure 2) was about $1.3 trillion (in 2009 dollars). By reducing
job losses, ARRA saved the equivalent of 11 million full-time years of work, CBO estimated.
11
As large, timely, and reasonably well-targeted and effective as ARRA was, a rapid and robust
recovery from the Great Recession proved elusive. The output losses and jobs hole created by the
Great Recession were so large that an even larger stimulus package would have been required to
climb out more quickly. Indeed, the incoming Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers (CEA),
11
A full-time-equivalent employment year is 40 hours a week for a year. This measure treats two 20-hour-per week jobs
held for a full year as equivalent to a single 40-hour-per-week job held for a full year.
12
Christina Romer, suggested a larger package, but it was judged to be politically impractical.
12
President Obama proposed additional stimulus in subsequent budgets, but Congress agreed to only
modestly more stimulus.
In a 2012 assessment of ARRA, Romer acknowledged that it was too small and could have been
more effective but stated that over time, “the fiscal stimulus will be viewed as an important step at a
bleak moment in our history. Not the knockout punch the administration had hoped for, but a
valuable effort that improved the lives of many.”
13
Policymakers Must Use Fiscal Stimulus in a Recession
The CBO and Blinder-Zandi analyses bear out Romer’s belief that ARRA moderated the Great
Recession. Jason Furman, who served as CEA chair in the second Obama term, argues based on
recent fiscal stimulus research that “the tide of expert opinion” among policy-oriented economists
and international institutions such as the International Monetary Fund and the Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development was already shifting prior to the COVID-19 pandemic.
The “new view” of fiscal policy reverses most of the “old view” that prevailed leading up to the
Great Recession — and still may prevail among some policymakers, notwithstanding the bipartisan
and near-unanimous support for the CARES Act as a COVID-19 emergency measure.
14
Several policy shifts distinguish this new perspective, which features the following four principles:
1. Fiscal policy shouldn’t be subordinate to monetary policy. Furman argues that fiscal policy is
an essential tool to support aggregate demand and should not be subordinate to monetary policy, as
many considered it to be before the Great Recession. In response to COVID-19, the Fed has cut its
target interest-rate range from one that was already substantially lower than before the Great
Recession essentially to zero,
15
eliminating its room for conventional interest rate cuts to stimulate
aggregate demand in a weakening economy. Notwithstanding the significant quantitative easing and
financial-market stabilization measures the Fed is now taking, the CARES Act and other fiscal policy
measures are critical for fighting a COVID-19 recession, and fiscal policy will be a necessary
complement to monetary policy in any future recession.
16
12
Brad DeLong, “Romer Advised Obama To Push $1.8 Trillion Stimulus,” Economists View, February 16, 2012,
https://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2012/02/romer-advised-obama-to-push-18-trillion-
stimulus.html.
13
Christina D. Romer, “The Fiscal Stimulus, Flawed but Valuable,” New York Times, October 20, 2012,
https://www.nytimes.com/2012/10/21/business/how-the-fiscal-stimulus-helped-and-could-have-done-more.html.
14
Jason Furman, “The New View of Fiscal Policy and Its Application,” remarks delivered at the conference Global
Implications of Europe’s Redesign, October 5, 2016,
https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/sites/default/files/page/files/20161005_furman_suerf_fiscal_policy_cea.pdf.
15
In late 2008, when it had run out of room for further cuts in its target short-term interest rate, the Fed switched to a
quarter-point target range.
16
Before the pandemic, former Federal Reserve chair Ben Bernanke wrote that the new monetary policy tools used in
the Great Recession would be effective and could provide the equivalent of about 3 additional percentage points of
short-term rate cuts as long as interest rates are not too low, but he conceded that with very low interest rates, fiscal
policy would likely be necessary as well. Ben Bernanke, “The new tools of monetary policy,” 2020 American Economic
Association presidential address, January 4, 2020, https://www.brookings.edu/blog/ben-bernanke/2020/01/04/the-
new-tools-of-monetary-policy/.
13
2. Fiscal policy stimulates demand in a recession. Furman argues that evidence from the Great
Recession shows that discretionary fiscal policy can be highly effective at stimulating aggregate
demand when the Fed does not counter it by tightening. By stimulating economic growth while
interest rates are low, well-targeted, deficit-financed stimulus measures may even encourage new
investment despite increasing the deficit. This suggests that CBO’s high-end estimates of ARRA’s
effect on output and employment, described in the box above, are likely to be much closer to the
likely stimulus effects of those measures in a recession than its low-end estimates.
Recovery from the Great Recession was slowed by a premature turn toward budget austerity
beginning in 2010, when concerns about budget deficits and debt prevented policymakers from
adopting further needed stimulus. Instead, the winding down of ARRA spending became a drag on
growth in 2010-11, as Figure 1 shows. Congressional opposition to continuing fiscal stimulus in
order to promote a stronger recovery was fueled by the emergence of small-government populist
Tea Party sentiments and since-discredited academic evidence purporting to show that levels of debt
beyond a 90-percent-of-GDP-threshold were damaging to growth
17
and that cutting government
spending in a recession could increase growth
18
— contrary to the overwhelming evidence that
cutting spending or raising taxes in a recession is contractionary.
3. Fiscal space constrains stimulus less than previously thought. Furman rejects the idea that
the United States now faces a debt crisis that requires immediate austerity, noting that “fiscal
stimulus is less constrained by fiscal space than previously appreciated.” Fiscal space is the amount
of room a country has to increase deficits and debt without debt holders losing confidence and
provoking a debt crisis with spiking interest rates, falling government bond prices, and the risk of a
sharp contraction in economic activity. Furman does not call for abandoning fiscal responsibility,
but even before COVID-19 created the need for an urgent and robust response, he rejected the idea
that we - have, or are near to having, a debt crisis that precludes borrowing for stimulus in a
recession.
Both former CBO Director Douglas Elmendorf and current CBO Director Phillip Swagel agree
with that position, with Swagel stating last summer, “when there’s a financial crisis and a recession . .
. countries that respond with expansionary policy do better. And it looks like the United States has
the fiscal space to do that. . . . Interest rates are low. The federal government is able to borrow. So
[the debt situation] is not an immediate crisis. . . . It’s a long-term challenge.”
19
Similarly, Elmendorf wrote in the Washington Post last year, “Yes, we have a serious long-term debt
problem, but no, that problem does not make anti-recessionary budget policy impossible or
17
Chad Stone, After Reinhart-Rogoff, Reflections on the Relationship Between U.S. Debt and Economic Growth,”
Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, May 6, 2013, https://www.cbpp.org/blog/after-reinhart-rogoff-reflections-on-
the-relationship-between-us-debt-and-economic-growth.
18
Chad Stone, “Spend Less, Owe Less, Grow the Economy,” testimony before the Joint Economic Committee, June 21,
2011, https://www.cbpp.org/blog/chad-stone-on-the-fallacy-of-spend-less-owe-less-grow-the-economy.
19
NPR, CBO Predicts Budget Deficit Will Reach Nearly $1 Trillion This Year,” August 22, 2019,
https://www.npr.org/2019/08/22/753355117/cbo-predicts-budget-deficit-will-reach-nearly-1-trillion-this-year.
14
unwise.”
20
The fact that interest rates were at a historically low level and expected to remain so for
many years even at the time he was writing last summer led Elmendorf to the following conclusion,
which is even more true now:
Federal borrowing is thus less costly and creates less risk for the federal government than
many of us predicted several years ago — and, according to economic analyses, does less
harm to the economy even in the long run. In addition, the funds used as stimulus do not
disappear: They support government spending for public goods and services, or they lower
taxes so that households have more resources for their private activities.
In sum, we have plenty of capacity in the federal budget to undertake vigorous
countercyclical tax and spending policies when the next recession arrives. Given the economic
and social costs of recessions, we should undertake such policies (emphasis added).
4. Sustained fiscal expansion could be necessary. The low-interest-rate environment and the
experience with sluggish recoveries from the Great Recession and the milder recessions in 1990-
1991 and 2001 lead to the fourth principle in the new view of fiscal policy: it may be desirable to
pursue sustained fiscal expansion.
Before the Great Recession, economists who were sympathetic to fiscal stimulus in principle were
hesitant to recommend it in practice due to concerns that delays in recognizing the need and
enacting the necessary legislation would delay the stimulus from taking effect until monetary
stimulus had already kicked in and the economy was recovering at a reasonable pace. That could
potentially be destabilizing and lead the Fed to raise interest rates to prevent overheating, largely
offsetting the stimulus. The net result would simply be an unnecessary increase in debt to finance
stimulus that was no longer needed and the Fed had largely offset.
In today’s low-interest-rate global economy, however, the case for more sustained stimulus in the
face of deficient aggregate demand is much stronger, especially if the stimulus takes the form of
productive investment.
21
The Great Recession wreaked long-lasting damage on the economy’s
productive capacity, as a result of the sharp contraction in productive investment and the effects of
long-term unemployment on workers’ skills, employment prospects, labor force participation, and
earnings, as described earlier. Stronger and more sustained fiscal stimulus could have attenuated
these effects substantially. Avoiding additional damage due to COVID-19 is now essential.
22
20
Douglas Elmendorf, “Yes, we still have the fiscal capacity to deal with a recession,” Washington Post, September 3,
2019, https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/yes-we-still-have-the-fiscal-capacity-to-deal-with-a-
recession/2019/09/03/2f5081b4-c8f0-11e9-a4f3-c081a126de70_story.html.
21
Brad DeLong, Larry Summers, and Laurence Ball, “Fiscal Policy and Full Employment,” Center on Budget and Policy
Priorities, April 2, 2014, https://www.cbpp.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/4-2-14fe-delong.pdf.
22
See Heather Boushey, Washington Center for Equitable Growth; Robert Greenstein, Center on Budget and Policy
Priorities; Neera Tanden, Center for American Progress; and Felicia Wong, Roosevelt Institute, “Commentary: Deficit
and Debt Shouldn’t Factor Into Coronavirus Recession Response,” March 19, 2020,
https://www.cbpp.org/research/economy/commentary-deficit-and-debt-shouldnt-factor-into-coronavirus-recession-
response: “We face a once-in-a-generation hopefully once-in-a-lifetime crisis, with the risk of tens of millions of
infections and mounting numbers of deaths, an overwhelmed hospital system that can’t respond adequately, large
numbers of businesses closing or cutting back, millions of workers losing their jobs or having their hours slashed, and
15
Designing Effective Stimulus
Stimulus measures must be well-designed to stimulate aggregate demand in a cost-effective way.
The principles for designing effective stimulus under the new view of fiscal policy are similar in
many ways to those captured in the “timely, targeted, and temporarycatch-phrase prevalent in
2008, but they should be updated to reflect changed circumstances — including COVID-19 — and
lessons learned from the Great Recession.
23
To be most effective stimulus should be:
Implemented early. Fiscal stimulus should be implemented as early as possible in a recession.
Measures like cash or SNAP payments for those in the greatest need delivered early in a recession
stimulate new spending quickly, lessening the extent to which businesses cut back on production or
lay off workers due to weak demand. Tax cuts that will be saved in large part rather than spent
quickly, in contrast, do little to bolster demand. Increased outlays in government investment
programs that spend out slowly don’t immediately boost aggregate demand, but they can be helpful
in getting back to full employment more quickly, thereby reducing the human costs and preventing
the harm to future growth a sluggish recovery could cause.
Well targeted. Measures targeted on individuals and entities that will quickly spend the bulk of
any new resources they receive have a high bang for the buck in stimulating aggregate demand (see
box, “How ARRA Increased Output and Employment”). Such individuals include unemployed
workers and people of modest means, in contrast to higher-income individuals and households, who
will save a large portion of any additional income.
Fiscal relief for state governments is another well-targeted form of stimulus. Faced with declining
tax receipts and looming deficits when the economy slows, states respond by raising taxes and
cutting back on spending, especially for health care, education, and aid to local governments. States
have little alternative, since almost all are required to balance their operating budgets in bad
economic years as well as good ones. But such actions further reduce demand in the economy and
deepen the recession. Federal fiscal relief that enables states to minimize such spending cuts and tax
increases thus helps prop up the economy in a time of weakness.
Bold in size and scope and responsive to changing conditions. Fiscal stimulus is a response
to temporary weakness in the economy. The country should not be stuck with permanent, deficit-
increasing tax cuts or spending increases because of a temporary economic downturn — but neither
should stimulus measures be terminated prematurely, as happened with ARRA. When the economy weakens,
avoiding a serious recession and its attendant social and economic costs should be policymakers’ top
priority, and recent slow recoveries suggest that the costs of erring on the side of providing too
much stimulus are less than the costs of providing too little — especially in today’s low-interest-rate
environment.
serious hardship all across our land. Deficits and debt pose no comparable risk. Policymakers should set aside their
concerns about red ink and deliver the response the crisis demands.
23
See Jason Furman, “The Case for a Big Coronavirus Stimulus,” Wall Street Journal, March 5, 2020,
https://www.wsj.com/articles/the-case-for-a-big-coronavirus-stimulus-11583448500.
16
A more robust set of automatic stabilizers would vary the size and duration of stimulus
automatically in response to changing economic conditions. In a recession, however, policymakers
also should be prepared to provide additional discretionary stimulus as needed.
The temporary measures enacted to fight the Great Recession added to the debt, and interest on
that higher debt added modestly to future deficits, but economic stimulus played only a minor role
in the rise in deficits and debt since 2001.
24
While it might be ideal in a non-crisis atmosphere to pair
stimulus measures with other measures that pay for the stimulus once the economy is strong
enough, the search for the latter in a politically fraught or crisis environment should not stand in the
way of enacting needed stimulus to keep a recession as short and shallow as possible.
The CARES Act and other measures policymakers have taken thus far in the pandemic largely
satisfy these criteria. CARES includes essential measures to respond to the public health and
economic crises, though more will be needed. The CARES Act measures are in effect only for
temporary periods, such as through the end of the year, and lack provisions for extending them as
economic conditions warrant. They also lack key elements such as a SNAP benefit increase and an
emergency fund modeled after the successful TANF Emergency Fund in place during the Great
Recession. Furthermore, the increase in the federal share of state Medicaid costs provided in the
previous COVID-19 response legislation is smaller than the increase provided in the Great
Recession and ends at the end of the public health emergency, neither continuing nor increasing if
the economy worsens.
25
Plan to Use Triggers to Turn Stimulus On and Off
Well-designed stimulus measures should “trigger on” as early as possible and “trigger off” once a
robust recovery is clearly underway. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), the
recognized arbiter of business-cycle dating, does not provide a determination of when a recession
started until well after that date, and only after examining and comparing several measures of
economic activity over many months. And, as discussed above, in recent business cycles, the formal
end of a recession has been followed by an extended period of sluggish growth and persistent slack
during which fiscal stimulus would still be beneficial, rather than the sharp rebound and robust
recovery characteristic of most earlier post–World War II recessions.
Thus, the NBER’s dating of business-cycle peaks and troughs is not a reliable real-time indicator
of when to start or end stimulus. Economist Claudia Sahm has shown, however, that a reliable early
indicator that the economy is in a recession is when the three-month average unemployment rate is
0.5 percentage points higher than its level in any of the previous 12 months. That indicator has
occurred early in every recession back to the 1970s and has never given a false reading indicating a
recession when none has followed.
24
Kathy Ruffing and Joel Friedman, “Economic Downturn and Legacy of Bush Policies Continue to Drive Large
Deficits,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, February 28, 2013, https://www.cbpp.org/research/economic-
downturn-and-legacy-of-bush-policies-continue-to-drive-large-deficits?fa=view&id=3849.
25
Sharon Parrott et al., “CARES Act Includes Essential Measures to Respond to Public Health, Economic Crises, But
More Will Be Needed,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, March 27, 2020,
https://www.cbpp.org/research/economy/cares-act-includes-essential-measures-to-respond-to-public-health-
economic-crises.
17
In more typical circumstances,
26
this indicator, now known as the “Sahm rule,”
27
is a good
indicator for triggering on a package of stimulus measures that ideally has already been enacted and
is ready to go. There also should be a trigger for turning off or phasing out such stimulus measures
when, but only when, a robust recovery is underway. That trigger may be different for particular
stimulus measures. In many cases, however, meeting all three of the following conditions would be a
reasonable triggering off criterion:
the three-month average unemployment rate has fallen for two straight months (in order to
guard against cutting off stimulus before unemployment has peaked);
the three-month average unemployment rate is below a specified threshold level for two
straight months (so as not to cut off stimulus when unemployment is still highly elevated); and
the three-month average unemployment rate is less than 1.5 percentage points higher than its
rate when the measure was triggered on.
In the case of the CARES Act, where measures are already in place but expire by the end of the
year, it is important that policymakers avoid prematurely withdrawing needed support for the
economy and those facing hardship. Triggers based on economic conditions, not arbitrary calendar
dates, should determine the extent and duration of stimulus measures.
To prepare for future recessions, policymakers could strengthen the existing automatic stabilizers
by embedding the Sahm rule in the statutes that provide such benefits, such as by providing
additional federally funded weeks of unemployment insurance, a bump in SNAP benefit levels, and
an increase in the federal matching rate for state Medicaid expenditure when the Sahm-rule trigger
signals that the economy is in a recession.
Effective Stimulus Measures
A core set of measures would provide effective fiscal stimulus to bolster aggregate demand and
reduce economic hardship in recessions. The following discussion offers general principles for
designing effective stimulus in those core areas.
One caveat: Puerto Rico participates fully in the unemployment insurance system, but instead of
receiving federal funding for its nutrition assistance program sufficient to serve all eligible people
who apply and having a fixed percentage of its Medicaid costs covered by the federal government, as
a state would, Puerto Rico instead gets capped block grants for Medicaid and nutrition assistance
that don’t rise automatically when need increases in a recession. ARRA and the CARES Act
included provisions to increase assistance for Puerto Rico in the troubled periods these pieces of
26
The sharp drop in economic activity due to the pandemic is unprecedented and will show up in economic indicators
with a lag, but policymakers’ early actions render the question of when the pandemic-induced recession started moot.
The pandemic experience does not invalidate the value of the Sahm rule as an indicator of future recessions.
27
Claudia Sahm, “Roundtable Discussion: Providing Direct Payments to Households as Fiscal Stimulus,” remarks at the
forum Preparing for the Next Recession: Policies to Reduce the Impact on the U.S. Economy, May 16, 2019,
https://www.hamiltonproject.org/events/preparing_for_the_next_recession_policies_to_reduce_the_impact_on_the_u
.s; and Heather Boushey, Ryan Nunn, and Jay Shambaugh, “Recession ready: Fiscal policies to stabilize the American
economy,” Brookings Institution, May 16, 2019, https://www.brookings.edu/multi-chapter-report/recession-ready-
fiscal-policies-to-stabilize-the-american-economy/.
18
legislation cover, and so should subsequent stimulus packages that Congress is likely to work on in
the months ahead. But Puerto Rico, whose economy has been struggling for years, has undergone
the largest municipal bankruptcy in U.S. history, and has been devastated further by recent natural
disasters, ultimately needs stronger safety net programs on an ongoing basis,
28
not just
accommodations in stimulus packages.
Additional measures are also likely to be needed to address challenging idiosyncratic problems
associated with particular crises, such as distressed homeowners in the mortgage crisis and Great
Recession
29
and, most vividly, the health care costs and income losses due to quarantines and
business shutdowns in the pandemic.
Unemployment Insurance
Unemployment insurance provides well-targeted fiscal stimulus and scores high in bang for the
buck. Substantial reforms to the UI program, however, would improve its coverage and make it a
stronger fiscal stimulus measure.
States run the basic UI program, while the U.S. Department of Labor oversees the system. The
basic program in most states provides up to 26 weeks of benefits to unemployed workers, replacing
about half of their previous wages, up to a maximum benefit amount that each state sets. States
provide most of the funding for those benefits through taxes paid by employers; the federal
government pays only the administrative costs.
Although states are subject to a few federal requirements, they are generally able to set their own
eligibility criteria and benefit levels. In recent years, for example, a handful of states have reduced
their maximum number of weeks of regular UI benefits below 26 weeks. This has weakened the
protections UI provides workers experiencing long unemployment spells and has reduced UI’s
effectiveness as stimulus when the economy is weak.
UI was established in 1935 and has not adapted adequately to subsequent changes in the labor
market. When UI was designed, the typical job loser was a married male breadwinner laid off from a
full-time job to which he could expect to return when business picked up. But in the 21
st
-century
labor market, the program’s outdated eligibility requirements often exclude people such as part-time
workers and those who must leave work for compelling family reasons, like caring for an ill family
member. This prevents large numbers of unemployed workers, many of whom are women and
people of color, from receiving UI benefits.
28
See Brynne Keith-Jennings and Elizabeth Wolkomir, “How Does Household Food Assistance in Puerto Rico
Compare to the Rest of the United States?” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, January 15, 2020,
https://www.cbpp.org/research/food-assistance/how-is-food-assistance-different-in-puerto-rico-than-in-the-rest-of-
the; and Judith Solomon, “Puerto Rico’s Medicaid Program Needs an Ongoing Commitment of Federal Funds,” Center
on Budget and Policy Priorities, April 22, 2019, https://www.cbpp.org/research/health/puerto-ricos-medicaid-
program-needs-an-ongoing-commitment-of-federal-funds.
29
Blinder and Zandi conclude that the policy responses to the mortgage crisis involving loan modifications and
refinancings were “underfinanced, under-promoted, and not effectively managed,” and hence,While the program
helped some, it fell well short of both expectations and needs.” Blinder and Zandi, op. cit.
19
Nor does UI respond as effectively as it could to provide additional weeks of benefits in an
economic downturn, when unemployed workers are more likely to exhaust their regular state UI
benefits. UI’s Extended Benefits (EB) program provides an additional 13 or 20 weeks of benefits to
jobless workers who have exhausted their regular UI benefits in states where the unemployment
situation has worsened dramatically (regardless of whether the national economy is in recession).
The total number of weeks of EB available in a state depends on the severity of unemployment in
the state and its unemployment insurance laws. Normally, the federal government and the states split
the cost of EB.
When a state’s economy weakens, regular state UI caseloads expand and at some point EB may
kick in, supporting unemployed workers’ and their families’ incomes and spending. In practice,
however, the criteria for EB to trigger on are so stringent that federal policymakers have had to
enact temporary programs providing additional weeks of UI benefits on an ad hoc basis in national
recessions since the late 1970s. The temporary discretionary measures enacted in the Great
Recession, for example, included extra weeks of benefits and full federal funding of EB from mid-
2008 through 2013, as well as a federally funded $25 increase in weekly UI benefits in 2009-10.
As discussed earlier, the stimulus to demand from an expanding UI caseload and additional weeks
of UI benefits helped prevent an even sharper drop in spending during the Great Recession and its
immediate aftermath. However, temporary federal UI stimulus needed to be reauthorized
periodically — which became increasingly contentious politically — and it expired at the end of
2013, even though there was still considerable unemployment and underemployment at the time and
economic activity was recovering relatively slowly. In addition, out-of-date eligibility criteria and the
reduction in the maximum number of weeks of regular UI benefits in some states limited the
expansion of caseloads in the Great Recession and hence the amount of stimulus UI could provide.
To strengthen UI as a stimulus measure — as well as to meet UI’s primary purpose of supporting
eligible workers (and their families) who’ve lost their jobs through no fault of their own — the
criteria for receiving UI benefits should be modernized to reflect 21
st
-century labor market
conditions, which would result in a larger share of the jobless receiving benefits and hence boost the
total amount of automatic stimulus in a recession.
The Obama Administration’s 2017 budget proposal
30
and a collaboration among the Center for
American Progress, the National Employment Law Project, and the Georgetown Law Center on
Poverty and Inequality
31
both provide blueprints for comprehensive reform of the UI system,
including modernizing eligibility and reforming EB not only to improve protections for workers but
also to strengthen the fiscal stimulus UI can provide. (These proposals also include UI solvency
reforms to ensure that states build up reserves during good economic times and are better prepared
to fund regular benefits when unemployment rises.)
The CARES Act provides robust changes to UI that temporarily expand eligibility and, for four
months, raise benefit levels substantially, but new legislation will be required to extend these
30
Chad Stone, “Obama Budget Modernizes Policies for Unemployed Workers,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities,
February 11, 2016, https://www.cbpp.org/blog/obama-budget-modernizes-policies-for-unemployed-workers.
31
Rachel West et al., “Strengthening Unemployment Protections in America,” Center for American Progress, June 2016,
https://cdn.americanprogress.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/05/31134245/UI_JSAreport.pdf.
20
provisions beyond the current year.
32
Comprehensive UI reform that broadens eligibility and
strengthens UI’s role as an automatic stabilizer is necessary to be better prepared for future
recessions.
SNAP
SNAP provides nutritional support for low-wage working families and unemployed individuals,
low-income seniors, and people with disabilities living on fixed incomes. The federal government
pays the full cost of SNAP benefits and splits the cost of administering the program with the states,
which operate the program. SNAP eligibility rules and benefit levels are, for the most part, set at the
federal level and uniform across the nation, though states have flexibility to tailor aspects of the
program.
Like UI, SNAP benefits are spent quickly and therefore provide high bang-for-the-buck stimulus
in a weak economy. SNAP caseloads also expand and contract with the level of economic activity as
more people’s income falls below the income threshold for eligibility in a recession and more
people’s income rises above it in an expansion.
The SNAP benefit formula targets food assistance according to need: very poor households
receive larger payments than households with somewhat more income since they need more help
affording an adequate diet. The benefit formula assumes that families will spend 30 percent of their
disposable income for food; SNAP makes up the difference between that 30 percent contribution
and the SNAP “maximum benefit,” which is set at the cost of the Thrifty Food Plan, the Agriculture
Department’s estimate of a very low-cost but nutritionally adequate diet. In 2018 the typical family
with children received $387 a month in SNAP benefits; a typical one-person household received
$130 a month.
Some people are not eligible for SNAP regardless of how small their income and assets may be,
such as striking workers, many college students, and certain immigrants with lawful immigration
status. Immigrants with undocumented status also are ineligible for SNAP.
In addition, adults without a disability who are aged 18 through 49 and aren’t employed at least 20
hours a week or participating in a qualifying workfare or job training program (and don’t have
dependents in the home) are limited to three months of benefits in a 36-month period. States can
waive this rule in areas with high unemployment. During the Great Recession and its aftermath, that
time limit was either suspended (for 2009 and 2010 under a provision of ARRA) or waived in most
states due to high unemployment.
Until recently, states qualified for waivers during and immediately after a recession when UI
Extended Benefits were triggered on in the state. In late 2019, however, the Trump Administration
32
See the section on UI in Sharon Parrott et al., “Immediate and Robust Policy Response Needed in Face of Grave Risks
to the Economy,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, March 19, 2020,
https://www.cbpp.org/research/economy/immediate-and-robust-policy-response-needed-in-face-of-grave-risks-to-the-
economy.
21
finalized an administrative rule that sharply limits such waivers, even in a recession.
33
If the new
policy goes into effect, the EB criterion will no longer be allowed as a qualification for state waivers,
and very few areas will qualify during economic downturns.
34
SNAP experienced large growth during and after the Great Recession. Caseloads expanded
significantly between 2007 and 2011 as the recession and sluggish economic recovery dramatically
increased the number of low-income households that qualified and applied for help. In addition to
the automatic stimulus from caseload growth, ARRA raised the level of maximum SNAP benefits by
13.6 percent beginning in April 2009, with the intention of keeping benefits at that new level until
the value of the Thrifty Food Plan caught up through normal food-price inflation. Because of very
low food price inflation (in fact, deflation in some years), the cost of the plan grew more slowly than
expected and policymakers ended the supplement to benefits in November 2013. While they were in
effect, these payments delivered $40 billion in high bang-for-the-buck economic stimulus on top of
the increase in SNAP outlays due to the growth in caseloads.
Both a provision allowing states to seek waivers to raise SNAP benefits for some households and
a suspension of the three-month time limit for unemployed adults not raising minor children are in
the Families First Coronavirus Response Act, but last only through the pandemic emergency
period.
35
A measure to raise the maximum SNAP benefit, comparable to the ARRA provision, is still
needed and should be designed to remain in effect while the economy remains weak and
unemployment remains elevated. In addition, to be ready for future recessions, policymakers should
enact legislation that provides for an increase in maximum SNAP benefits and suspension of the
three-month time limit that would be triggered on automatically when the economy slides and then
triggered off automatically when the economy recovers.
State Fiscal Relief
In a recession, state budget receipts fall, and rising unemployment and poverty increase the
demands on state-provided services that assist people in need, including the state share of Medicaid
costs. Many of the actions that states must take to achieve budget balance in the face of falling
revenues — cutting services, laying off workers, and raising taxes — further weaken the economy.
33
Chad Stone, “Trump Rule Weakens SNAP’s Recession-Fighting Power,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities,
December 11, 2019, https://www.cbpp.org/blog/trump-rule-weakens-snaps-recession-fighting-power.
34
The Families First Coronavirus Response Act suspends the time limit, but only during the public health emergency
period of the pandemic and not through the duration of the recession. However, a federal district court on March 13,
2020 issued a nationwide injunction blocking the new rule from taking effect until the court decides whether the
rule restricts state flexibility beyond what the law allows. The Trump Administration has indicated that it plans to appeal
the court ruling. See Ed Bolen, “Unemployed Workers Can Get SNAP During Health Emergency,” Center on Budget
and Policy Priorities, April 2, 2020, https://www.cbpp.org/blog/unemployed-workers-can-get-snap-during-health-
emergency.
35
See the section on SNAP in Parrott et al., “CARES Act Includes Essential Measures to Respond to Public Health,
Economic Crises, But More Will Be Needed” and Dottie Rosenbaum et al., “USDA, States Must Act Swiftly to Deliver
Food Assistance Allowed by Families First Act,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, updated April 7, 2020,
https://www.cbpp.org/research/food-assistance/usda-states-must-act-swiftly-to-deliver-food-assistance-allowed-by-
families.
22
Federal financial assistance to states can mitigate these effects. Direct federal grants to states can
provide fiscal relief in a recession that helps states meet their balanced budget requirements without
having to go as far in enacting contractionary policies that lengthen and deepen the recession. The
approach taken in the last two recessions included, as one of the key fiscal relief measures,
temporarily increasing the federal government’s share of the costs that states incur in operating
Medicaid, the public insurance program that provides health coverage to low-income families and
individuals.
Medicaid is funded jointly by the federal government and the states. Each state operates its own
Medicaid program within federal guidelines. Because the federal guidelines are broad, states have a
great deal of flexibility in designing and administering their programs. As a result, Medicaid eligibility
and benefits can and often do vary widely from state to state. States are guaranteed federal Medicaid
matching funds for the costs of covered services furnished to eligible individuals, but states have
relatively broad discretion to determine who is eligible, what services they will cover, and what they
will pay for covered services.
The federal government contributes at least a dollar in matching funds for every dollar a state
spends on Medicaid. The fixed percentage that the federal government pays, known as the Federal
Medical Assistance Percentage (FMAP), varies by state, with the federal government shouldering a
larger share of the costs in poorer states than in wealthier ones. In the poorest state, the federal
government pays well over 70 percent of Medicaid service costs. In addition, the federal government
pays 90 percent of the costs for care provided under the Medicaid expansion provision of the
Affordable Care Act in states that have adopted the expansion. The federal share of Medicaid
expenses used to be about 57 percent overall in a typical year but has increased to over 60 percent
with the expansion.
36
In the 2001 downturn, Congress gave $20 billion in fiscal relief to the states, half in the form of
enhanced Medicaid matching rates and half in a block grant distributed among the states on a per-
capita basis. That relief was not enacted until May 2003, however, more than two years after the start
of the recession, by which time virtually all states were experiencing budget deficits. That delay
reduced the effectiveness of the fiscal relief in averting cuts in vital programs such as Medicaid and
education and in lessening the adverse effects that such state budget actions were having on the
economy.
State fiscal relief in the Great Recession was enacted more quickly as part of ARRA. That relief
included an increase in the Medicaid FMAP and a “State Fiscal Stabilization Fund” that provided
two block grants for states — a $39.5-billion grant earmarked for education and an $8.8-billion grant
to help fund other key services. States could use the flexible block grants to avert budget cuts in
education or other basic state services, such as public safety and law enforcement, services for the
elderly and people with disabilities, and child care. Those funds could also be used for school
modernization, renovation, or repair.
36
Alison Mitchell,Medicaid’s Federal Medical Assistance Percentage (FMAP),” Congressional Research Service, April
25, 2018, https://fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/R43847.pdf, p.11.
23
The CARES Act contains significant new resources to help states address massive budget
problems due to COVID-19, though states will need more aid in coming months.
37
The FMAP
increase in the Families First Coronavirus Response Act lasts only through the health emergency
period. A larger increase in the FMAP of longer duration, as well as a more robust stabilization fund,
are necessary.
38
In addition, to be ready for future recessions, policymakers should enact legislation
that provides for an increase in the FMAP and a stabilization fund that would be triggered on
automatically in a national recession and for states experiencing high unemployment when there is
not a national recession.
Stimulus Payments to Individuals and Families
Direct cash assistance to low- and moderate-income households is one of the most well targeted
stimulus measures because it goes to people who will quickly spend almost all of any additional
income they receive, generating high bang for the buck. Either one-time, lump-sum payments or a
refundable tax credit (under which taxpayers whose tax liability is less than the amount of the credit
receive a cash payment for the difference) are suitable delivery mechanisms for a large share of the
population. Low-income people not required to file a tax return can be identified if they are
receiving benefits such as Social Security, Supplemental Security Income, or veterans’ benefits that
are administered by the federal government, and likely also if they receive benefits administered
through state social service agencies. In addition to its role in providing stimulus, direct cash
assistance for low- and moderate-income households directly addresses the human costs of
recessions by helping ensure that individuals and families have enough income to meet basic needs
in particularly tough times.
In theory, temporary middle-class tax cuts are less stimulative because recipients are less cash
constrained and are not likely to change their consumption dramatically in response to a temporary
increase in income, although some evidence suggests one-time cash rebates may stimulate one-time
purchases of, or be used as a down payment for, big-ticket items such as new appliances or a car.
Temporary tax cuts for high-income taxpayers have little bang for the buck because high-income
taxpayers are least likely to increase their spending substantially in response to a temporary boost to
their income.
The Economic Stimulus Act, enacted in February 2008, delivered one-time income tax rebates
and payments to tax filers who had at least $3,000 in earnings in 2007 or 2008, and to people who
received Social Security benefits or veterans’ payments. These rebates were phased out for high-
income taxpayers. ARRA then followed with a “Making Work Pay” refundable tax credit for the
2009 and 2010 tax years, in the form of reduced income-tax withholding over the course of the year,
although the saliency of the tax cut to many taxpayers seems to have been less than if they had
received it as a lump sum payment. The Making Work Pay tax credit was replaced in 2011 and 2012
by a 2-percentage-point cut in the payroll tax, which delivers stimulus in a less well targeted way than
does a refundable credit.
37
“How Will States and Localities Divide the Fiscal Relief in the Coronavirus Relief Fund?” Center on Budget and
Policy Priorities, March 27, 2020, https://www.cbpp.org/research/state-budget-and-tax/how-will-states-and-localities-
divide-the-fiscal-relief-in-the.
38
See the section on strengthening health care and providing states with needed fiscal relief in Parrott et al., “CARES Act
Includes Essential Measures to Respond to Public Health, Economic Crises, But More Will Be Needed.”
24
ARRA also made temporary changes to the Child Tax Credit and the Earned Income Tax Credit
(EITC), both refundable credits.
39
The changes lowered the earnings threshold for the Child Tax
Credit from $12,550 to $3,000, which enabled families with earnings in that range to receive a partial
credit and many other low-income families to receive a larger credit. This change was well targeted at
families with low earnings who were most likely to spend the additional funds. The EITC is
designed to reach individuals of modest means, so expansions of it during a recession generate high
bang for the buck. ARRA increased the EITC for families with three or more children and provided
a larger tax credit to married couples, which lessened marriage penalties.
Expansions of the Child Tax Credit and EITC to respond to an economic downturn can be
further tailored to reach the lowest-income individuals, enhancing these measures’ effectiveness as
stimulus. Making the full $2,000-per-child Child Tax Credit available to families without requiring
them to meet a minimum earnings threshold would enable the credit to reach families with very low
or no earnings, who have the highest likelihood of spending the funds quickly but who currently
receive only a partial Child Tax Credit or no credit at all, due to their very low income. In addition,
increasing the EITC for workers without children at home would reach substantially more low-
income workers, who are particularly susceptible to losing income during recessions such as by
having their hours reduced or losing part-time jobs as businesses cut back.
The stimulus payments in the CARES Act are available to low- and moderate-income households,
including those without earnings and those that do not file tax returns. But the Act left out key
groups, including many immigrants, large numbers of whom are on the front lines in the COVID-19
pandemic delivering food, providing health care services, and caring for the elderly. The CARES Act
also didn’t provide sufficient direction to ensure that Treasury will use all existing means to get these
payments to eligible households automatically rather than requiring them to file tax returns.
40
The
Treasury should aggressively use the authority the CARES Act provides, and any upcoming
legislation should fill the holes and improve delivery.
A recession heightens the importance of improvements in and further expansions of eligibility for
the Child Tax Credit and EITC, especially for the lowest-income workers and families currently left
out of the full credits. Such improvements would deliver high bang-for-the-buck stimulus and, if
made permanent, also could strengthen these credits’ role as automatic stabilizers.
Emergency Cash Assistance and Subsidized Jobs
The number of people facing deep economic insecurity because they are unable to find steady
work rises in a recession. Many of these people normally don’t qualify for unemployment insurance,
which over the past decade reached less than 30 percent of the unemployed. And while the
Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) program can provide cash assistance to families
with children with very low incomes, TANF is a fixed block grant whose resources fail to expand in
39
These changes were made permanent in 2015.
40
See the section on direct payments to households in Parrott et al., “CARES Act Includes Essential Measures to
Respond to Public Health, Economic Crises, But More Will Be Needed.”
25
a recession despite rising need. Moreover, TANF benefits in most states are very low and have
eroded substantially in value over time.
41
Policymakers should be ready to address the rising number of people facing deep economic
insecurity in a recession by designing a program that supplements TANF with additional grants to
states to help address emergent and ongoing basic needs of low-income households, especially those
facing financial crisis. Ideally, such a program would be enacted and ready to go when triggered on
by the Sahm rule and then be triggered off in the same way that UI Extended Benefits would be.
Unlike TANF, which is limited to families with children, this assistance should also be available to
other low-income individuals who otherwise meet the state’s TANF eligibility criteria.
The TANF Emergency Fund in ARRA provided funding that states could use in 2009 and 2010
to deliver cash assistance to help families meet basic needs, provide emergency assistance to help
avert family crises, and create subsidized jobs for both parents and youth. The flexibility afforded
states allowed them to quickly deploy resources to families, reducing harm that might otherwise have
occurred. A signature feature of the fund was its subsidized jobs program, which an assessment
found succeeded in engaging the private sector in creating meaningful employment for large
numbers of individuals who would otherwise have been unemployed. It showed that “unemployed
individuals in large numbers will seize the opportunity to work when given a paying job.”
42
Together, an emergency cash assistance fund and a subsidized jobs program would provide
needed income support to populations with limited assets and labor market prospects in a recession
and stimulate economic activity in their local economies.
The CARES Act does not include anything akin to the TANF Emergency Fund in ARRA, leaving
it up to states to fund any additional assistance that families and individuals may need to meet their
basic needs, which only a few states have done. Some families and individuals in need of ongoing
assistance will be helped by the Pandemic Unemployment Assistance benefits in the CARES Act or
the expansion of grants to address and prevent homelessness, but many others will not. For the
future, emergency assistance and subsidized jobs measures should be ready in advance to go into
effect when the Sahm rule indicates a recession is under way.
Housing Assistance to Prevent a Sharp Rise in Evictions and Homelessness
People experiencing homelessness are at greater risk of contracting illnesses. They struggle to
address chronic health conditions and experience worse mental health, exacerbated by the stress and
trauma of being without a home. Families with children who are without a home face additional
challenges ensuring that their children regularly attend school, have a safe place to do homework,
can access nutritional meals, and receive needed health services.
Recessions lead to increased risks of evictions and homelessness. Measures that help people
remain housed and safe moderate the increase in human hardship and suffering. They also provide
41
Ashley Burnside and Ife Floyd, “Policy Brief: More States Raising TANF Benefits to Boost Families’ Economic
Security,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, December 9, 2019, https://www.cbpp.org/research/family-income-
support/policy-brief-despite-recent-increases-in-some-states-tanf-cash.
42
LaDonna Pavetti, “The Legacy of the TANF Emergency Fund,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, February 16,
2011, https://www.cbpp.org/blog/the-legacy-of-the-tanf-emergency-fund.
26
stimulus by enabling those at risk of losing their housing to spend more of their income on other
basic needs.
In the Great Recession, ARRA’s Homelessness Prevention and Rapid Re-Housing Program
(HPRP) was important in helping very poor families who were homeless or at risk of becoming
homeless. Despite lacking adequate administrative infrastructure in many places when it was
enacted, HPRP drew on $1.5 billion to serve about 1.15 million people in about 470,000 households
between July 2009 and September 2011. Communities’ infrastructure for providing homelessness
prevention and rapid re-housing assistance is now more established, and they could ramp up in
times of need and scale down during better times if provided the federal resources to do so.
43
While an increase in HPRP-type assistance should help in a recession, a major 2015 study from
the Department of Housing and Urban Development found that Housing Choice Vouchers
44
are
the most effective tool to help homeless families with children find and keep stable housing.
45
More
than 5 million people in 2.2 million families with low incomes use vouchers to help pay for housing
in the private market. The program is federally funded but run by a network of about 2,150 state and
local housing agencies. Only 1 in 4 eligible households use housing vouchers, however, because of
inadequate funding.
46
Housing agencies have the administrative capacity to quickly and effectively extend rental
assistance to more families and the expertise to inspect housing to ensure that it meets basic health
and safety standards. They are also able to target assistance to those with the most urgent needs,
such as people who are experiencing or at high risk of homelessness. With additional funding,
housing agencies could increase the availability of vouchers in a recession when many more families
experience temporary homelessness and housing instability and return to pre-recession levels when
the economy improves. The amount and duration of such temporary increases should be tied to
economic conditions.
The CARES Act contains important new investments in programs to serve people experiencing
homelessness and to prevent people from losing their housing, but considerably more is needed.
47
An anti-recessionary increase in housing vouchers along with an increase in funds to address
emergency housing needs should be in further COVID-19 responses. To be ready for the next
recession, policymakers can enact legislation with triggers that automatically increases the number of
vouchers when the economy weakens.
43
Department of Housing and Urban Development, “Homelessness Prevention and Rapid Re-Housing Program
(HPRP): Year 2 Summary,” February 2013,
https://www.hudexchange.info/resources/documents/HPRP_Year2Summary.pdf.
44
“Policy Basics: The Housing Choice Voucher Program,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, May 3, 2017,
https://www.cbpp.org/research/housing/policy-basics-the-housing-choice-voucher-program.
45
Douglas Rice, “Major Study: Housing Vouchers Most Effective Tool to End Family Homelessness,” Center on
Budget and Policy Priorities, July 24, 2015, https://www.cbpp.org/blog/major-study-housing-vouchers-most-effective-
tool-to-end-family-homelessness.
46
“Three Out of Four Low-Income At-Risk Renters Do Not Receive Federal Rental Assistance,” Center on Budget and
Policy Priorities, https://www.cbpp.org/three-out-of-four-low-income-at-risk-renters-do-not-receive-federal-rental-
assistance.
47
See Parrott et al., op. cit.
27
Conclusion
The long economic expansion following the Great Recession lulled many policymakers into
unwarranted complacency about the need to prepare for the next recession. The COVID-19
pandemic has produced a rude awakening, just as the financial crisis and Great Recession did a
dozen years ago. This time, however, important lessons from the Great Recession about the
effectiveness of fiscal policy in keeping an economic crisis from becoming even more severe should
guide our responses.